Risk and the consumption, saving, and portfolio choices of American households.
Parker, Jonathan A.
In the past few years, U.S. households have faced an enormous
amount of macroeconomic uncertainty. The financial crisis, the Great
Recession, and the European debt crisis together have caused large
changes in asset prices and incomes, increases in market volatility, and
significant uncertainty about government policies. My research considers
how consumption and saving behaviors respond to risk and to government
policies, as well as how the risks that households face are evolving.
Here I discuss four topics more specifically: How do households allocate
their savings in response to different risks across different stocks?
How do households (mis) perceive risk and how does this affect their
behavior? How effective was the government stabilization policy of
distributing tax rebates at generating household spending? And how have
changes in the labor market and increasing inequality in particular
changed which households bear macroeconomic risks?
Saving, Portfolios, and Risk
Different types of stocks traded on the U.S. stock market can
exhibit quite different average returns over long periods, differences
that persist out of sample, are highly statistically significant, and
can be as much as 10 percent per year. Such differences ought to be
understandable from the saving and portfolio choices of households,
choices which in turn presumably are determined by differences in the
riskiness of different stocks. That is,
people should pay less for stocks that are more risky, and we
should observe risky stocks on average earning higher rates of return.
But then the key issue becomes how we measure riskiness.
The central view in economics is that people save to support future
consumption, which implies that we should be able to explain differences
in expected returns across stocks by the risk that each investment poses
for future consumption, or equivalently by the extent to which
people's spending on consumption drops when the return is low and
rises when the return is high. Such risky stocks are said to have high
"consumption betas." Unfortunately, this theory does not work
well in many dimensions. Groups of stocks with quite different average
returns have similar consumption risk (betas). And the average returns
on the stock market as a whole (relative to safe, short-term interest
rates) are too large to be justified by its consumption risk, unless
households are assumed to be implausibly risk averse.
My own work argues that in evaluating this theoretical
insight--that consumption risk determines how attractive an asset is and
thus its price and average return--it makes more sense to measure
ultimate consumption risk rather than the usual contemporaneous consumption risk. I find that ultimate consumption risk largely does
explain expected returns on stocks. The argument is that when a stock
declines, measured consumer spending may take a while to fall for
reasons that range from delay in measurement to hard-to-adjust
commitments to spend to inattention or near rationality. The finding
starts by defining ultimate consumption risk as the change in
consumption over a three-year horizon that includes and follows a return
that occurs over three months. Three years seems the right balance
between the increased signal about consumption risk from a longer
horizon and the greater mis-measurement of consumption risk that comes
from overlapping data and unexpected movements of consumption following
an asset return.
I show that measures of the ultimate consumption risk of the stock
market come closer to making the consumption-based understanding of
portfolio choice consistent with observed total stock market returns. I
find that the ultimate consumption risk of the stock market is about six
times what was previously measured by contemporaneous consumption risk.
(1) Furthermore, considering only the ultimate consumption risk of those
households that actually participate in the stock market yields an even
higher measure of consumption risk. (2) Finally, market returns are
higher following periods in which ultimate consumption risk is higher,
although that relationship is statistically weak. (3)
Returning to the wide differences in average returns across
different stocks, Christian Julliard and I show that ultimate
consumption betas do a good job of explaining the differences in
expected returns across stocks. (4) Differences in ultimate consumption
risk (a single factor) line up well with differences in average returns
across the Fama and French 25 portfolios and explain as much of the
variation as the Fama-French (three) factor model constructed from these
returns to price these portfolios. (5) This finding implies that the
differences in average returns known as the value premium and the size
premium are actually largely consistent with portfolio choice following
from ultimate consumption risk, with one exception. The exception is
that the risk aversion implied by this exercise still remains too large
to satisfactorily explain differences in returns from portfolio choices
in the canonical consumption-based model. Thus, it seems the theory has
some truth to its model--consumption risk matters--but maybe not enough.
Research on asset pricing is continuing by developing more complex
models of how consumption maps into riskiness. In these models, the
marginal value of consumption in a state of the world, or the state
price, is not based only on consumption in that state of the world, but
also on other factors, such as anxiety in that state of the world about
risk to future consumption. (6)
Perceptions of Risk and Reactions to Risk
My own work has focused not on modeling how anxiety varies across
states of the world but instead on how people's optimism varies and
how this in turn affects (among other things) portfolio choices and
asset prices. My co-authors and I build an economic model of situational
biases in beliefs and explore its behavioral implications. 7 We assume
that people have a natural bias towards optimism because it provides a
straightforward way for them to raise their expected discounted value of
utility. This optimism however is tempered by the severity of the
mistakes to which it would lead, leading to an equilibrium bias in
beliefs that affects their behavior.
Consistent with much experimental evidence on probability
assessments, our assumptions imply that optimism is pervasive because a
small bias in beliefs typically leads to first-order gains attributable
to increased anticipatory utility, and only to second-order costs
attributable to distorted behavior. Our model implies that biases in
expectations are situational. They are less rational when biases have
little cost in realized outcomes, or when biases have large benefits in
terms of expected future happiness. Markus Brunnermier, Filippos
Papakonstantinou, and I show that this approach is consistent with
observed optimism concerning task completion and evidence on how
environmental factors mitigate this problem and lead to better task
completion. (8)
Our general approach also provides insights into a number of
sometimes puzzling patterns of observed household investment choices and
the risks and returns of assets. (9) In a general equilibrium model with
complete markets, 1) because the cost of biased beliefs are
second-order, investors hold biased assessments of probabilities and so
are not perfectly diversified according to objective metrics; 2) because
the costs of biased beliefs temper these biases, the ex post costs of
the lack of diversification are limited; 3) because there is a
complementarity between believing a circumstance more likely and
purchasing more of the asset that pays off in that circumstance,
investors over-invest in assets that pay off in one future state of the
world and otherwise insure their consumption well; 4) because different
households can settle on different states of the world to be optimistic about, optimal portfolios of ex ante identical investors can be
heterogeneous; 5) because low-price and low-probability outcomes are the
cheapest to gamble on, optimism about these states distorts consumption
the least in the rest of the states, so that investors tend to
overinvest only in the most positively skewed securities; 6) finally,
because investors have higher demand for more skewed assets, more skewed
assets can have lower average returns.
While our theory is probably not ready for quantitative prediction,
some of its insights are consistent with more recent analyses of what
asset markets tell us about how households respond to risk. (10)
Saving, Spending, and Fiscal Stabilization Policy
Switching gears from how risk affects the way people allocate their
savings to how much people choose to consume and save, my co-authors and
I have studied how spending responds to changes in tax policy that
induce large predictable changes in people's after tax incomes.
This issue has generated a lot of interest lately, as the U.S.
government has recently lowered taxes and distributed stimulus payments
with the intention of raising consumer demand.
In theory, these types of policies might be futile. Tax changes
that lead to offsetting increases in future taxes, or reductions in
future benefits, have little effect on people's lifetime incomes
and so might lead to little adjustment in spending. And pre-announced
temporary tax changes that do not change tax distortions might lead only
to small persistent adjustments to spending upon announcement and no
changes when the funds are distributed. In practice, however households
do seem to respond significantly to some tax changes that lead to
predictable, temporary changes in after tax income. Using variation in
the timing of when households hit the Social Security tax cap during a
calendar year, I find large spending increases around the time of the
income increases. (11)
But the bigger question is the size of spending responses to
policies specifically designed to stimulate spending in recessions. In
both the summer of 2001 and the spring-summer of 2008, the Federal
government sent out billions of dollars of tax rebates or economic
stimulus payments in the hopes of stimulating aggregate demand. In each
instance, the timing of the distribution of the payments was based on
the second-to-last digit of the Social Security number of the tax filer
who received it, a digit that is effectively randomly assigned. The
policy experiment provided by the randomized mailing dates allows my
co-authors and me to identify the causal effect of the receipt of a
rebate on household spending by comparing the expenditures of households
who received rebates at different times. Of course to do this, one has
to have information on household expenditures, and we worked with the
Bureau of Labor Statistics and other government agencies which did
commendable work adding survey modules about the stimulus payments on
short notice to their existing survey of household expenditures. (12)
We find that in both 2001 and 2008, households spent roughly a
quarter of their rebate payments on a broad measure of nondurable spending. The circumstances in each recession were different however,
and other features of the responses were less similar. For example, in
the summer of 2008, gas prices had just risen significantly, and we find
that more than a third of the stimulus payments were spent on purchases
of new cars, whereas no significant amount was spent on cars in 2001.
[GRAPHIC OMITTED]
Our research does not allow us to infer how the economy would have
behaved without the payments, but it does measure the initial change in
aggregate demand for consumption caused by the distribution of the
payments. The household-level spending response estimated in our work
implies that the aggregate change was large, around 2 percent of
personal consumption expenditures (PCE) in the peak quarter. The figure
above shows monthly disposable personal income, PCE, and
PCE-less-our-estimated-initial-demand-effect of the 2008 economic
stimulus payments. The vertical axes each span a trillion dollars, so
income and consumption scales are comparable. The increase in disposable
income from the stimulus payments in May, June, and July is clearly
visible (dashed line). Our estimates imply that the spending response to
the payments was not immediate but, as the difference between the solid
and dotted lines shows, the policy was a substantial contributor to
strong consumption demand in the summer of 2008. While our research does
not quantify the general equilibrium impact of the stimulus payment
program--the size of the multiplier and the ultimate magnitude of its
impact on GDP and employment for example--in other work I argue for
using experiments like this to increase the accuracy of macroeconomic
models of such policies. Our results can help researchers to better
model steps in the causal chain from policy to the economy, critical
components of any model of macroeconomic policy, which are often only
weakly identified in current empirical investigations. (13)
The Rising Risk of High Incomes
The recession of 2008-9 was deep and unexpected, and in recent work
Annette Missing-Jorgensen and I investigate how if affected the incomes
of high-income households relative to middle-income households. We find
that the business cycle exposure of the income of the top 1 percent of
households has changed in fundamental ways. Further, this change seems
closely related to recent increases in inequality and thus is
potentially illuminating about why economic inequality in our society is
rising.
We know from previous research that since the early 1980s there has
been a large increase in the share of aggregate income received by
households at the very top of the income distribution. (14) We show that
at the same time, the business-cycle exposure of the earnings of these
high-income households has risen dramatically. (15) Since the early
1980s, the income of those in the top 1 percent of the income
distribution has averaged 14 times average income and been 2.4 times
more cyclical; prior to the early 1980s, the income of the top 1 percent
averaged nine times average income and was slightly less cyclical than
that of the average household. Thus, top incomes now rise much more than
average in booms and fall much more in recessions, where prior to 1980,
they rose and fell less than average.
One interesting question is whether high-income households use
other assets to insure this higher level of income risk. We show that
they do not. Looking at spending instead of income, we also find higher
exposure for the spending of high income households (as best we can
measure it). Thus it is likely that high-income households now bear a
greater share of macroeconomic risk than they used to. Analogous to the
use of the term "high-beta" to describe stocks that have high
exposure to risk (as discussed above), our findings have spawned the
term the "high-beta rich" to describe the new high exposure of
high-income households to macroeconomic risk. (16)
Why have the incomes of high-income households become more exposed
to macroeconomic risk? While the field is far from a definitive answer,
our research suggests a link between this increase in exposure to
macroeconomic risk and the increase in the share of income earned by the
top 1 percent. The rise in the exposure of top incomes to booms and
recessions not only starts at the same time as the rise in the
top's share of total income, but we also show that greater
top-income share is associated with greater top-income exposure across
decades, across subgroups of top incomes, and, in changes, across
countries. This close relationship suggests a common cause and does not
directly support the idea that the increase in inequality comes from
slowly changing social norms about pay, or from the idea that lower
income tax rates have caused a boom in top earnings. We put forward the
possibility that information and communication technologies have caused
both changes by increasing the optimal production scale of the most
talented and increasing the exposure of profits from these activities to
macroeconomic fluctuations.
Note that neither this theory nor our findings imply that
high-income households suffer more in recessions, nor do they imply that
the disproportionately higher incomes of the top 1 percent are
associated solely with greater production of socially valuable output.
In conclusion, my research on the ways in which households respond
to risk, to government transfers in recessions, and to income risks give
us clues to the determinants of asset returns, how effective
anti-recessionary policies are, and what is driving recent increases in
income inequality.
(1.) J.A. Parker, "The Consumption Risk of the Stock
Market," Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, 2, 2001, pp.
279-348.
(2.) This is found both in Parker (2001) and in Y. Ait-Sahalia, JA.
Parker, and M. Yogo, "Luxury Goods and the Equity Premium"
NBER Working Paper No. 8417, August 2001, and Journal of Finance, 59(6),
December 2004, pp. 2959-3004.
(3.) J.A. Parker, "Consumption Risk and Expected Stock
Returns," NBER Working Paper No. 9548, March 2003, and American
Economic Review, 93(2), May 2003, pp. 376-382.
(4.) J.A. Parker and C. Julliard, "Consumption Risk and the
Cross-Section of Expected Returns," NBER Working Paper No. 9538,
March 2003, and Journal of Political Economy, 113(1), February 2005, pp.
185-222.
(5.) See E.F. Fama and K.R. French, "The Cross-Section of
Expected Stock Returns," The Journal of Finance, 47, 1992, pp.
427-65.
(6.) See for example R. Bansal, D. Kiku, and A. Yaron, l'An
Empirical Evaluation of the Long-Run Risks Model for Asset Prices,"
NBER Working Paper No. 15504, November 2009; J. Beeler and J. Y.
Campbell, "The Long-Run Risks Model and Aggregate Asset Prices: An
Empirical Assessment," NBER Working Paper No. 14788, March 2009;
and R. Jagannathan and S. Marakani, "Long Run Risks &
Price/Dividend Ratio Factors," NBER Working Paper No. 17484,
October 2011.
(7.) M. K. Brunnermeier and JA. Parker, "Optimal
Expectations," NBER Working Paper No. 10707, August 2004 and
American Economic Review, 95(4), September 2005, pp. 1092-118.
(8.) M. K. Brunnermeier, F. Papakonstantinou, and J.A. Parker, 721n
Economic Model of the Planning Fallacy," NBER Working Paper No.
14228, August 2008.
(9.) M. K. Brunnermeier, C. Gollier, and A. Parker, "Optimal
Beliefs, Asset Prices, and the Preference for Skewed Returns," NBER
Working Paper 12940, February 2007 and American Economic Review, 97(2),
May 2007, pp. 159-65.
(10.) See for example T. G. Bali, N Cakici, and R. Whitelaw, Waxing
Out: Stocks as Lotteries and the Cross-Section of Expected Returns, NBER
Working Paper 14804, March 2009.
(11.) J.A. Parker, "The Reaction of Household Consumption to
Predictable Changes in Social Security Taxes," American Economic
Review, 89(4), September 1999, pp. 959-73. See also N Souleles,
"The Response of Household Consumption to Income Tax Refunds,"
American Economic Review, 89(4), September, 1999, pp. 947-58, and the
literature review in D. S. Johnson, J.A. Parker, and N S. Souleles,
"Household Expenditure and the Income Tax Rebates of
2001,"NBER Working Paper No. 10784, September 2004, and American
Economic Review, 96(5), December 2006, pp.1589-610.
(12.) J.A. Parker, N.S. Souleles, D.S. Johnson, and R. McClelland,
"Consumer Spending and the Economic Stimulus Payments of
2008," NBER Working Paper No. 16684, January 2011, and D. S.
Johnson et al., "Household Expenditure and the Income Tax Rebates
of 2001," op cit.
(13.) J.A. Parker, "On Measuring the Effects of Fiscal Policy
in Recessions," NBER Working Paper No. 17240, July 2011, and
Journal of Economic Literature, 49(3), September 2011, pp. 703-18.
(14.) See T. Piketty and E. Saez, "Income Inequality in the
United States, 1913-1998," NBER Working Paper No. 8467, September
2001, and Quarterly Journal of Economics, 118(1), February 2003, pp.
1-39.
(15.) J.A. Parker and A. Vissing-Jorgensen, "The Increase in
Income Cyclicality of High-Income Households and its Relation to the
Rise in Top Income Shares," NBER Working Paper No. 16577, December
2010, and Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, 41(2), Fall 2010, pp.
1-55, and JA. Parker and A. Vissing-Jorgensen, "Who Bears Aggregate
Fluctuations and How?" NBER Working Paper No. 14665, January 2009,
and American Economic Review, 99(2), May 2009, pp. 399-405.
(16.) Coined by Robert Frank in R. Frank, The High-Beta Rich: How
the Manic Wealthy Will Take Us to the Next Boom, Bubble, and Bust,
Random House, New York NY, 2011.
Jonathan A. Parker *
* Parker is a Research Associate in the NBER's Programs on
Asset Pricing, Economic Fluctuations and Growth, and Monetary Economics.
He is also a Professor at the Kellogg School of Management, Northwestern
University. His Profile appears later in this issue.