Environmental and energy economics.
Fullerton, Don
The NBER'S Program on Environmental and Energy Economics (EEE)
was initiated in 2007, but has grown to 80 members and 240 NBER Working
Papers in less than three years. The Program's research is broad
and diverse. Program members study topics as varied as pollution
abatement technology, the role of "pollution havens,"
regulated electricity markets, pollution-tax incidence, and the effects
of environmental policy on employment, morbidity, and mortality. Because
this body of research is too broad and too diverse to summarize in one
Program Report, I will touch on only a few topics here.
Gasoline Use and Vehicle Emissions
Numerous federal policies are directed at the reduction of gasoline
consumption, with the aim being to improve environmental quality and to
reduce oil imports. Recent research covers a range of such policies,
including gasoline taxes, fuel-efficiency regulation, and alternative
fuel subsidies. the current federal tax is 18.4 cents/gallon, with state
taxes adding about 30 cents more. Changes to the tax at the state level
are frequent, as are proposals to alter the federal tax. The sharp
gasoline price increases experienced through 2008 offer a valuable
source of variation for examining the influence of gasoline price on the
vehicle fleet.
Meghan Busse, Christopher Knittel, and Florian Zettelmeyer use this
price variation to examine changes in the price and composition of cars
purchased. (1) They find that each $1 increase in the gas price causes
more than a 20 percent change in new car sales at the high and low end
of fuel efficiency, and changes the resale price for used cars by as
much as $3000. Shanjun Li, Roger von Haefen, and Christopher Timmins
investigate the effect on the fleet as a whole, showing that each 10
percent increase from the $2.34 per gallon price in 2005 generated
improvements in fuel economy that were only 0.22 percent in the short
run and 2 percent in the long run. (2)
Politically, direct mandates have proven more successful in
achieving their goals than gasoline taxes. Still, recent increases in
required fuel efficiency of about 30 percent by 2016 raise questions
about technological feasibility. However, Knittel draws from a long
time-series of vehicle characteristics, estimating shifts in the
technological frontier of fuel economy, weight, and power, (3) and finds
that if technological progress since 1980 had been put toward fuel
economy rather than weight and power, it could have reduced fuel use by
50 percent. Meeting the strict new rules may require little more than
halting the observed increases in weight and horsepower, he concludes.
Lawrence Goulder, Mark Jacobsen, and Arthur van Benthem examine
ambitious new state-level mandates on fuel economy. (4) Fourteen states
have agreed to improve fuel economy by about 45 percent for the 2020
model year, expecting large savings in gasoline use within their
borders. Yet 65 to 75 percent of these savings may be offset in the rest
of the country. Federal rules are applied nationwide, so more fuel
economy in some states means that less is required elsewhere. This issue
of overlapping jurisdictions also applies to low carbon fuel standards
and to proposals for greenhouse gas reductions.
Some policies and proposals would encourage alternative fuels such
as ethanol through subsidies, mandates, and standards. Stephen Holland,
Knittel, and Jonathan Hughes examine the low carbon-fuel standard, a
mandate on the average ethanol content of fuels in California. (5) That
standard implicitly taxes conventional fossil fuel and subsidizes
ethanol; yet the impact of the subsidy component can outweigh the tax
and result in more overall emissions of carbon dioxide. Other policies
to encourage ethanol production avoid this effect.
Mandated increases in ethanol production from corn also create
pressure on world food supplies. Michael Roberts and Wolfram Schlenker
calculate that mandated ethanol production in the United States will
consume 5 percent of world caloric production from corn, wheat, rice,
and soybeans. (6) They show that U.S. mandates alone could increase
world food prices by 20 to 30 percent.
Each of these policies would alter miles driven and change the
vehicle fleet, in turn influencing traffic congestion and trade
patterns. Lucas Davis and Matthew Kahn study the trade in used vehicles
to Mexico, showing that 2.5 million used vehicles were exported in the
four years following the North American Free Trade Agreement. (7)
Policies that influence the future of the U.S. vehicle fleet therefore
can be expected to affect the Mexican fleet, altering gasoline use in
both countries.
Energy Markets
Heightened concerns about climate change have fuelled interest in
making energy production and consumption more efficient and less carbon
intensive. Leading climate policy proposals would price the externality,
so that the cost of energy includes all social costs, but this approach
presumes that current energy prices paid by consumers already reflect
private supply costs. However, Lucas Davis and Eric Muehlegger document
significant departures from marginal cost pricing in domestic natural
gas markets. (8) They estimate that residential and commercial gas
customers face an average markup of more than 40 percent over the period
1991-2007.
A paper by Steven Davis, Cheryl Grim, John Haltiwanger, and Mary
Streitwieser studies the electricity prices paid by U.S. manufacturing
plants from 1963 to 2000. (9) They document tremendous dispersion in
electricity prices paid by manufacturers and they find that marginal
supply costs exceed marginal prices for smaller manufacturing customers
by 10 percent or more.
The energy sector also is affected by market failures associated
with technology innovation and diffusion. Policies that aim to
accelerate the development and adoption of clean energy technologies
have become an important component of environmental policy more broadly.
Gilbert Metcalf analyzes the impacts of incentives for energy investment
offered under the Federal tax code. (10) He concludes that the Federal
production tax credit has played an important role in increasing
investment in wind energy development over the past decade.
Asking a slightly different question, David Popp and Richard Newell
posit that new investment in the development of climate change
mitigation technologies comes at the expense of other investment. (11)
Linking patent data and financial data by firm, they ask whether
increases in alternative energy R and D are likely to represent new R
and D spending, or how much of the additional climate change R and D
comes at the expense of other types of patenting activity. Although they
find evidence of crowding out for alternative energy firms, they also
find that alternative energy patents are cited more frequently, and by a
wider range of other technologies, than other patents by these firms,
suggesting that their social value is higher.
In addition to environmental externalities and the imperfect
appropriability of the returns to R and D, sub-optimal investment in
energy efficiency and conservation may be the result of a series of
market barriers, market failures, and cognitive failures. These
distortions help to rationalize more prescriptive policy interventions,
including appliance standards and building energy efficiency codes. EEE
Program Members evaluate the impacts of these programs and test some of
their underlying assumptions. Using detailed micro data from California,
for example, Dora Costa and Matthew Kahn show that the phase-in of
building codes in 1983 has effectively reduced residential electricity
consumption. (12) Jacobsen and Kotchen analyze the impacts of a more
recent building code change in Florida. (13) Using household-level
billing data from Gainesville, they conclude that the increased
stringency of the energy code is associated with a statistically and
economically significant reduction in both electricity and natural gas
consumption.
Economic Effects of Environmental Policy
Environmental and energy policy can affect employment,
productivity, and growth, as well as emissions and overall economic
welfare. Alternative policies differ in terms of these effects, and
therefore deserve study. These policies certainly affect the price and
availability of natural resources, including fisheries, (14) land, (15)
water, (16) and petroleum. (17)
Policies for environmental protection may affect the benefit or
value of ecosystem services. Jared Carbone and Kerry Smith investigate
how willingness to pay for such services depends on changes in demand
for complementary market goods, where these demands can change with
pollution regulations. (18) As a result, partial equilibrium estimates
differ from general equilibrium calculations. Arik Levinson matches
survey happiness data with EPA air quality data to infer the dollar
value of air quality. (19) A major economic impact of environmental
policies is their overall cost. Because air quality varies through the
course of the year, Maureen Cropper and her co-authors demonstrate that
costs can be reduced by limiting driving more on high-ozone days, for
example by selling fewer permits to drive on those days. (20) Meredith
Fowlie, Knittel, and Catherine Wolfram find higher marginal abatement
costs for stationary sources than for mobile sources, indicating further
cost reductions from reallocation of abatement between those sources.
(21)
Environmental protection also has important effects on technology,
(22) trade, (23) and human health. Using random variations in annual
temperature, Olivier Deschenes and Michael Greenstone find that climate
change could raise the annual mortality rate from 0.5 percent to 1.7
percent by the end of the twenty-first century, a modest amount that is
not statistically significant, except for infants. (24) Janet Currie and
Reed Walker estimate health damages from congestion-related air
pollution. (25) They exploit changes in congestion from the introduction
of electronic toll collection. As a result of the improved traffic flow,
they find that mothers living within two kilometers of toll stations
experience more than a 10 percent reduction in the incidence of low
birth weight.
The EEE group also studies the distribution of the costs of
environmental policy. Some researchers use partial equilibrium or
input-output models to calculate the effects of increased energy costs
on output prices, finding regressive effects. (26) Others use computable
general equilibrium (CGE) models to find effects on factor prices as
well as output prices. (27) Still others use analytical general
equilibrium models with few sectors to solve for expressions that show
how parameters affect output prices and factor prices (28) and other
researchers investigate redistributions between generations, (29)
between locations, (30) or between ethnic groups. (31)
Absent coordinated and harmonized global climate change policy,
emissions regulation imposed in one jurisdiction may lead to increases
in emissions in other jurisdictions that are less stringently regulated.
Meredith Fowlie analyzes the potential for this emissions
"leakage" from California's electricity sector under a
source-based cap-and-trade program. Regulation that exempts out-of-state
producers achieves approximately one third of the emissions reductions
achieved under complete regulation, at more than twice the cost per ton
of emissions abated.
James Bushnell and Yihsu Chen develop a regional model of the power
sector in the western United States. (32) They examine the impacts of
alternative cap-and-trade designs on operations, emissions, and
electricity prices. Even when the scope of the cap-and-trade program is
expanded to include seven western states, they find, emissions leakage
in the electricity sector could still be significant. They provide
evidence to suggest that emissions leakage could be mitigated
significantly by making permit allocations contingent upon past
electricity production choices.
Finally, environmental and energy policy may be able to reduce
uncertainty. Martin Weitzman first noted the importance of a
"fat-tail" probability distribution for damages, such that a
climate catastrophe might have low probability but also very high
damages that outweigh the effects of discounting. (33) The importance of
the possible catastrophe then depends on risk aversion in utility.
Constant relative risk aversion means that marginal utility is
unbounded, and society would pay huge amounts to avoid a major
catastrophe. Robert Pindyck finds that once marginal utility is bounded,
extreme results disappear, and a thin-tailed distribution can yield
higher willingness to pay for abatement. (34)
The Design and Implementation of U.S. Climate Policy
Although academic environmental economists like to discuss major
conceptual issues in the choice between pollution taxes, permit systems,
or command and control mandates, (35) the U.S. House of Representatives
in June of 2009 passed actual climate policy legislation. The choices
are no longer just conceptual, but involve many small aspects of policy
design that collectively determine the effectiveness of the policy. For
this reason, Catherine Wolfram and I organized an NBER conference in
Washington D.C. in May 2010, which focused on the actual problem of
policymakers trying to design climate legislation.
In their paper for the conference, Lawrence Goulder and Robert
Stavins show how federal policy interacts with state and local policy to
control greenhouse gas (GHG) emissions. (36) For cap-and-trade
legislation, a regional policy reduces pressure on federal constraints
and allows polluters in other regions to increase emissions.
With a carbon tax, however, a particular region can have a stricter
policy without that leakage. Kahn points out that cities have policies
affecting carbon emissions, too. (37) Zoning rules may encourage urban
density, for example, which can reduce commuting, residential unit
sizes, and thus energy use.
Lucas Davis points out that the House Bill also tightens energy
efficiency standards for consumer appliances. (38) Such standards are
not necessary if higher energy prices encourage energy-efficient
appliances, but they may help if landlords buy cheap inefficient
appliances because renters pay electric bills. Controlling for household
income and characteristics using household-level data, Davis finds that
renters are significantly less likely to have efficient appliances.
Kotchen studies the effects of voluntary programs on "green
electricity" adoption. (39) Knittel and Ryan Sandier analyze the
effects of carbon pricing on GHG emissions from the transportation
sector; they find large effects of gasoline prices on consumer choices
both about vehicle miles travelled and about when to scrap older
vehicles. (40) Other papers prepared for the conference analyze
distributional effects, (41) interactions of climate policy with other
regulations, (42) and issues of monitoring and enforcement. (43)
Continuing with the details of cap-and-trade policy, Meredith
Fowlie looks at whether eligibility for output-based allocation of
permits might be based on energy intensity and import penetration in a
way that would mitigate adverse impacts on international
competitiveness. (44) Roberton Williams analyzes the time-profile of
climate policies, finding efficiency reasons for phase-in of a permit
policy but not for a carbon tax. (45) Erin Mansur looks at reasons to
implement climate policy downstream (on emissions) rather than upstream
(on the carbon content of coal, natural gas, and petroleum). (46)
Climate policy is likely to have other effects as well. Stephen
Holland shows how carbon emission restrictions might have output effects
that reduce other pollutants, or substitution effects that increase
other pollutants. (47) Olivier Deschenes notes that higher industrial
energy costs may affect labor demand; he uses 30 years of data to
estimate a cross-price elasticity of -0.15 to -0.08, implying that the
proposed bill's 3 percent increase in electricity prices might
result in 0.3 percent less employment in the short run. (48) Charles
Kolstad looks at incentives for R and D, showing that a permit system
can allow the innovator to capture the gains from innovation, while a
tax system might not. (49)
The design of climate policy also must account for international
considerations. Kala Krishna uses a general equilibrium model to draw
analogies between emission permit restrictions and quotas or other trade
restrictions, with effects on output prices, factor prices, and traded
quantities. (50) Besides the effects on traded goods, climate policy
might create trade in "offsets", with problems that are
analyzed by James Bushnell. (51) More broadly looking at all
natural-carbon cycles, Severin Borenstein notes that many types of human
activities could have indirect as well as direct effects on climate, in
ways that might be very difficult to regulate. (52)
V. Kerry Smith suggests that besides introducing carbon pricing,
climate policy might provide incentives for adaptation. (53) Changes in
climate will affect the demand for substitutes, for example when
variations between normal and dry periods change the residential demand
for water.
Finally, Michael Roberts and Wolfram Schlenker look at the effects
of climate change on agricultural output. (54) While average yields have
risen over past decades, crop tolerance to extreme heat has not.
Unfortunately, climate change may significantly reduce yields under
current technologies.
(1) M.R. Busse, C. R. Knittel, and E Zettelmeyer, "Pain at the
Pump: The Differential Effect of Gasoline Prices on New and Used
Automobile Markets," NBER Working Paper No. 15590, December 2009.
(2) S. Li, R. von Haefen, and C. Timmins, "How Do Gasoline
Prices Affect Fleet Fuel Economy?" NBER Working Paper No. 14450,
October 2008, and American Economic Journal: Economic Policy, 1(2),
August 2009, pp. 113-37.
(3) C.R. Knittel, "Automobiles on Steroids: Product Attribute
Trade- Off and Technological Progress in the Automobile Sector,"
NBER Working Paper No. 15162, July 2009, and forthcoming in the American
Economic Review.
(4) L. Goulder, M. Jacobsen, and A. van Benthem "Unintended
Consequences from Nested State & Federal Regulations: The Case of
the Pavley Greenhouse-Gas-per-Mile Limits," NBER Working Paper No.
15337, September 2009.
(5) S. Holland, C. Knittel, and J. Hughes, "Greenhouse Gas
Reductions under Low Carbon Fuel Standards?" NBER Working Paper No.
13266, July 2007, and American Economic Journal: Economic Policy, 1(1),
February 2009, pp. 106-46.
(6) M. Roberts and W. Schlenker, "Identifying Supply and
Demand Elasticities of Agricultural Commodities: Implications for the US
Ethanol Mandate," NBER Working Paper No. 15921, April 2010.
(7) L. Davis and M. Kahn, "International Trade in Used Durable
Goods: The Environmental Consequences of NAFTA," NBER Working Paper
No. 14565, December 2008, and forthcoming in the American Economic
Journal: Economic Policy.
(8) L. W. Davis and E. Muehlegger, "Do Americans Consume Too
Little Natural Gas? An Empirical Test of Marginal Cost Pricing",
NBER Working Paper No. 15885, April 2010, forthcoming in the RAND
Journal of Economics.
(9) S.J. Davis, C. Grim, J. Haltiwanger, and M. Streitwieser,
"Electricity Pricing to U.S. Manufacturing Plants, 1963-2000, NBER
Working Paper No. 13778, February 2008.
(10) G. E. Metcalf "Investment in Energy Infrastructure and
the Tax Code", NBER Working Paper No. 15429, October 2009, and Tax
Policy and the Economy 24, 2010, pp. 1-33.
(11) D. Popp and R. G. Newell, "Where Does Energy R&D Come
From? Examining Crowding Out from Environmentally-Friendly R
&D", NBER Working Paper No. 15423, October 2009.
(12) D. L. Costa and M. E. Kahn, "Why Has California's
Residential Electricity Consumption Been So Flat since the 1980s?: A
Microeconometric Approach, NBER Working Paper No. 15978, May 2010.
(13) G. D. Jacobsen and M. J. Kotchen, "Are Building Codes
Effective at Saving Energy? Evidence from Residential Billing Data in
Florida", NBER Working Paper No. 16194, July 2010.
(14) R. T. Deacon, D. P. Parker, and C. Costello, "Overcoming
the Common Pool Problem through Voluntary Cooperation: The Rise and Fall
of a Fishery Cooperative", NBER Working Paper No. 16339, September
2010.
(15) H. Sigman, "Environmental Liability and Redevelopment of
Old Industrial Land", NBER Working Paper No. 15017, May 2009, and
Journal of Law and Economics, 53, May 2010, pp. 289-306.
(16) S. Olmstead, W. M. Hanemann, and R. N. Stavins, "Water
Demand under Alternative Price Structures", NBER Working Paper No.
13573, November 2007, and Journal of Environmental Economics and
Management, 54, 2007, pp. 181-98.
(17) J. D. Hamilton, "Causes and Consequences of the Oil Shock
of 2007-8", NBER Working Paper No. 15002, May 2009, and
"Understanding Crude Oil Prices", NBER Working Paper No.
14492, November 2008, and The Energy Journal, 30(2), 2009, pp. 179-06.
(18) J. C. Carbon and V. K. Smith, "Valuing Ecosystem Services
in General Equilibrium", NBER Working Paper No. 15844, March 2010.
(19) A. Levinson, "Valuing Public Goods Using Happiness Data:
The Case of Air Quality, NBER Working Paper No. 15156, July 2009.
(20) M. L. Cropper, Y. Jiang, A. Alberini, and P. Baur,
"Getting Cars off the Road: The Cost-Effectiveness of an Episodic
Pollution Control Program", NBER Working Paper No. 15904, April
2010.
(21) M. Fowlie, C. R. Knittel, and C. Wolfram, "Sacred Cars?
Optimal Regulation of Stationary and Nonstationary Pollution
Sources", NBER Working Paper No. 14504, November 2008.
(22) W. D. Nordhaus, "The Perils of the Learning Model For
Modeling Endogenous Technological Change, NBER Working Paper No. 14638,
January 2009.
(23) A. Levinson, "Technology, International Trade, and
Pollution from U.S. Manufacturing, NBER Working Paper No. 13616,
November 2007, and American Economic Review, 99(5), December 2009, pp.
2177-92.
(24) O. Deschenes and M. Greenstone, "Climate Change,
Mortality, and Adaptation: Evidence from Annual Fluctuations in Weather
in the US'; NBER Working Paper No. 13178, June 2007.
(25) J. Currie and R. Walker, "Traffic Congestion and Infant
Health: Evidence from E-Z Pass," NBER Working Paper No. 15413,
October 2009, and forthcoming in the American Economic Journal: Applied
Economics.
(26) Three examples include: S. Borenstein, "The
Redistributional Impact of Nonlinear Electricity Pricing" NBER
Working Paper No. 15822, March 2010;K. A. Hassett, A. Mathur, and G. E.
Metcalf "The Incidence of a U.S. Carbon Tax: A Lifetime and
Regional Analysis" NBER Working Paper No. 13554, October 2007, and
The Energy Journal, 30(2), pp. 155-178; and C. A. Grainger and C. D.
Kolstad, "Who Pays a Price on Carbon?", NBER Working Paper No.
15239, August 2009 and Environmental & Resource Economics, 46(3),
July 2010, pp. 35976.
(27) S. Rausch, G. E. Metcalf J. M. Reilly, and S. Paltsev,
"Distributional Implications of Alternative U.S. Greenhouse Gas
Control Measures, NBER Working Paper No. 16053, June 2010, and The B.E.
Journal of Economic Analysis & Policy, i0(2).
(28) D. Fullerton and G. Heutel, "Analytical General
Equilibrium Effects of Energy Policy on Output and Factor Prices,"
NBER Working Paper No. 15788, February 2010, and The B.E. Journal of
Economic Analysis & Policy, 10(2). See also D. Fullerton and H.
Monti, "Can Pollution Tax Rebates Protect Low-Income Families? The
Effects of Relative Wage Rates, NBER Working Paper No. 15935, April
2010.
(29) L. H. Summers and R. J. Zeckhauser, "Policymaking for
Posterity," NBER Working Paper No. 14359, September 2008, and
Journal of Risk and Uncertainty, 37(2), pp. 115-40.
(30) N. V. Kuminoff V. K. Smith, and C. Timmins, "The New
Economics of Equilibrium Sorting and its Transformational Role for
Policy Evaluation, NBER Working Paper No. 16349, September 2010.
(31) H. S. Banzhaf and R. P. Walsh, "Segregation and Tiebout
Sorting: Investigating the Link between Investments in Public Goods and
Neighborhood Tipping, NBER Working Paper No. 16057, June 2010.
(32) J. B. Bushnell and Y. Chen, "Regulation, Allocation, and
Leakage in Cap-and-Trade Markets for C02, NBER Working Paper No. 15495,
November 2009.
(33) M. L. Weitzman, "On Modeling and Interpreting the
Economics of Catastrophic Climate Change," Review of Economics and
Statistics, 91(1), February, 2009, pp 1-19. Also see M. L. Weitzman,
"GHG Targets as Insurance against Catastrophic Climate Damages,
NBER Working Paper No. 16136, June 2010.
(34) R. S. Pindyck, "Fat Tails, Thin Tails, and Climate Change
Policy, NBER Working Paper No. 16353, September 2010.
(35) See, for example, L. Kaplow, "Taxes, Permits, and Climate
Change, NBER Working Paper No. 16268, August 2010.
(36) L. H. Goulder and R. Stavins, "Interactions of State and
Federal Climate Change Policies, NBER Working Paper 16123, June 2010.
(37) M. E. Kahn, "Urban Policy Effects on Carbon
Mitigation," NBER Working Paper No. 16131, June 2010.
(38) L. W. Davis, "Evaluating the Slow Adoption of Energy
Efficient Investments: Are Renters Less Likely to Have Energy Efficient
Appliances?" NBER Working Paper 16114, June 2010.
(39) M. J. Kotchen, "Climate Policy and Voluntary Initiatives:
An Evaluation of the Connecticut Clean Energy Communities Program, NBER
Working Paper No. 16117, June 2010.
(40) C. R. Knittel and R. Sandler, "Carbon Prices and
Automobile Greenhouse Gas Emissions: The Extensive and Intensive
Margins", NBER Working Paper No. 16482, October 2010.
(41) G. E. Metcalf, A. Mathur, and K. A. Hassett,
"Distributional Impacts in a Comprehensive Climate Policy
Package", NBER Working Paper No. 16101, June 2010.
(42) A. Levinson, "Belts and Suspenders: Interactions among
Climate Policy Regulations", NBER Working Paper No. 16109, June
2010.
(43) H. Sigman, "Monitoring and Enforcement of Climate
Policy", NBER Working Paper No. 16121, June 2010.
(44) M. Fowlie, "Updating the Allocation of Greenhouse Gas
Emissions Permits in a Federal Cap-and-Trade Program" NBER Working
Paper No. 16307, August 2010.
(45) R. C. Williams, "Setting the Initial Time-Profile of
Climate Policy: The Economics of Environmental Policy Phase Ins",
NBER Working Paper No. 16120, June 2010.
(46) E. T. Mansur, "Upstream versus Downstream Implementation
of Climate Policy, NBER Working Paper No. 16116, June 2010.
(47) S. P. Holland, "Spillovers from Climate Policy, NBER
Working Paper No. 16158, July 2010.
(48) O. Deschenes, "Climate Policy arid Labor Markets",
NBER Working Paper No. 16111, June 2010. Employment effects are also
studied by J. Graff Zivin and 34. J. Neidell, "Temperature and the
Allocation of Time: Implications for Climate Change, NBER Working Paper
No. 15717, February 2010.
(49) C. D. Kolstad, "Regulatory Choice with Pollution and
Innovation", NBER Working Paper No. 16303, August 2010.
(50) K. Krishna, "Limiting Emissions and Trade: Some Basic
Ideas, NBER Working Paper No. 16147, July 2010.
(51) J. B. Bushnell, "The Economics of Carbon Offsets, NBER
Working Paper No. 16305, August 2010.
(52) S. Borenstein, "Markets for Anthropogenic Carbon within
the Larger Carbon Cycle", NBER Working Paper No. 16104, June 2010.
(53) V. K. Smith, "How Can Policy Encourage Economically
Sensible Climate Adaptation?" NBER Working Paper No. 16100, June
2010.
(54) M. J. Roberts and W. Schlenker, "Is Agricultural
Production Becoming More or Less Sensitive to Extreme Heat? Evidence
from U.S. Corn and Soybean Yields, NBER Working Paper No. 16308, August
2010.
Don Fullerton *
* Fullerton directs the NBER's Program on Environmental and
Energy Economics and is Gutgsell Professor in the Finance Department,
Center for Business and Public Policy, and Institute of Government and
Public Affairs at the University of Illinois.