The financialization of commodity markets.
Xiong, Wei
Over the last decade, commodity futures have become a popular asset
class for portfolio investors, just like stocks and bonds. This process
is sometimes referred to as the financialization of commodity markets.
According to an estimate provided by the Commodity Futures Trading
Commission (CFTC) in 2008, investment inflows to various commodity
futures indices from early 2000 to June 30, 2008 totaled $200 billion.
(1) The increasing presence of financial investors in commodity markets
has led to a growing concern of the public and in policy circles as to
whether financialization might have affected commodity prices and
whether more government regulation in these markets is warranted.
In particular, the synchronized boom and bust cycle in 2007-8 in a
large number of commodities across the energy, metal, and agricultural
sectors has led to a heated debate regarding whether speculation in
commodity futures markets caused a bubble in commodity prices. Testing
to determine whether there actually was a price bubble is challenging
and deflects attention from analyzing more nuanced impacts of
financialization on commodity markets. Mindful of these considerations,
in a series of studies my co-authors and I focus on analyzing how the
increasing presence of financial traders has transformed commodity
markets through the economic mechanisms that underpin these markets:
risk sharing and information discovery. This research summary provides
an overview of these studies. Ing-Haw Cheng and I have also written a
broader review of the literature on the financialization of commodity
markets and on the debate about whether there was a price bubble. (2)
Evidence of Financialization
Prior to the early 2000s, despite liquid futures contracts being
traded on many commodities, their prices offered a risk premium for
idiosyncratic commodity price risk, and had little co-movement with
stocks or with each other. (3) These aspects are in sharp contrast to
the price dynamics of typical financial assets, which carry a premium
only for systematic risk and are highly correlated with market indices
and with each other. This contrast indicates that commodity markets were
partially segmented from outside financial markets and from each other.
Ke Tang and I present evidence that financialization has increased
the integration of commodity futures markets with each other. (4) We
find that futures prices of non-energy commodities became increasingly
correlated with oil prices after 2004, when significant index investment
started to flow into commodities markets. Figure 1, on page 21, shows
that while this trend intensified after the world financial crisis
triggered by the bankruptcy of Lehman Brothers in September 2008, its
presence was already evident and significant before the crisis. In
particular, this trend was significantly more pronounced for commodities
in the popular S&P-GSCI and DJ-UBS commodity investment indices than
for those off the indices after controlling for a set of alternative
arguments. The trend increase in the difference in futures price
co-movements with oil between indexed and off-index com modities is
related to the large inflows of investment capital to commodity index
securities during this period.
[FIGURE 1 OMITTED]
A compelling alternative argument for the increased co-movements
between commodity prices is the rapidly increasing commodity demands
from fast-growing emerging economies such as China. (5) Indeed, there is
evidence of an increasing return correlation between commodities and the
Morgan Stanley emerging market equity index in recent years. However, we
also find that co-movements of commodity futures prices in China
remained stable in 2006-8, which was in sharp contrast to the large
increases in the United States during this period. This contrast again
suggests that the increases in commodity price co-movements were not all
driven by changes in supply and demand of commodities from the
fast-growing emerging economies.
Risk sharing
One of the original reasons for developing commodity futures
markets was to facilitate commodity producers' unloading of their
commodity price risks to other economic agents. The long-standing
hedging pressure theory of Keynes and Hicks emphasizes that commercial
hedgers, who are typically producers and are net short in commodity
futures markets, face insufficient interest from other participants on
the long side. The aforementioned partial segmentation of commodity
futures markets prior to the 2000s is consistent with the premise of
such inefficient risk sharing posited by the hedging pressure theory. By
bringing more financial traders to the long side of commodity futures
markets, financialization facilitates the risk sharing of commercial
hedgers. (6)
However, financial traders such as hedge funds and commodity index
traders also face their own need to control risk and may have to reduce
risk exposure in commodity futures markets when their risk-bearing
capacity falls as a result of reasons outside of commodity markets. My
joint work with Cheng and Andrei Kirilenko provides a vivid example of
how financial distress experienced by financial traders during the
recent financial crisis may cause them to consume rather than to provide
liquidity in commodity futures markets. (7) By using changes in the VIX
to proxy for shocks to financial traders' risk-bearing capacity, we
find that during the crisis, but not before it, increases in the VIX led
financial traders to reduce their net long positions in 12 agricultural
commodities. The market-clearing condition implies that this was coupled
with reductions in futures prices and hedgers' short positions,
leading to a reallocation of commodity price risk from financial traders
to hedgers during the crisis. This finding highlights financial
traders' dual roles as both liquidity providers and liquidity
consumers to hedgers.
A common practice in both academic and policy studies of
speculation and hedging in futures markets is to treat trading by
hedgers as hedging and trading by speculators as speculation. Like
financial traders who might have hedging needs, hedgers may also engage
in speculative trading. In a recent study, Cheng and I specifically
analyze whether hedging motives can sufficiently explain trading by
hedgers in futures contracts of four agricultural commodities--wheat,
corn, soybeans, and cotton--for which we have relatively clean measures
of hedgers' positions and needs. (8) Figure 2 shows that in each of
these commodities, the volatility in hedgers' futures positions,
measured by the volatility of the monthly percentage change of their
aggregate short position, is many times greater than the cross-harvest
volatility of monthly percentage changes in USDA output forecasts, which
ultimately determine the hedgers' hedging need. Interestingly,
price changes prove to be a far better explanatory variable for
short-term changes in hedgers' positions than changes in output
forecasts. Specifically, hedgers tend to sell more futures when prices
rise and buy back futures when prices fall. (9) These findings suggest
that while hedgers take short positions in futures markets to hedge
their commercial risks, they may also engage in speculation on the
margin.
[FIGURE 2 OMITTED]
Taken together, my studies present a more nuanced view of risk
sharing in commodity futures markets than the prior literature suggests.
While financialization causes more financial traders to share the
commodity price risk of hedgers, financial traders may have to demand
liquidity from hedgers when they experience their own financial
distress, which occurred during the recent financial crisis. On the
other side, hedgers trade not just to hedge, and hedgers may engage in
speculation against financial traders as well. To fully understand risk
sharing in commodity futures markets thus requires identifying the
motives of both sides of individual trades rather than simply
classifying traders into different categories and then separating
speculation from hedging based on the categories.
Information Discovery
Participants in commodity markets face severe informational
frictions. The globalization of many industrial and agricultural
commodities has exposed market participants to informational frictions
regarding the supply, demand, and inventory of these commodities around
the world. Aggregating such information from different countries or
regions is challenging. The statistics from emerging economies are often
sparse and unreliable. The statistics from OECD countries, while more
reliable, are often delayed and subject to subsequent revisions. The
presence of severe informational frictions gives trading in both spot
and futures markets for commodities an important role in aggregating
information regarding supply and demand of these commodities.
In my joint work with Michael Sockin, we develop a theoretical
framework to highlight an informational feedback channel for trading in
commodity markets to affect commodity demand. (10) This framework
integrates commodity market trading under asymmetric information with an
international macro setting. In this setting, a continuum of specialized
goods producers whose production has complementarity, which emerges from
their need to trade produced goods with each other, faces unobservable
global economic strength and demands a key commodity, such as copper, as
a common production input. Through the trading of the commodity either
in a spot or futures market, the equilibrium commodity price aggregates
dispersed information regarding global economic strength and, in turn,
affects the goods producers' expectations. Through this channel,
informational noise in the commodity price, which may originate from
either supply shocks or trading in futures markets, affects the goods
producers' demand for the commodity.
In contrast to conventional wisdom that a higher commodity price
leads to a lower quantity demanded by goods producers, our model shows
that demand may increase with price. This happens because a higher
commodity price signals a stronger global economy and motivates each
goods producer to demand more of the commodity for producing more goods.
This informational effect offsets the cost effect. The complementarity
in production among goods producers magnifies the informational effect
through their incentives to coordinate production decisions and can even
lead to a positive price elasticity of their commodity demand.
Conghui Hu and I provide empirical evidence that supports commodity
futures prices as barometers of global economic strength in recent
years. (11) Specifically, we find that in 2005-12, the stock prices of
five East Asian economies -- China, Hong Kong, Japan, South Korea, and
Taiwan--had positive reactions to lagged overnight futures prices of
copper and soybeans traded in the United States, and weaker reactions to
crude oil. Interestingly, these East Asian economies are all net
importers of these commodities. The positive price reactions indicate
that East Asian stock markets tended to interpret the rising futures
prices as signals of strong global demand for their produced final goods
despite the higher input factor cost during the sample period.
The important informational role of commodity prices has an
intricate implication for empirical detection of speculative effects in
commodity markets and in particular for understanding the boom and bust
of commodity prices in 2007-8. After the oil price boom in 2008, many
commentators pointed toward the lack of inventory response to rising oil
prices as a reason to doubt speculative effects on oil prices. The logic
is as follows: if speculation artificially drives up oil prices, the
increased prices would reduce oil consumption and thus lead to more oil
storage. According to this logic, the lack of a spike in oil inventory
during the oil price boom suggests that the rising oil prices during
this period were justified by rising oil demand. This logic, while
intuitive and compelling, ignores the aforementioned informational
effect of oil prices. When the informational effect is sufficiently
strong, it is possible for speculation to drive up oil prices without
causing demand to fall or inventory to rise.
Indeed, it is difficult to fully explain the large price increases
of crude oil, copper, and other key commodities in the first half of
2008 simply based on rising commodity demands. In this period, oil
prices increased by 40 percent before peaking at $147 per barrel in
intraday trading in July 2008. Major world economies such as the United
States were falling into recession in late 2007, with the United States
beginning its recession in December 2007 (as determined by the NBER).
The S&P 500, FTSE 100, DAX, and Nikkei equity indices had peaked by
October 2007, and with the collapse of Bear Stearns in March 2008 the
world financial system was facing imminent trouble. Growth in emerging
economies such as China was also slowing: year-on-year growth in
China's GDP peaked in mid-2007, and the Shanghai CSI 300, MSCI
China, and broader MSCI Emerging Markets equity indices peaked in
October 2007. With the benefit of hindsight, it is difficult to argue
that the growth of the emerging economies, which were heavily dependent
on exports to developed economies and were themselves slowing, was
strong enough to more than offset the weakness in the developed
economies and to push up oil prices by more than 40 percent over the
first half of 2008.
On the other hand, it is reasonable to argue that there was great
uncertainty regarding the strength of the global economy during this
period. As shown in recent work by Kenneth Singleton, the large oil
price increases in early 2008 were accompanied by a greatly increased
dispersion of one-year-ahead oil price forecasts by professional
economists. (12) In this uncertain environment, agents in the economy
might have reasonably interpreted the large increases in futures prices
of oil and other commodities as positive signals of robust commodity
demand from China and other emerging economies. Through this
informational channel, speculation in commodity futures markets might
have affected commodity demand and prices.
This body of research suggests that to fully understand the
dramatic boom and bust of commodity prices in recent years and to
systematically evaluate the role of futures market speculation, it is
important to account for severe informational frictions faced by market
participants and for the informational role of commodity prices in
affecting their expectations.
(1) Commodity Futures Trading Commission, "Staff Report on
Commodity Swap Dealers and Index Traders with Commission
Recommendations" September 2008.
(2) I. Cheng and W. Xiong, "The Financialization of Commodity
Markets" NBER Working Paper No. 19642, November 2013,
andforthcoming in the Annual Review of Financial Economics.
(3) H. Bessembinder, "Systematic Risk, Hedging Pressure, and
Risk Premiums in Futures Markets" Review of Financial Studies, 4
(1992), pp. 637-67; G. Gorton and G. Rouwenhorst, "Facts and
Fantasies about Commodity Futures," Financial Analysts Journal, 62
(2) (2006), pp. 47-68; C. Erb and C. Harvey, "The Strategic and
Tactical Value of Commodity Futures," Financial Analysts Journal,
62 (2) (2006), pp. 69-97.
(4) K. Tang and W. Xiong, "Index Investment and
Financialization of Commodities," NBER Working Paper No. 16385,
September 2010, and Financial Analysts Journal, 68 (6) (November
2012),pp. 54-74.
(5) J. D. Hamilton, "Causes and Consequences of the Oil Shock
of 2007-08" NBER Working Paper No. 15002, May 2009; L. Kilian,
"Not All Oil Price Shocks Are Alike: Disentangling Demand and
Supply Shocks in the Crude Oil Market," American Economic Review,
99 (2009), pp. 1053-69.
(6) See evidence by J. D. Hamilton and J. C. Wu, "Risk Premia
in Crude Oil Futures Prices," NBER Working Paper No. 19056, May
2013.
(7) I. Cheng, A. Kirilenko, and W. Xiong, "Convective Risk
Flows in Commodity Futures Markets," NBER Working Paper No. 17921,
March 2012.
(8) I. Cheng and W. Xiong, "Why Do Hedgers Trade So
Much?"NBER Working Paper No. 19670, November 2013, and forthcoming
in the Journal of Legal Studies.
(9) See also the recent work of W. Kang, G. Rouwenhorst, and K.
Tang, "The Role of Hedgers and Speculators in Liquidity Provision
to Commodity Futures Markets," Working paper, Yale University,
2013.
(10) M. Sockin and W. Xiong, "Informational Frictions and
Commodity Markets," NBER Working Paper No. 18906, March 2013.
(11) C. Hu and W. Xiong, "Are Commodity Futures Prices
Barometers of the Global Economy?" NBER Working Paper No. 19706,
December 2013.
(12) K. Singleton, "Investor Flows and the 2008 Boom/Bust in
Oil Prices" Management Science, 60 (2) (February 2014), pp. 300-18.
Wei Xiong *
* Wei Xiong is a Research Associate in the NBER's Program on
Asset Pricing and a Professor of Economics at Princeton University. His
profile appears later in this issue.