Economics of education.
Hoxby, Caroline M.
The Economics of Education Program is both exciting and productive,
currently adding new Working Papers at the rate of 7.5 per month--a 50
percent increase from the rate at the time of my last program report in
fall 2006. The number of papers submitted for a typical Program Meeting
is often ten times the number of available slots, and attendance at
those meetings is high.
I am particularly proud of three aspects of the Program. The first
is the quality of the research being produced and the methods used by
members, including some of the latest, most rigorous methods in applied
microeconometrics. The second is the fact that members use some of the
richest, most comprehensive datasets in economics--many of these
datasets were initially compiled by schools or school-related
organizations, and program members deserve enormous credit for their
resourcefulness in making them useful for economic research by
establishing strong, collegial relationships with data providers,
convincing schools to conduct randomized and other policy experiments,
matching data from diverse sources, and themselves surveying or testing
people when data otherwise would be missing. Third, program members
produce research that is policy relevant, credible to policymakers, and
grounded in economic logic.
The NBER's Higher Education Working Group was integrated into
the Economics of Education Program in 2009. We made the integration an
occasion to celebrate the leadership of Charles T. Clotfelter, director
of that working group, who oversaw an immense improvement in the quality
of research on the economics of higher education. Although the practical
policy questions differ across the two levels of education, all of the
methods, much of the data, and much of the deep economic logic are
shared.
Areas of Continuing Interest and New Interest
In my last review, I focused on three areas in which research was
advancing particularly rapidly: the analysis of peer effects; the
estimation of teachers' effects on achievement; and making sense of
students' college choices (not just whether to attend college in
the first place, but which schools to attend and whether to persist at
each school). These three areas continue to be highly productive. For
instance, Elias Bruegmann and C. Kirabo Jackson (15202) demonstrate
that, when a teacher whose own effect on achievement is strongly
positive moves into a new school, her new colleagues improve. They
further show that the colleagues' improved ability to raise
achievement is attributable to their changing, not merely to selection.
That is, incumbent teachers in the new school raise their performance.
For another example, we now have substantial evidence on what happens to
a student who goes to a school where other students are high-achieving:
his own achievement rises. This evidence relies on regression
discontinuity methods, that is, on comparing the later achievement of
students who are just above and just below some admissions threshold,
where the threshold is not known to students when they apply. Christian
Pop-Eleches and Miguel Urquiola (16886) study this situation in Romania;
Damon Clark ("Elite Schools and Academic Performance",
presented at the spring 2007 Program Meeting) studies this situation in
England; and C. Kirabo Jackson (16598) studies this situation in
Trinidad and Tobago. Turning to college-going behavior, some of the most
interesting new research provides rigorous evidence on how students
respond to scholarships and other financial aid designed to improve
their college outcomes. Aimee Chin and Chinhui Juhn (15932) show that
allowing undocumented students to pay in-state tuition (usually just
one-third to one-half of out-of-state tuition) has no statistically
significant effect on their college attendance. Stephens Desjardins and
Brian McCall ("The Impact of the Gates Millenium Scholars
Program", presented at the spring 2008 Program Meeting) show that
Gates Scholarships very modestly improved persistence among the
low-income minority students eligible for them.
Since my last report, several new themes also have emerged in
Economics of Education research. Two notable ones are the importance of
information and the role of incentives for students, teachers, and
schools. Because any program review is necessarily selective, I focus
here mainly on illustrating these new themes.
The Importance of Information
Much of the existing research on education concerns the change in
some concrete resource: a salary increase for teachers; a reduction in
class size; a scholarship or other financial aid for students; the
extension of compulsory schooling; or the opening of a program. Although
such resource changes often can be shown to change educational outcomes,
their effects typically are much smaller than proponents believed they
would be. Also, two students with similar prior achievement often react
to resources in very different ways. For instance, although making
financial aid more generous causes some students to attend college or to
persist longer in college, a good share of students do not respond.
Frustratingly for researchers, the students who do not respond often
look very similar to the students who do. (On this point, see for
instance the Desjardins and McCall paper mentioned above.) Put another
way, researchers have been unable to show that policymakers could
control and improve most people's educational outcomes simply by
controlling policies that are concerned with educational resources.
Responding to the weak explanatory power of resource-type policies,
researchers increasingly have wondered whether differences in
students' and families' information can account for variation
in educational outcomes. Recent findings from behavioral economics,
which often show that apparently small differences in the content or
framing of information can have large effects, have only intensified education researchers' focus on information. There are practical
reasons to focus on information as well: information interventions tend
to be very inexpensive compared to resource-type interventions (so that
even modest benefits may outweigh costs) and often have positive
spillovers (useful information given to one person tends to spread to
other people).
Eric Bettinger, Bridget Long, Philip Oreopoulos, and Lisa
Sanbonmatsu (15361) designed an experiment in coordination with the tax
preparer H&R Block. Some families with college-aged children were
randomly assigned to be given information on their child's
eligibility for government-based financial aid and on local
college-going options. Some families also were randomly assigned to
receive help in filing the federal application for financial aid
("FAFSA"). The results, which are highly credible owing to the
randomized design, suggest that the intervention that combined
information and FAFSA help actually caused people to be 25 to 30 percent
more likely to enroll in college. These effects are dramatic in size for
such a modest intervention--one that, if implemented routinely, would
cost only a few dollars per family.
Todd Stinebrickner and Ralph Stinebrickner (14810) investigate
whether students learn about their academic ability in college and make
decisions about persisting in a logical way, based on that information.
To study this question, they combine rich administrative data from Berea
College with data from surveys they conducted themselves. Thus, they are
able to observe not just students' academic behavior, such as their
course-taking patterns and the grades they earn, but also students'
beliefs about their academic aptitude and expectations about college
completion. The authors show that students enter college with beliefs
about their academic ability that are both optimistic and diffuse.
Moreover, the students update their beliefs in the manner predicted by
the Bayesian learning model. Students' learning about their own
aptitude explains much of their decision to drop out of college.
Amanda Pallais ("Why Not Apply?" presented at the spring
2008 Program Meeting) shows that an apparently tiny change in ACT policy
produced a 20 percent increase in students' applications to
colleges. The change was that ACT, one of the two college aptitude
testing organization in the United States, gave students four free score
reports instead of three. Because an additional score report cost only
$6 before and after the policy change, the intervention was negligible
when viewed against the background of family income or the potential
returns to college attendance. Yet, the policy change caused about 40
percent of students to send their scores to an additional school. This
generated some additional information for students because, when a
student who is a plausible applicant sends his scores to a school, that
school responds with brochures and other materials describing its
offerings. It is striking that such a modest change in information
produced such sizable effects on behavior.
Avery and Turner ("Playing the College Application Game",
presented at the fall 2009 Program Meeting) and Avery and Hoxby
("The Missing One-Offs", presented at the 2010 Summer
Institute) demonstrate that low-income students apply to fewer and less
selective colleges than their more affluent counterparts who have the
same test scores and achievement in high school. This fact holds even
for low-income students whose achievement is so high that they qualify
for free tuition and living expenses at the most selective colleges in
the United States. The authors of these papers assemble an array of
evidence that indicates that low-income students lack information about
college-going. While it is hard to argue that these students do not have
access to materials (since most colleges' materials are readily
available online), they have few contacts with people who attended
selective colleges. They are frequently too isolated geographically to
find a critical mass of college-going peers or advisors. In fact, the
latter paper shows that it would not even make sense for selective
colleges' staff to visit the schools or cities of most low-income,
high-achieving students: they are simply too isolated for the benefits
of such visits to outweigh the costs. The bottom line is that
information interventions might be warranted, but they may prove hard to
design--see Avery (16359).
Informational differences among students are also important in
primary and secondary education. Parag Pathak and Tayfun Sonmez (16783;
also "Leveling the Playing Field," 2008 Summer Institute) show
that school choice mechanisms that are susceptible to strategic
manipulation tend to generate better outcomes for families who are more
informed. That is, although all students have the same opportunities
under these mechanisms, students who understand how the mechanisms work
and which schools are in demand end up enrolling in schools that are
higher in their preference rankings. These better informed students
disproportionately have parents who are affluent and educated. Thus,
superior information is one reason why students' outcomes are
correlated with their family's socioeconomic circumstances.
Abigail Wozniak and Ofer Malamud (16463) explore another reason why
students from more educated families have better outcomes. They
investigate the long-standing hypothesis that more educated people
respond more elastically to changes in opportunities. (Theodore W
Schultz often is credited with originating this idea. See Bowman, 1980,
cited in endnote.) Specifically, Wozniak and Malamud investigate people
who were induced to attend college because they had a higher risk of
being drafted for the Vietnam War. They use draft induction risk as an
instrument for attending and graduating from college, and they show that
college education makes a person more likely to subsequently choose his
labor market experience based on expected earnings, as opposed to the
market's mere proximity to his place of origin.
School report cards--simple reports that describe students'
achievement in absolute terms and relative to other local schools--are
very inexpensive to provide. Asim Khwaja, Tahir Andrabi, and Jishnu Das
("Report Cards," spring 2009 Program Meeting) arranged to
provide reports in 112 randomly selected educational markets in
Pakistan. The intervention was purely informational: no explicit rewards
or punishments were included. The authors find that the report cards
improved learning by 0.10 standard deviations and increased enrollment
slightly. Private schools that were initially bad--those with below
median scores at baseline--improved especially strongly: learning gains
were 0.34 standard deviations. Private schools that were initially good
did not improve learning but did cut their fees. Government schools were
somewhat less responsive than private schools. The authors interpret
these results as showing that report cards generate competitive pressure
on schools to increase price-adjusted quality.
Jonah Rockoff, Douglas Staiger, Thomas Kane, and Eric Taylor
(16240) study another informational intervention that appears small yet
had big effects. They evaluate the effect of a program in which New York
City school principals were provided with estimates of how much each of
their teachers had raised students' test scores. Principals were
randomly assigned to this program, so the study's findings are
highly credible. The authors show that principals update their beliefs
about teachers' effects in accordance with the Bayesian learning
model: for instance, principals update their beliefs more when the
estimates provided to them are more precise and their own prior opinions
are less precise. More importantly, principals are likelier to retain
their effective teachers (and not retain their ineffective ones) when
they are provided with the estimated teacher effects. The change in the
sensitivity of retention to performance improves student achievement by
a statistically significant though small amount. Here, it is worthwhile
to remember the cost-benefit ratios typical of information
interventions: although the change in achievement is small, the cost of
the intervention is very small on an ongoing basis.
Finally, Eric Taylor and John Tyler (16877) examine a highly
reputed teacher evaluation system and find that it improves
teachers' performance, as measured by their effects on student
achievement. While the cost-benefit ratio of the program they study is
not as impressive as the results of the information program in New York
City (16240), the improvement that Taylor and Tyler see is entirely
within teacher. As a rule, it has been hard for researchers to produce
credible evidence that teachers improve simply through being evaluated
and then informed about how to improve their instruction. Even if such
evaluation systems are an expensive means of improving achievement
relative to some of the informational interventions described above,
they remain inexpensive relative to most resource-type interventions.
Incentives for Students, Teachers, and Schools
Even though improving incentives is often more expensive than
improving information, incentive-type interventions are often much less
expensive than resource-type interventions, especially when their
relative efficacy is taken into account. This is shown by an array of
recent research done by program members.
Joshua Angrist, Daniel Lang, and Philip Oreopoulos (12790) and
Joshua Angrist, Philip Oreopoulos, and Tyler Williams (16643) explore
incentives for students to improve their grades in a Canadian
university. In the former paper, they study students who are randomly
assigned to receive a merit scholarship if they maintain solid grades.
In the second paper, they study students who are randomly assigned to
receive cash for better grades: $100 for each grade of 70 or better and
an additional $20 for each percentage point above 70 percent. They find
that the merit scholarship improved the grades and persistence of female
students, though not of males. Interestingly, they also find that the
availability of the merit scholarship caused female students to seek out
more help with their courses: they were more likely to take advantage of
supplemental instructional services. In the latter paper, the authors
find that the cash rewards improved males' achievement, though not
females! The effects on males are modest overall, but larger for males
who understood the function linking performance to rewards.
Judith Scott-Clayton ("On Money and Motivation", fall
2008 program meeting) studies a West Virginia incentive scheme for
college students. The program offered free tuition to students who
maintained a certain minimum course load and minimum GPA (2.75 in the
freshmen year, 3.0 thereafter). Since students were not randomly
assigned to the program, Scott-Clayton exploits differences in the
timing of implementation and discontinuities in the eligibility formula
to generate credible estimates. Not only does she find substantial
effects on achievement, she also finds that the effects are highly
concentrated around the thresholds for annual scholarship renewal,
indicating that the program's effects come via the incentives it
provides, not simply via relaxing financial constraints.
C. Kirabo Jackson (15722) studies incentives for students and
teachers based on Advanced Placement (AP) scores. The program he
analyzes ("APIP") pays high school students and their teachers
between $100 and $500 per score of three or above on an AP exam. To give
a sense of magnitude of rewards that a person could earn, the maximum
that a teacher has ever earned in one year is $11,500, and the maximum
that a student has ever earned in high school is $1,400. Because the
program is not randomly assigned to schools, Jackson has to use a
detrended difference-in-differences strategy: essentially, the
achievement trends of schools that adopted the program earlier are
compared to the achievement trends of schools that adopted it later.
Because the program's sponsors were not able to roll out the
program in a single year to every school interested in adoption, the
late adopters are fairly idiosyncratically selected from among schools
who applied. Thus, the results are quite credible. Jackson finds that
students who participate in the program are more likely to attend
college and persist in college beyond their freshman year. In addition,
Black and Hispanic students are more likely to graduate from college.
Eric Bettinger (16333) examines cash incentives for students funded
by a philanthropist in Coshocton, a poor city in the Appalachian area of
Ohio. Schools and grades in the city were randomly assigned to have
their students get rewards of up $75 per year for "proficient"
scores and $100 per year for "advanced" scores on Ohio's
statewide exams. Bettinger finds that the incentives improve math scores
by 0.15 standard deviations but he does not find similar effects on
other subject exams. The Coshocton program was highly beneficial
relative to its costs: the program costs were only fifteen hundredths of
1 percent (0.15 percent) of the district's per-pupil expenditures.
The effects of this inexpensive program on achievement were 250 times
what we would predict if the district had spent the same amount on class
size reduction. (The class size comparison is based on Project Star,
which generates some of the highest credibly estimated effects of class
size reduction.)
Karthik Muralidharan and Venkatesh Sundararaman (15323) investigate
performance pay for teachers, using a program in India that they
themselves largely designed. Hundreds of schools were randomly assigned
to have their teachers receive higher pay for higher students'
scores. Hundreds of schools were assigned to an alternative treatment
that gave them additional resources equal to the value of the
performance pay. Muralidharan and Sundararaman find that students in
incentive schools improved their performance by 0.28 and 0.16 standard
deviations in math and language tests, relative to control scores.
Students scored significantly higher on "conceptual" as well
as "mechanical" components of the tests and also performed
better on subjects for which no incentives were given. These results
suggest that the students' gains in achievement were authentic, not
mere "teaching to the test." The gains in schools that simply
received the extra resources were one-third to one-half as large as the
incentive-driven gains.
Several authors have examined what happens when schools face
incentives. For instance, Jonah Rockoff and Lesley Turner (14564) and
Hanley Chiang ("Accountability Pressure on Failing Schools,"
fall 2008 Program Meeting) use regression discontinuity methods to show
that schools that "just fail" according to their state's
accountability program raise their students' achievement more than
schools that "just pass." In these two studies, failing
schools faced several possible consequences: students could transfer
out, principals could lose their jobs, and schools could be closed
completely (though this was rare). Since the passing thresholds were
unknown to schools in advance, the regression discontinuity designs
produce convincing results.
A very different source of school incentives--competitive pressures
generated by private school vouchers--is analyzed by David Figlio and
Cassandra Hart (16056) and by Winnie Chan and Robert McMillan
("School Choice and Public School Performance, fall 2009 program
meeting). Although the authors investigate programs in different
locations--Figlio and Hart analyze a Florida corporate tax credit
program and Chan and McMillan analyze a tax credit program in
Ontario--both teams of authors exploit variation in pressure on public
schools that arises through pre-existing differences in the local
availability of private schools. Both teams find that public schools
respond to the potential loss of students to private schools by raising
their students' achievement. Neither team of authors finds evidence
that differential student sorting (poor students disproportionately
leaving the public schools) accounts for the improvement.
Summing Up
New themes emerge in research because researchers find themselves
convinced by previous studies that some questions remain answered,
thereby exposing other questions as likely to be important. Thus, I
think that it is a measure of the success of the NBER's Economics
of Education Program that, although some recent research extends and
elaborates themes I identified previously, I did not predict the themes
of much recent research in my previous program review. In particular, it
is encouraging that so much current research focuses on issues like
information and incentives that economists have long regarded as
important. That information and incentive-type interventions also tend
to have propitious cost-benefit ratios is a bonus. Finally, it is
important that NBER researchers continue to pioneer rigorous
methodological designs and create good data that allow them to analyze
such interventions.
M.J. Bowman, "Theodore W. Schultzs Contributions to
Economics" The Scandinavian Journal of Economics, Vol. 82, No. 1
(1980), pp. 80-107
Caroline M. Hoxby, Hoxby is the Director of the NBER's Program
on Economics of Education and the Scott and Donya Bommer Professor of
Economics at Stanford University. The numbers in parends throughout this
report refer to NBER Working Papers. A complete list of NBER Education
Working Papers can be found at: www.nber.org/papersbyprog/ED.html