A summary of recent corporate tax research.
Graham, John R.
Taxes are thought to influence corporate decisions in many ways.
For that reason, in the past decade a number of changes (or proposed
changes) to the U.S. tax code have been made in an attempt to affect
corporate behavior. For example, U.S. and European authorities have
raised the possibility of eliminating or reducing the ability of
companies to deduct interest payments from taxable income, because the
tax-favored status of debt has reduced tax revenue collection and
allegedly encouraged a "debt bias" of corporations. It is
believed that by using too much debt financing, firms may have
exacerbated economic downturns. Also, during the last two recessions, in
an attempt to stimulate the corporate sector, the U.S. government has
temporarily granted companies the ability to carry current-year losses
back five years, in order to receive a refund on taxes paid during the
past five years. Further, equity tax rates have been decreased for
retail investors in an attempt to reduce the corporate cost of capital,
and these changes are thought to have increased dividend payout. And,
there have been proposals to disallow multinational companies from
avoiding income taxes on profits earned overseas by their reinvesting
those profits overseas. In this report, I summarize academic research on
these and related issues.
In 1958 Modigliani and Miller (M&M) laid the groundwork for
modern corporate finance research by demonstrating that when capital and
informational markets are perfect, firm value is not affected by
financial decisions. Five years later they showed that the existence of
taxation can create an environment in which financial decisions affect
firm value. In particular, M&M demonstrated that when corporate
income is taxed and debt interest is a deductible expense, firm value
can be increased by using debt financing rather than funding entirely
from equity.
Several branches of research emanated from these basic insights.
The first addresses whether the tax environment leads to firm-specific
optimal capital structures and value enhancement. If there are costs to
using too much debt (for example, expected financial distress costs or
personal taxes on interest income), then firms with the greatest benefit
to shielding taxes (for example, firms facing higher income tax rates)
should be the ones with the greatest incentives to use debt financing.
Much of my tax research focuses on how to measure these tax incentives
in the context of a dynamic tax code.
One important feature of the tax code is that a firm can
"carry back" current losses (by refiling past tax returns) to
receive a tax refund for taxes paid in recent years. Alternatively, if
carrying back losses is not attractive, then firms can carry forward
losses to offset taxable income in future years. Therefore, because the
dynamic tax code allows firms to move income through time, it is
necessary to forecast future taxable income to estimate current-period
tax rates and tax incentives.
Capital Structure Choices and Simulating Corporate Marginal Income
Tax Rates
In my early work, I simulated dynamic corporate marginal income tax
rates that could explain the probability that a firm will be nontaxable
and that allow it to carry losses forward and backward. I then used
these simulated tax rates to document that firms respond to tax
incentives when they make incremental financing choices, (1) and when
they choose the level of debt and the level of leasing. (2) These
corporate tax incentives hold up even in the presence of high personal
tax rates on interest income. (3)
Most tax and capital structure research, including the work just
mentioned, uses data drawn from financial statements, not data from
actual tax returns. Given that financial statements consolidate
worldwide income statements and balance sheets for multinational firms,
but that tax rules and tax incentives vary by country, one might wonder
how closely financial-statement-based research mirrors tax return data.
(4) In recent work, Lillian Mills and I access confidential tax returns
to explore how closely tax rates estimated from financial statement data
parallel those based on tax return data. (5) Fortunately, we find that
simulated tax rates based on financial statement data are very highly
correlated with tax variables based on tax return data.
Capital Structure--Debt Bias
Documenting that tax rates are correlated with corporate capital
structure choices suggests that firms may increase value by choosing
debt optimally. However, some argue that an increased use of debt in
response to tax incentives leads to negative outcomes. After all, the
extent to which firms are able to increase value occurs directly because
deducting interest expenses deprives the government of tax revenues.
More than just reducing tax revenues, a "debt bias"--using
extra debt in response to tax incentives--could result in too much debt
in the system, increasing the probability that firms will become
financially distressed, and thereby exacerbating or perhaps even causing
economic downturns. Critics of debt bias argue that the ability to
deduct interest should be eliminated or at least reduced. For this
argument to have its greatest force, it should be the case that 1) tax
incentives lead to a large increase in the use of debt, and that 2) the
"extra" debt that firms use in response to tax incentives
should lead to a material increase in the probability of experiencing
financial distress.
Regarding whether taxes have a first-order effect on the use of
debt, I have documented that a tax rate that is 10 percentage points
higher (for example, 34 percent instead of the mean 24 percent) leads to
debt usage that is 0.7 percent higher. Thus, while taxes do affect
capital structure, the effect is moderate, providing only partial
evidence of the first debt bias consideration. Regarding whether the
extra debt usage increases the odds of encountering distress, two
co-authors and I search for these effects when one might expect the
negative effects of excess leverage to be at their worst: during the
severe economic contractions during the Great Depression and during the
years 2008-9. (6) In the first stage of our analysis, we show that firms
did in fact use more debt because of tax incentives during the
Depression. However, we do not find any evidence that this extra debt
increased the probability of encountering distress. Similarly, we do not
find any evidence that debt bias led to negative outcomes during the
recent recession. It is important to note that our failure to find
negative effects of debt bias could be attributable to noise in the data
(especially during the Depression era) and to our focus on nonfinancial
firms. Clearly, there needs to be more research on this important issue
in general, and with respect to financial firms in particular.
Capital Structure--Tax Benefit Functions
One way to measure how much interest tax savings contribute to firm
value involves estimating marginal tax benefit functions--that is,
measuring the marginal tax benefit of each incremental dollar of tax
deduction. By adding up the value created by each incremental dollar of
interest deduction, one can estimate the contribution to firm value
associated with the tax savings that flow from a given level of interest
deductions. Two co-authors and I follow this approach and estimate that
the equilibrium, gross tax benefit of interest deductions (ignoring all
costs) equals about 10.5 percent of value across all firms, and about
twice that much for the top decile of companies. (7)
Analogous to using supply shifts to identify demand curves, we use
exogenous variation in benefit functions to deduce the cost-of-debt
function that justifies the capital structure choices that firms make.
By summing the area under the cost functions up to a given amount of
debt, we estimate that the equilibrium all-in expected cost of debt
equals about 7 percent of firm value. By summing up the area between the
cost and benefit functions, we estimate that the equilibrium net
benefits of debt (net of all costs) are about 3.5 percent of firm value.
Again, these numbers are fairly moderate and do not suggest pervasive
high leverage caused by severe debt bias.
Tax-Loss Carrybacks and Economic Stimulus
For the most part, U.S. companies in recent decades have been able
to carry back current-period losses to receive a refund for taxes paid
in the past two years. This feature of the tax code serves as an
economic stabilizer by providing an infusion of liquidity to (previously
profitable) companies that are currently struggling. During the last two
recessions, the carryback period was temporarily lengthened to five
years in an attempt to stimulate the corporate sector during an economic
downturn.
Hyunseob Kim and I examine the economic impact of the stimulus
during the most recent recession. (8) Companies were given the option to
carry back losses from either their 2008 tax year or their 2009 tax year
to receive a refund for taxes paid during the previous five years. Had
the carryback period remained at two years, we estimate the carryback
feature of the tax code would have provided $77 billion in tax refunds;
allowing losses to be carried back an additional three years added an
incremental $54 billion in tax refunds to corporate coffers (this
estimate ignores TARP recipients and the tax benefits granted to them).
Interestingly, the increased benefit was particularly valuable to
sectors that were hugely profitable during the economic boom of the
mid-2000s but then suffered the greatest losses during the recession:
housing, finance, and autos. That is, the U.S. government supported
firms in these industries via changes to the tax code.
Payout Policy
One feature of the famous 2003 "Bush tax cuts" was to
reduce the maximum tax rate on both qualifying dividends and capital
gains to 15 percent, from 38 percent and 20 percent, respectively. This
relative reduction in dividend taxation thus made dividends more
attractive to taxable individual investors. (9) Given this increased
investor preference for dividends, one might expect companies to begin
to pay out a larger proportion of profits via dividends. Research shows
that there was a surge of dividend initiations following the May 2003
implementation of these tax breaks and that dividend hikes were largest
at the companies that had the greatest net tax incentive to increase
dividends, such as firms with proportionally more individual investors
(which makes sense given that the tax cut was focused on individuals).
Chetty and Saez show that the dividend increases were less likely to
occur in firms for which the executives owned substantial stock options
(which makes sense because options are not dividend protected, meaning
that paying a dividend reduces the value of existing options). (10)
Thus, investor-level taxes affect corporate payout choices.
However, are taxes the dominant force driving payout policy? Based on
surveys and one-on-one interviews, three co-authors and I document that
CFOs agree with the general conclusion that firms increased dividends in
response to the reduction in retail investor dividend tax rates--but we
conclude that the 2003 tax effect on corporate payout decisions was
overall moderate. (11) Executives indicate that non-tax conditions (such
as generating long-run, sustainable earnings or facing lower growth
prospects) are the first-order factors that determine payout policy and
also determine whether a particular firm is at a margin where taxes
would affect its payout decisions. In summary, most CFOs say that tax
considerations matter but taxes are not the dominant factor in their
decisions about whether to increase dividends or choose dividends over
share repurchases.
Taxes on Foreign Profits
Economics and politics have merged into a contentious debate
related to the extent to which U.S. firms should pay U.S. taxes on
profits earned by their foreign divisions and subsidiaries. Under
current law, taxes are paid to foreign authorities as the profits are
earned--but taxes are not paid to the U.S. tax authority until the
profits are returned home ("repatriated") to the domestic
parent. By surveying tax executives, two-coauthors and I learn that the
ability to defer paying U.S. taxes is in fact one of the most important
reasons that U.S. companies invest overseas. (12) Opponents of these tax
rules argue that evidence like this is proof that U.S. firms shift jobs
overseas to the detriment of domestic employment. (Supporters of the
repatriation tax rules argue that they help U.S. firms compete
overseas.)
If foreign profits are repatriated home, they are then taxed at a
rate essentially equal to the degree to which the U.S. tax rate exceeds
the tax rate in the foreign jurisdiction in which they were earned (for
example, profits earned and taxed at an Irish corporate tax rate of 13
percent would be taxed an additional 22 percent when returned to the
United States because the U.S. corporate income tax rate is 35 percent).
In 2004, Congress passed the American Jobs Creation Act, which allowed
firms to repatriate profits to the United States subject to a tax rate
of no more than 5.25 percent and often much lower. Our research
documents that many firms embraced this tax break and bought profits
home to the United States. Perhaps surprisingly, we also show that some
firms did not repatriate earnings, even at low repatriation tax rates,
and even though repatriation would have a positive effect on actual cash
flows, because it would lead to a reduction in reported earnings. That
is, even at low tax rates repatriation is at times avoided by firms
because it reduces earnings per share, which financial executives
believe in turn hurts stock price. Interestingly, Senator Kay Hagen
recently proposed instituting another "one time" reduction in
taxes owed on repatriated profits. Justification for such a proposal is
unclear given that, overall, academic research into the 2004 reduction
in repatriation taxes does not provide clear evidence that on net firms
used the funds brought home to increase investment or hiring.
In summary, the tax code is constantly under revision, in part in
an attempt by authorities to alter corporate behavior. Recent research
documents that tax incentives do affect corporate behavior, but the
effects are often modest. I look forward to future research that helps
explain why tax effects are not always as large as we might expect,
whether the reason be measurement issues, offsetting nontax influences,
or unanticipated changes in corporate behavior that occur as the economy
re-equilibrates.
(1) J. R. Graham, "Debt and the Marginal Tax Rate,"
Journal of Financial Economics, 41, 1996, pp. 41-74.
(2) J. R. Graham, M. Lemmon, and J. Schallheim, "Debt, Leases,
Taxes, and the Endogeneity of Corporate Tax Status" Journal of
Finance, 53, 1998, pp. 131-62.
(3) J. R. Graham, "Do Personal Taxes Affect Corporate
Financing Decisions?" Journal of Public Economics, 73, 1999, pp.
147-85.
(4) For details, see J. R. Graham, J. Raedy, and D. Shackleford,
Accounting for Income Taxes" NBER Working Paper No. 15665, January
2010, and Journal of Accounting and Economics forthcoming
(5) J. R. Graham and L. Mills, "Using Tax Return Data to
Simulate Corporate Marginal Tax Rates" NBER Working Paper No.
13709, December 2007, and Journal of Accounting and Economics, 446:2-3,
2008, pp. 366-88.
(6) J.R. Graham, S. Hazarika, and K. Narasimhan, "Financial
Distress during the Great Depression" NBER Working Paper No. 17388,
August 2011, and Financial Management, forthcoming.
(7) J. van Binsbergen, J. R. Graham, and J. Yang, "The Cost of
Debt" NBER Working Paper No. 16023, May 2010, and Journal of
Finance 65:6, 2010, pp. 2089-136.
(8) J.R. Graham, and H. Kim, "The Effects of the Length of the
Tax-Loss Carry back Period on Tax Receipts and Corporate Marginal Tax
Rates" NBER Working Paper No. 15177, July 2009, and National Tax
Journal, 62, 2009, pp. 413-27.
(9) Alok Kumar and I find that individual investors form clienteles
based on tax preferences of holding dividends and that individual
investors shift holdings to tax-deferred accounts in response to higher
income tax rates. See J.R. Graham and A. Kumar, "Do Dividend
Clienteles Exist? Evidence on Dividend Preferences of Retail
Investors" Journal of Finance 61, 2006, pp. 1305-336.
(10) R. Chetty and E. Saez, "Dividend Taxes and Corporate
Behavior: Evidence from the 2003 Dividend Tax Cut," NBER Working
Paper No. 10841, October 2004; J. Poterba, "Taxation and Corporate
Payout Policy" NBER Working Paper No. 10321, February 2004; J.
Bouin, J. Raedy, and D. Shackelford, "Did Dividends Increase
Immediately After the 2003 Reduction in Tax Rates?" NBER Working
Paper No. 10301, February 2004.
(11) A. Brav, J. R. Graham, C. R. Harvey, and R. Michaely,
"Payout Policy in the 21st Century" NBER Working Paper No.
9657, April 2003, and Journal of Financial Economics, 77:3, 2005, pp.
483-527.
(12) J.R. Graham, M. Hanlon, and T. Shevlin, "Real Effects of
Accounting Rules: Evidence from Multinational Firms Investment Location
and Profit Repatriation Decisions" Journal of Accounting Research,
49,2011, pp. 137-85.
John R. Graham *
* John Graham is a Research Associate in the NBER's Corporate
Finance Program and a professor of Finance at Duke University. His
Profile appears later in this issue.