Banking crises and the Federal Reserve as a lender of last resort during the Great Depression.
Richardson, Gary
My research focuses on banking crises in the Great Depression, the
structural flaws in the financial system that propagated the crises, the
Federal Reserve's efforts to act as a lender of last resort, and
the factors that shaped how policy-makers responded to the crisis.
Research on these issues involves gathering documents from the archives
of the Federal Reserve System as well as collecting information from
state regulators and private firms.
My emphasis on institutions and data stems from a desire to
identify the causes of the crises and the effects of a lender of last
resort. These events and policies were, obviously, endogenous, making it
difficult and at times impossible to clearly identify cause and effect.
Identification is complicated because the factors that facilitate
identification in financial theory consist of information--like the
beliefs and expectations of economic agents and policy makers--that is
difficult (and often impossible) to observe in practice and that exists
in few of the records remaining from the 1930s.
Structural Weakness in the Commercial Banking System before the
Great Depression
The NBER dates the onset of the Great Depression to August 1929. In
the fall of 1930, 15 months after the onset of the contraction, the
economy appeared poised for recovery. The previous three contractions,
in 1920, 1923, and 1926, had lasted an average of 15 months. In November
1930, however, a series of crises among commercial banks turned what up
to that time had been a typical recession into the longest and deepest
contraction of the twentieth century.
When the crises began, over 8,000 commercial banks belonged to the
Federal Reserve System, but nearly 16,000 did not. Those non-member
banks operated in an environment similar to that which existed before
the Federal Reserve was established in 1914. That environment harbored
the causes of banking crises.
One cause was the practice of counting checks in the process of
collection as part of banks' cash reserves. These
'floating' checks were counted in the reserves of two banks,
the one in which the check was deposited and the one on which the check
was drawn, and in many cases, additional banks, through which the check
flowed through while clearing. In reality, however, the cash resided in
only one bank. Bankers at the time referred to the reserves comprised of
float as fictitious reserves. The quantity of fictitious reserves rose
throughout the 1920s and peaked just before the financial crisis in
1930. Estimates vary, but in the fall of 1930, fictitious reserves
probably accounted for more than half and possibly up to four-fifths of
all reserves in non-member banks. This meant that the banking system as
a whole had a limited amount of cash reserves available for emergencies
(1).
Another challenge was the inability to mobilize bank reserves in
times of crisis. Non-member banks kept a portion of their reserves as
cash in their vaults and the bulk of their reserves as deposits in
correspondent banks in designated cities. Many, but not all, of the
ultimate correspondents belonged to the Federal Reserve System. This
reserve pyramid limited country banks' access to reserves during
times of crisis. When a bank needed cash, because its customers were
panicking and withdrawing funds en masse, the bank had to turn to its
correspondent, which might be faced with requests from many banks
simultaneously, or might be beset by depositor runs itself. The
correspondent bank also might not have the funds on hand because its
reserves consisted of checks in the mail, rather than cash in its vault.
If so, the correspondent would, in turn, have to request reserves from
another correspondent bank. That bank, in turn, might not have reserves
available or might not respond to the request. (2)
It should be noted that these flaws had been apparent to the
founders of the Federal Reserve. Paul Warburg wrote about them even
before the financial crisis in 1907. The National Monetary Commission
described them in its series of reports. The initial leaders of the
Federal Reserve System discussed them in their writings and explained
how the structure of the Federal Reserve and the actions of its leaders
solved these problems for member banks. But--here is a key part of the
story--the Federal Reserve solved these problems only for member banks.
For this reason, Warburg urged all commercial banks to join the Federal
Reserve System. At the start of the depression, what the Federal Reserve
could and should do for non-member banks remained an open question.
The Initial Banking Crisis and a Policy Experiment
These flaws in the financial system engendered the initial banking
crisis of the Great Depression. This crisis began with the collapse of
Caldwell and Company. Caldwell was a rapidly expanding conglomerate and
the largest financial holding company in the South. It provided its
clients with an array of services--including banking, brokerage, and
insurance--through an expanding chain and a series of overlapping
directorates controlled by its parent corporation headquartered in
Nashville, Tennessee. The parent got into trouble when its leaders
invested too heavily in securities markets and lost substantial sums
when stock prices declined. In order to cover their own losses, the
leaders drained cash from the corporations that they controlled.
On November 7, one of Caldwell's principal subsidiaries, the
Bank of Tennessee (Nashville) closed its doors. On November 12 and 17,
Caldwell affiliates in Knoxville, TN, and Louisville, KY, also failed.
The failures of these institutions triggered a correspondent cascade
that forced scores of commercial banks to suspend operations. In
communities where these banks closed, depositors panicked and withdrew
funds from other banks. Panic spread from town to town. Within a few
weeks, hundreds of banks suspended operations. About a third of these
banks reopened within a few months, but the majority liquidated.
Panic began to subside in early December. But on December 11, the
fourth largest bank in New York City, Bank of United States, ceased
operations. The bank had been negotiating to merge with another
institution. The New York Fed had helped with the search for a merger
partner. When negotiations broke down, depositors rushed to withdraw
funds, and New York's Superintendent of Banking closed the
institution. This event, like the collapse of Caldwell, generated
newspaper headlines throughout the United States, stoking fears of
financial Armageddon and inducing jittery depositors to withdraw funds
from other banks.
The Federal Reserve's reaction to this crisis varied across
districts. The crisis began in the Sixth District, headquartered in
Atlanta. The leaders of the Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta believed
that their responsibility as a lender of last resort extended to the
broader banking system. The Atlanta Fed expedited discount lending to
member banks, encouraged member banks to extend loans to their
non-member respondents, and rushed funds to cities and towns beset by
banking panics.
The crisis also hit the Eighth District, headquartered in St.
Louis. The leaders of the Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis had a
narrower view of their responsibilities and refused to rediscount loans
for the purpose of accommodating non-member banks. During the crisis,
the St. Louis Fed limited discount lending and refused to assist
non-member institutions.
Outcomes differed between the districts. After the crisis, in the
Sixth District, the economic contraction slowed and recovery began. In
the Eighth District, the banking system lay in shambles. Lending
declined. Business faltered and unemployment rose.
I examine these events in a paper that estimates the effect of the
intervention by the Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta relative to the
inaction of the Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis. (3) To control for
the factors that typically impede inference in such situations, we
restrict our analysis to the state of Mississippi. The southern half of
Mississippi belonged to the Atlanta District. The northern half belonged
to the St. Louis District. None of the banks in Mississippi had
connections to the Caldwell conglomerate, so the banking crisis in the
state stemmed almost entirely from the panic and runs that spread
throughout the region in the wake of Caldwell's collapse. An array
of statistical tests (including non-parametric survival analysis and
more common parametric regressions) demonstrate that during the panic in
the Atlanta District, banks failed at much lower rates, and after the
crisis, banks loaned larger amounts of funds and output and employment
were higher, than in the St. Louis District. A variety of robustness
checks corroborate this claim.
To further examine the impact of Atlanta's lender-of-last
resort policies, two co-authors and I exploit exogenous variation in
banking conditions across Florida in 1929 to assess the effect of the
Atlanta Fed's policies during the last banking crisis before the
onset of the contraction. This crisis involved an infestation of
Mediterranean fruit flies in the spring and summer of 1929. In the
summer of 1929, the state and Federal government began eradicating
infested groves and embargoing shipments of crops from infested regions.
Congress recessed without determining whether to compensate farmers for
their losses. Within two weeks, runs began on the correspondent banks in
Tampa which served as hub of the financial network in central Florida.
The Atlanta Fed intervened by rushing large quantities of cash to the
afflicted institutions, stopping the panic in its tracks, and
resuscitating the financial system. (4)
Banking Crises in 1931 through 1933
Much of my research focuses on the initial banking crises of the
Great Depression, because the structure of institutions and events
enables plausible identification of cause and effect at that time. The
banking crises continued, however, for two and a half years, and my
research examines that period as well.
From 1931 to 1933, the U.S. banking system experienced a series of
regional crises as well as two national crises. The first national
crisis coincided with the financial crisis in Europe and peaked after
Britain's departure from the gold standard in the fall of 1931. The
second national crisis began in the winter of 1933 and ended when
Roosevelt declared a national banking holiday.
In one paper, I reassess a perennial debate concerning the causes
of the banking crises during the Great Depression. One school argues
that illiquidity forced most banks out of business, and therefore, an
aggressive lender of last resort may have mitigated the crisis. Another
school argues that insolvency forced most banks out of business. These
failures occurred, in other words, because the banks invested funds in
assets that failed to pay back. Returns to investments fell because the
industrial economy contracted. 'Fundamental' investment losses
drove banks out of business. In this case, a lender of last resort could
not have ameliorated the crisis. Government assistance of financial
institutions might have worsened the problem by enabling zombie banks to
remain in operation and shifting losses from private investors to the
public sector.
To address this debate, I examine a database on the causes of bank
suspensions complied by the Federal Reserve Board. (5) It indicates bank
examiners' conclusions concerning the causes of failure for almost
all commercial banks operating in the United States at that time. The
data demonstrate that both illiquidity and insolvency were substantial
sources of bank distress. Periods when large numbers of banks failed
were periods of intense illiquidity. Illiquidity and contagion via
correspondent networks was particularly intense during the initial
banking panic in the fall of 1930 and last banking panic in the winter
of 1933. As the depression deepened, asset values declined, and the
Reconstruction Finance Corporation increasingly served as a lender of
last resort, insolvency loomed as the principal threat to depository
institutions.
In a series of three papers, I examine the transmission of the
financial crisis from Europe to the United States in the summer and fall
of 1931. The transmission might have occurred by directly affecting
financial institutions in the United States, particularly the banks in
New York, which had sizeable investments in and deposits from Europe. To
determine the magnitude of this channel, my coauthors and I compare the
performance of banks with substantial exposure to European deposits and
debts with those with little or no exposure to European risks. (6) We
demonstrate that the banks with European exposure did not change their
behavior during or after the European crisis. In fact, the banks with
European exposure--which tended to be the largest money-center banks in
the United States--performed significantly better by almost all measures
than banks without European exposure.
Why? New York's money center banks predicted financial turmoil
in Europe at least two years prior to the event. Recognizing their
vulnerability to a trans-Atlantic crisis and realizing that they had to
rely on their own efforts to survive the shock, these banks accumulated
reserves and capital in preparation for the event. When the crisis came,
they wrote down their reserves and both deliberately and collectively
continued lending as usual.
Another paper examines a related question: why did bank failures in
New York City, at the center of the United States' money market,
peak in July and August 1931, when the banking crisis peaked in Germany
and before Britain abandoned the gold standard (7)? The chronological
correlation suggests that a connection existed between events in New
York and on the continent. Our research initially sought this
connection. Instead, we found the correlation to be coincidental. Rather
than the exposure to events overseas, bank distress rose in New York due
to intensified regulatory scrutiny, which was a delayed reaction to the
failure of the Bank of United States. In the summer of 1931, New
York's legislature held hearings regarding the performance of the
Superintendent of Banking, who they accused of lack of vigilance. Before
and during the hearings, the bank superintendent directed a wave of
examinations of banks in New York City and shut down a series of
institutions that failed to pass muster.
A final essay examines the transmission of financial shocks from
the periphery to the center of the financial system in the United
States. In 1929, nearly all interbank deposits held by Federal Reserve
member banks belonged to "shadowy" nonmember banks which were
outside the regulatory reach of federal regulators. Regional banking
panics in the early 1930s drained these interbank deposits from central
reserve city banks of Chicago and New York. Money-center banks responded
to the increasing volatility and declining quantity of interbank
deposits by changing the composition of their balance sheets. They
reduced lending to businesses and individuals, and increased their
holdings of cash and government bonds. (8) This interbank channel
accounted for a substantial share of the decline in lending during the
contraction of the 1930s.
What Have We Learned?
The financial crisis of 2008 and its aftermath highlight the
importance of studying infrequent economic cataclysms. These events
seldom occur, but when they do, economic agents and policymakers need to
be prepared, because in a short span of time, they must make decisions
that have tremendous impact on the lives of ordinary men and women and
on the future of the world economy.
By studying the late 1920s and early 1930s, we learn that
prosperous economies can have healthy financial systems that harbor
hidden flaws. The depth of the structural problems may not be apparent
during the boom years. Detecting them may be difficult even for scholars
studying events after the fact. The structural flaws that I study are a
case in point. Scholars studying the Depression after World War II
attributed the weakness of the financial system to an institutional
change that they believed had occurred around the time of the Federal
Reserve Act. (9) In the nineteenth and early twentieth centuries, the
principal defense mechanism for banks beset by runs was the suspension
of the conversion of deposits to currency. Suspension of convertibility
enabled banks to preserve their assets by strictly enforcing the
contracts that depositors signed when they opened accounts. While the
suspension of convertibility during crises before the founding of the
Federal Reserve is widely recognized, leading scholars asserted that
because of regulations associated with the founding of the Federal
Reserve, banks could not suspend payments during the Great Depression.
My research drawing on records of the Division of Bank Operations of the
Federal Reserve Board finds that during the early 1930s, banks could and
frequently did suspend payments to depositors. (10) In the 1920s, the
Division of Bank Operations established a nationwide reporting network
that gathered information--including examiners reports--on all bank
suspensions, liquidations, and mergers. (11) This data clearly
illuminates problems relating to reserves (which I described earlier) as
the principal propagators of the commercial banking crises in 1930 and
1933 and a contributor to the financial crises that occurred in the
interim.
We also learn that policymakers can take actions to mitigate a
financial crisis. When a correspondent cascade knocks banks down like
dominoes, rushing liquidity to nodes in the network can stop the chain
reaction. The Atlanta Fed took this approach during crises in Florida in
1929 and Tennessee and Mississippi in 1930. Their efforts mitigated the
panic and encouraged economic recovery.
(1.) G. Richardson, "Correspondent Clearing and the Banking
Panics of the Great Depression," NBER Working Paper No. 12716,
December 2006. Published as "The Check is in the Mail:
Correspondent Clearing and Clearing and the Collapse of the Banking
System, 1930 to 1933." Journal of Economic History, 67(3) 2007:
643-71.
(2.) K. Mitchener and G. Richardson, "Shadowy Banks and
Financial Contagion during the Great Depression: A Retrospective on
Friedman and Schwartz." American Economic Review, 103(May 2013):
73-78.
(3.) G. Richardson and W. Troost, "Monetary Intervention
Mitigated Banking Panics During the Great Depression: Quasi-Experimental
Evidence from the Federal Reserve District Border in Mississippi, 1929
to 1933," NBER Working Paper No. 12591, October 2006, published in
Journal of Political Economy 117 (2009), 1031-1076.
(4.) M. Carlson, K. Mitchener, and G. Richardson, "Arresting
Banking Panics: Fed Liquidity Provision and the Forgotten Panic of
1929," NBER Working Paper No. 16460, October 2010, published in
Journal of Political Economy 119 (2011), 888-924.
(5.) G. Richardson, "Bank Distress during the Great
Depression: The Illiquidity-Insolvency Debate Revisited," NBER
Working Paper No. 12717, December 2006, published in Explorations in
Economic History 44 (2007), 586-607.
(6.) G. Richardson and P. Van Horn, "When the Music Stopped:
Transatlantic Contagion During the Financial Crisis of 1931," NBER
Working Paper No. 17437, September 2011, and G. Richardson and P. Van
Horn, "Fetters of Debt, Deposit, or Gold during the Great
Depression? The International Propagation of the Banking Crisis of
1931," NBER Working Paper No. 12983, March 2007, published in
Jahrbuch fuer Wirtschaftgeschichte, 52 (2011), 29-54.
(7.) G. Richardson and P. Van Horn, "Intensified Regulatory
Scrutiny and Bank Distress in New York City during the Great
Depression," NBER Working Paper No. 14120, June 2008, published in
Journal of Economic History 69 (2009).
(8.) K. Mitchener and G. Richardson, 2013, op cit.
(9.) M. Friedman and A. Schwartz. The Monetary History of the
United States, 1863-1961. Princeton: Princeton University Press. 1963,
and B. Bernanke, "Nonmonetary Effects of the Financial Crisis in
the Propagation of the Great Depression." American Economic Review,
73 (1983), 257-276.
(10.) G. Richardson, "Quarterly Data on the Categories and
Causes of Bank Distress during the Great Depression," NBER Working
Paper No. 12715, December 2006, published in Research in Economic
History 25 (2008) 37-115.
(11.) G. Richardson, "Bank Distress during the Great
Contraction, 1929 to 1933, New Data from the Archives of the Board of
Governors," NBER Working Paper No. 12590, October 2006. I found
this data in the National Archives. Milton Friedman read the draft of
this paper and told me that he and Anna Schwartz had looked for this
data long ago, but could not find it, and then listed the questions that
I should try to answer with the information.
Gary Richardson *
* Gary Richardson is a Research Associate in the NBER Programs on
the Development of the American Economy and Monetary Economics. He is a
Professor of Economics at the University of California at Irvine.