The changing focus of Public Economics research, 1980-2010.
Chetty, Raj ; Finkelstein, Amy
The NBER's Program on Public Economics (PE) has covered a very
wide range of topics since the last program report six years ago. Rather
than attempting to summarize the entire corpus of work that has been
done by this program in the past few years, this report provides a
bird's eye view of some of the major changes in the field from two
perspectives. First, we quantify the main trends in public finance
research at the NBER over the last thirty years, drawing on statistics
from the database of NBER Working Papers. Second, we qualitatively
summarize some of the emerging themes of recent research, both in terms
of topics and methods.
A Statistical Perspective
The Public Economics Program began as the Business Taxation and
Finance Program, which held its first meeting under the direction of
David Bradford in December 1977. It was renamed the Taxation Program in
1980, to reflect the broader research interests of its affiliated
researchers. To recognize the importance of expenditure as well as tax
research, the program was renamed "Public Economics" in 1991,
when James Poterba succeeded David Bradford as Program Director.
In the last two decades, the research conducted by the Public
Economics Program has changed dramatically in volume, methodology, and
topics. To broadly characterize some of the main trends, we downloaded
all of the Working Papers in the Taxation Program in 1990 and in the
Public Economics Program in 2000 and 2010, and classified them in
various ways, which we summarize in Table 1, on page 3.
Table 1-Overview
1990 2000 2010
Total # of 398 665 1025
NBER Working
Papers
Total # of 55 153 183
Working
Papers in
Public
Economics
Share of 13.8% 23.0% 17.9%
Working
Papers in
Public
Economics
Public
Economics
Working
Papers by
Methodology
1990 2000 2010
Empirical 29.1% 46.4% 52.5%
Theory 38.2% 37.3% 30.1%
Both 29.1% 11.8% 5.5%
Other (survey 3.6% 4.6% 12.1%
of the
literature,
research
methodology,
etc)
Public
Economics
Working
Papers by
Topic
1990 2000 2010
Tax 63.6% 28.1% 15.3%
Spending 5.5% 13.7% 20.8%
Tax and 0.0% 7.8% 1.1%
Spending
Other 30.9% 50.3% 62.8%
(Education,
Regulation,
etc) *
Public
Economics
Working
Papers on
Taxation:
Corporate vs.
Individual
1990 2000 2010
Individual 47.1% 79.2% 88.9%
Corporate 41.2% 13.2% 7.4%
Both 11.8% 7.5% 3.7%
* WPs on education factors and their productivity, such as teachers'
value added and school choice mechanisms, are categorized under
"other" while WPs on the financing of public education are
categorized under "spending".
The number of Public Economics (PE) papers per year has grown over
time from 55 in 1990 to 183 in 2010. This appears to primarily reflect
the growth in the number of Program members; over the same period, the
total number of NBER affiliates has also increased; and the Public
Economics share of NBER Working Papers has not shown any pronounced
trend. However, the activities of the PE Program have branched out in
part to related programs, including Children, the Economics of
Education, Aging, Health Economics, and Health Care. The papers in these
programs collectively account for over 40 percent of NBER Working Papers
in 2010.
The typical methodology used in papers in the PE Program also has
changed over time. In 1990, about 30 percent of papers listed in PE were
purely empirical; by 2010 that number had grown to about 50 percent.
Much of this growth is likely due to the greater availability of micro
data that permit rigorous empirical analyses of questions that cannot be
answered purely based on theory. We expect this growth to be even more
rapid in the coming years, as researchers gain access to large
administrative panel databases that permit even finer analysis.
The topics analyzed by public economists have changed as much as
the methods used. Although public finance traditionally has been
associated with government spending and taxation, our analysis of papers
listed in the PE Program shows a marked trend over time toward a broader
definition of what constitutes public finance. The share of papers
listed in the PE Program that are not directly related to government
spending or taxation rose from 30 percent in 1990 to over 60 percent in
2010. Common topics for these other papers include macroeconomics,
regulation (environmental, housing, financial and so on), and papers on
educational productivity and outcomes. Another metric of this broadening
of focus is the increasing share of PE papers that are cross-listed in
another field, from about 30 percent in 1990 to about 90 percent in
2010.
There also has been a marked shift in research from the analysis of
taxation to the analysis of government expenditures. In 1990, less than
10 percent of PE papers on taxes or spending dealt exclusively with
spending; in 2010 that number was about 55 percent. Part of this
increase is related to the fact that the nature of government
expenditure today is more amenable to economic analysis: economists have
less to say about the best way to build bridges than about how to design
social insurance programs. But another likely reason for the shift is
that the varied nature of expenditure programs at the state and local
level creates many important and interesting questions that researchers
can investigate using modern quasi-experimental techniques.
There also have been important changes within the subfield of
taxation. Most notably, research has focused increasingly on issues of
individual taxation. The share of tax-related papers that deal
exclusively with individual taxation has risen from almost 50 percent in
1990 to about 90 percent in 2010. We believe that part of this trend is
related to the availability of excellent microdata and identification
strategies that are useful in analyzing individual tax and spending
programs. Corporate taxation is thus an area that appears ripe for
additional work using modern theoretical and empirical methods.
A Qualitative Perspective
While the descriptive statistics above provide a broad sense of the
major shifts in the field, there are many thematic and methodological
changes that require a more nuanced reading of the literature. We
briefly review what we view as some of the most important themes that
have emerged over the past decade of work and highlight areas that are
likely to be very active in the coming years. Naturally, the summaries
below neglect a far larger fraction of research than they cover; no
brief review could do justice to the breadth and depth of work done by
the PE group over the past five years. For most of the major points we
make we try to list a few illustrative examples from recent working
papers, but do not attempt a comprehensive reference list. We apologize
to researchers whose work and topics of focus we have been unable to
cover here because of space constraints.
Connecting Theory to Evidence
Prompted by the growth in empirical work documented above,
researchers more recently have begun to seek methods of connecting
empirical findings back to the theoretical models that formed the core
of public finance research in the 1970s and 1980s. The explosion in
empirical research in the 1990s and 2000s was largely driven by studies
that documented the causal impacts of tax policies or expenditure
programs on economic behavior. For instance, a large empirical
literature estimated the impacts of income taxation on labor supply and
reported taxable income (7512, 15012, 15583). These studies generally
have found significant impacts of taxes on reported taxable income,
particularly for high income individuals and over longer horizons when
individuals have had sufficient time to adjust labor supply. Estimates
of the taxable income elasticity vary, but are generally between 0.25
and 0.5 excluding top income earners (15616). An equally large number of
studies have measured the impacts of social insurance and welfare
programs on many behaviors (12865, 14306, 15589, 17049). Again, there is
consistent evidence that these government expenditure programs affect
behaviors around labor supply, savings, and healthcare expenditures.
Many of these studies used quasi-experimental methods that permit
convincing identification of the causal impacts of policies under
relatively weak assumptions.
This body of empirical work has advanced enormously (and continues
to advance) our understanding of policy impacts. For instance, several
studies have demonstrated convincingly that social security programs
have significant effects on retirement decisions (7830, 8658, 17320).
Yet in many cases, it has been difficult to translate these findings
into assessments of the efficiency or other economic effects associated
with social security programs. Theoretical studies on social security
(10260, 16503) have characterized the efficiency consequences of program
design under specific assumptions about various parameters. However, the
implications of the empirical findings for the parameters that entered
these theoretical models were often unclear.
Recent work in the PE group has connected the earlier theoretical
literature with modern empirical evidence more directly. Researchers
used two types of methodology to accomplish this goal. The first is to
build structural models that are calibrated to match empirical estimates
(9183, 13228, 13375, 17338) and then to analyze policy using these
models. This structural approach offers a versatile tool for making
quantitative predictions about how particular measures of household
welfare could be affected by policy changes in a variety of settings.
The second is to derive formulas for policies that meet specified
criteria--such as maximizing individuals' utility or welfare--from
standard theoretical models that can be expressed in terms of the
high-level reduced-form parameters estimated in modern empirical work.
This latter technique, which has come to be known as the
"sufficient statistic" approach, is less dependent on the
specification of a particular model of underlying behavior, but is more
limited in the set of questions it can answer.
Both of these methodologies have allowed PE researchers to start to
assess how various policies affect a number of criteria that might be
used for policy analysis. For instance, researchers have provided
numerical characterizations of how a utilitarian social welfare
criterion would be affected by various degrees of progressively of the
income tax schedule (7628, 7708, 17616), of the level of unemployment
benefits that maximizes individuals' expected utility (12618,
13967), of the tax rate on capital gains that maximizes net surplus
(17642), and of the welfare costs of adverse selection in health
insurance and annuity markets (13228, 14414). These approaches have in
turn helped to refocus the empirical literature on estimating the
parameters that matter most for policy analysis. There are many areas of
the field in which work connecting theory to data is only now beginning,
such as the analysis of social security and disability insurance
programs or the analysis of education policies. We expect much more
research in these areas using the tools that have been developed in
recent research.
Behavioral Public Finance
Public economics has been quick to draw upon the insights of other
fields and to understand their implications for policy analysis. One of
the most important transformations in public economics over the past
decade has been the incorporation of lessons from behavioral economics.
While traditional public economics often starts from potential market
failures that might motivate government intervention--such as asymmetric
information or externalities due to incomplete markets--behavioral
models open up a new class of potential motives and considerations for
government policy. When individuals do not optimize, there may be a
rationale for government intervention even in well-functioning markets,
for instance by requiring that individuals who underestimate risks buy
health insurance or by forcing myopic agents to save for retirement.
A key challenge in this nascent literature has been to understand
how to do welfare analysis when agents do not optimize. Public
economists have leaned very heavily upon the tools of revealed
preference in order to analyze policy. By recovering individual
preferences from choices, one can proceed to identify policies that
maximize the individual's welfare. But when individuals do not
optimize, their choices no longer reveal their true preferences, and it
becomes much less clear what the government's objective should be.
Recent work has made several productive strides in tackling this issue,
ranging from defining welfare criteria when agents make specific
mistakes (13976, 15328) to developing robust methods of welfare analysis
that acknowledge choice inconsistencies (13330, 13737).
Partly because welfare analysis in behavioral models is complex,
much of the growth in the behavioral public economics literature has
been in positive empirical work. A recurring finding of these studies is
that while traditional economic incentives do matter on the margin,
other aspects of policies--such as framing, information, or the decision
environment--often have much larger impacts. Researchers have
demonstrated that behavioral considerations play a first-order role in
an array of settings, including the role of defaults in retirement
savings contributions (12009, 13352, 14859), the role of salience in tax
policies (12924, 13330), and the impacts of information provision tax
and transfer programs (14836, 17287).
While behavioral considerations play an increasingly important role
in public finance research, much remains to be learned before
researchers have a unified framework for policy analysis when agents do
not optimize. We expect to see much more research in this area in the
coming years.
New Dynamic Public Finance
Just as public economists have drawn inspiration from work in
behavioral economics, research on dynamic macroeconomic models also has
had a significant influence on the field. While many of the theoretical
models studied by public economists in the 1980s and 1990s were static,
macroeconomists were developing dynamic models with forward-looking
agents who anticipated changes in future government policies. This style
of work now has informed research on public finance, with a large and
robust literature dealing with policy problems such as capital income
taxation and social insurance in dynamic models. These problems are
technically very challenging, because dynamic models are generally much
less tractable than static models.
Researchers have made considerable progress in facing these
technical challenges and have begun to obtain some interesting findings.
For example, several studies have suggested that there may be a role for
capital taxation even in infinite-horizon economics, contrary to the
results of classic papers that made stronger assumptions about the set
of policy instruments available to the government (10792, 16619, 13720,
17642). Other work has shown that in an environment without liquidity
constraints, the path of unemployment benefits that maximizes expected
utility is constant over time (11689).
An interesting direction for further work in this area is combining
the insights of behavioral models with dynamic models. Most dynamic
models assume that agents are forward looking, rational agents, contrary
to the lessons from the behavioral literature summarized above. One
early example along these lines is work showing that constraining
agent's savings decisions when individuals have self-control
problems can increase utility (10151). Another interesting direction for
further work will be to tie the new dynamic models more closely to
empirical evidence, as is now common in the analysis of static problems.
Lab and Field Experiments
While a great deal of the new empirical work in public finance
exploits large observational datasets, public economists also run
experiments and collect new data to use in analyzing economic policies.
An active literature uses lab experiments to investigate economic
decision making in a variety of domains. These include classic topics
such as public goods (15967) and the endowment effect, and reference
dependent behavior (16715), as well as newer areas of inquiry such as
the impact of matching grants on charitable giving (13728) and the
effect of campaign finance regulations (17384). Other recent work has
tested the internal consistency of economic choices and has attempted to
explain which types of agents are most rational in their behavior
(16791).
Researchers also have turned to field experiments to tackle a broad
range of questions because of concerns about the external validity of
lab experiments (12992, 14356). Field experiments have been used to
analyze the role of ballot secrecy in voter turnout (17673), motives for
charitable giving (17648), the long-term impacts of early childhood
education (16381, 17533), the effects of information provision on
Medicare Part D prescription drug insurance plan choices (17410), and
the consequences of using various strategies to address the needs of
poor individuals in developing countries (15980). The breadth of these
studies, relative to traditional public finance topics, illustrates both
the expansion of the field as discussed above and the fact that field
experiments allow researchers to tackle questions that could not be
answered with standard observational datasets.
As with empirical work using observational data, recent research
has begun to integrate more closely the findings from experiments with
theoretical models (17047). Several studies involve the design of
experiments that directly test the predictions of standard models. For
instance, recent work has tested theoretical predictions about
observational learning (13516), analyzed whether neoclassical models of
tax evasion are good descriptions of taxpayer behavior (15769), and
investigated whether individuals' utility depends upon absolute or
relative income (16396). Other studies have estimated the parameters
needed to calibrate models for policy analysis, such as the price
elasticity of charitable giving (12338).
Social Insurance
The growth in research on expenditure programs documented above is
driven primarily by research on major social insurance programs,
particularly Social Security and Disability Insurance, Medicare and
Medicaid, and Unemployment Insurance. These programs make up over half
of federal expenditures and are expected to grow rapidly over the coming
decades as the baby boomers age and medical costs continue to grow. In
the 1980s and early 1990s, empirical work tended to focus on the
distortion consequences of social insurance programs, particularly for
labor supply, but also for other behaviors such as savings and health
expenditures. While important advances continue to be made in this area,
we have also seen an increasing focus on formalizing and quantifying the
benefits of these programs. For example, recent work has examined the
potential benefits that unemployment insurance may provide by giving
unemployed workers access to liquidity (11689, 11709, 13967); one of the
central findings of this new vein of research is that access to
liquidity during unemployment may be one of the most important functions
of unemployment insurance. In the area of health insurance, while
interest continues in the impact of Medicare and Medicaid on health
spending, research also examines the potential benefits of these
programs not only for health outcomes but, increasingly, for risk
spreading (16155, 17190), where evidence suggests health insurance may
play an important role in reducing the risk of large out-of-pocket
medical expenditures or medical debts.
Another welcome development in this area has been the creation of
compelling research designs to use in investigating the impacts of
uniform national programs. Historically, much of the empirical work on
social insurance has focused on unemployment insurance or Medicaid, both
of which are state level programs, therefore offering potential
"natural experiments" as different states have adjusted these
programs in different ways at different points in time. Much of the
empirical work on important national social insurance programs--such as
Social Security, Medicare, and Disability Insurance--was limited to
time-series comparisons as the programs expanded or to cross-sectional
comparisons about individuals whose incomes gave them access to
different benefit levels. Increasingly, however, researchers have been
able to draw on other empirical strategies--sometimes in other countries
and often drawing on large administrative databases--to shed light on
the impact of these important social insurance programs. In the United
States, for example, recent studies have used the discontinuity in
Medicare eligibility at age 65 to study the impact of Medicare on health
care utilization and health outcomes (13668, 10365). One paper presented
at the Spring 2011 NBER Public Economics Program Meeting uses the
quasi-random assignment of disability applicants to examiners with
different degrees of leniency in judging disability to examine the
impact of disability insurance receipt on labor supply. (1) The authors
find that the receipt of disability insurance reduces labor force
participation more for those who are estimated to have less severe
disabilities.
In addition to examining the impacts of social insurance, a growing
body of empirical research has investigated some of the underlying
economic rationales for these social insurance programs, focusing
particularly on the existence and nature of selection in private
insurance markets for annuities and health insurance (12289, 14414,
15326) as well as the impact of public policy in selection markets
(16977). The emphasis on developing techniques for detecting selection
and then applying them has generated interesting and at times surprising
insights about the nature of selection and the implications for public
policy in annuity and health insurance markets. Several papers include
examples in which rather than adverse selection--where those who have
private information that they are at high risk select more
insurance--there is evidence of advantageous selection--in which those
who have private information that they are at low risk will select more
insurance. This has raised the possibility that there may be insurance
markets in which private information results in too much rather than too
little insurance coverage.
Research influences from the financial crisis and current
macroeconomic events
One of the strengths of the PE program is that the research it
produces quickly responds to important economic events. Recently, the
financial crisis has touched almost all aspects of American life and
society. Thus, we have seen a remarkably quick and direct influence of
the macroeconomic situation and the public policy questions it has
generated on research in the PE program. Two topics in particular have
generated such a concentrated burst of related research that we
organized mini-symposia around the topics.
One research topic concerns the varying economic effects of
unemployment insurance over the business cycle (16526, 17173, 17534),
and the potential implications of such variation for program design.
These studies have analyzed, among other things, the extent to which
unemployment benefit extensions have increased unemployment rates, and
whether this effect is smaller or larger in recessions. In the spring of
2011, we organized a symposium around this topic.
Another question concerns the nature, mechanism, and magnitude of
the fiscal multiplier. One day of the July 2011 Summer Institute was
devoted to six papers on this topic. Mankiw and Weinzierl (17029)
provided a theoretical framework for analyzing the optimal response of
monetary and fiscal policy to aggregate demand shocks. Nakamura and
Steinsson (17391) provided empirical estimates of the impact of regional
shocks to public expenditures on economic activity, and a framework with
which to use such estimates to try to inform one's sense of the
standard closed-economy aggregate multiplier. The program that day also
featured several papers that estimated the fiscal multiplier using
quasi-experimental designs, such as those induced by the stimulus bill
(the American Reinvestment and Recovery Act), by the changes in federal
spending in localities brought about by decennial updates to the
population estimates, and by the performance of state pension fund
investments. Other program meetings have featured NBER Working Papers
related to the impact of fiscal stimulus as well, including an analysis
of the impact of the "Cash for Clunkers" program on the
economy (16351) which concluded that almost all of the additional car
sales induced by this program represented moving forward sales that
otherwise would have occurred within the year anyway.
The interest in analyzing fiscal stimulus is one example of a
broader trend toward analyzing issues that have been tackled
historically using macroeconomic approaches rather than microeconometric
methods. Another example of the use of quasi-experimental methods is
work estimating the marginal propensity to consume out of windfall cash
grants (16684, 14753).
While the character of public economics research at the NBER has
changed dramatically over the past three decades--as any healthy and
active area of research should--the fundamental goals of the field
remain much the same: to provide careful, rigorous economic analysis
that bears on the most important government policy questions of the
time. The NBER's PE program has made significant contributions
toward achieving this goal over the past decades and is well poised to
continue to do so in the years to come.
(1) Nicole Maestas, Kathleen Mullen, and Alexander Strand,
"Does Disability Insurance Receipt Discourage Work? Using Examiner
Assignment to Estimate Causal Effects of SSDI Receipt".
* Chetty and Finkelstein direct the NBER's Program on Public
Economics. Chetty is a professor of economics at Harvard University.
Finkelstein is a professor of economics at MIT. They are grateful to
Annetta Zhou for excellent research assistance. The numbers in
parentheses throughout this report refer to NBER Working Papers.
Raj Chetty and Amy Finkelstein *