Corporate Finance.
Rajan, Raghuram G.
The NBER's Program on Corporate Finance was founded in 1991,
and has initiated some very promising avenues of research since then.
Narrowly interpreted, corporate finance is the study of the investment
and financing policies of corporations. Because firms are at the center
of economic activity, and almost any topic of concern to
economists--from microeconomic issues like incentives and risk sharing
to macroeconomic issues such as currency crises--affects corporate
financing and investment, it is however increasingly difficult to draw
precise boundaries around the field.
The range of subjects that Corporate Finance Program members have
addressed in their research reflects this broad scope. Rather than
offering a broad brush survey of all the work currently being done,
however, I thought it would be most useful to focus on what our
researchers have contributed to the analysis of the ongoing financial
crisis. Even here, I have had to be selective, given the large number of
papers on this subject in the last two years. I should also note that
even prior to the crisis, Corporate Finance Program members had done
important work on such topics as credit booms, illiquidity, bank runs,
and credit crunches. This work laid much of the foundation for the more
recent analyses. In the interests of space, though, I will not survey
that earlier work.
A number of papers offer an overview of the crisis (Brunnermeier,
14612; Diamond and Rajan, 14739; Gorton, 14398). There is some consensus
on its proximate causes: 1) the U.S. financial sector financed
low-income borrowers who wanted to buy houses, and it raised money for
such lending through the issuance of exotic new financial instruments;
2) banks seemed very willing to take risks during this time, and a
significant portion of these instruments found their way, directly or
indirectly, into commercial and investment bank balance sheets; 3) these
investments were largely financed with short-term debt. But what were
the more fundamental reasons for these proximate causes?
Why Low Income Borrowers?
Atif Mian and Amir Sufi (13936) offer persuasive evidence that it
was an increase in the supply of finance to low-income borrowers--not an
improvement in the credit quality of those borrowers--that drove
lending, appreciation of house prices, and subsequent mortgage defaults.
They argue that zip codes with high unmet demand for credit in the
mid-1990s (typically dominated by low-income potential borrowers)
experienced large increases in lending from 2001 to 2005. These
increases occurred even though these zip codes experienced significantly
negative relative income and employment growth over this time period,
suggesting that improvements in demand did not drive lending. The
increase in the supply of credit seemed to be associated with a sharp
relative increase in the fraction of loans from these zip codes sold by
originators for securitization. The increase in the supply of credit
from 2001 to 2005 led to subsequent large increases in mortgage defaults
from 2005 to 2007. Mian and Sufi conclude that originators selling
mortgages were a main cause of the U.S. mortgage default crisis.
Why did supply increase? One possibility is that financial
innovation--the process of securitization which spread risk--enabled the
financial sector to lend to risky borrowers who previously were
rationed. The reality, though, is that deep flaws in the process of
securitization seem to have compromised quality. Efraim Benmelech and
Jennifer Dlugosz (14878, 15045) offer some evidence on the extent to
which low quality mortgage packages were transformed into highly rated
securities. They suggest that "ratings shopping" by some
issuers of mortgage backed securities (which refers to the process by
which an issuer finds the rating agency that will offer the most
favorable rating), as well as a fall in standards at some rating
agencies, must have played a role in the deterioration in quality.
Vasiliki Skreta and Laura Veldkamp (14761) argue that for complex
products, where rating agencies could have produced a greater dispersion
in ratings even if totally unbiased, the incentive for the issuer to
shop for the highest rating may have been higher, and therefore the
inherent bias in published ratings larger. It would be interesting to
see whether ratings shopping by issuers could come close to accounting
for the size of the errors that were made.
Another possibility is raised by Charles Calomiris (15403) and Mian
and Sufi (13936), all of whom argue that government pressure to expand
housing to low-income segments, and government involvement through the
Federal Housing Authority and mandates to Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac,
may have caused the explosion in supply.
The effects of both flawed financial innovation and undue
government pressure to lend may have been aggravated by household
behavior. For instance, Mian and Sufi (15283) document the rise in home
equity borrowing in areas that had substantial house price appreciation,
with the borrowing seemingly going to finance additional consumption.
Their estimates suggest an increase in home-equity borrowing of 2.8
percent of GDP every year from 2002 to 2006. Following the housing
crash, home equity borrowing seems to account for at least 34 percent of
the new defaults from 2006 to 2008. While all of these aggregate
estimates are, by necessity, tentative, borrower repayment capacity may
have deteriorated even after the initial mortgage origination because of
the easy availability of credit.
Were banks more willing to take risks?
The large quantities of mortgage backed securities that were
originated should have been sold to institutions that could bear the
risk. Somehow, they landed up on bank balance sheets, or in off-balance
sheet vehicles like conduits, all financed with very short-term debt.
Why did banks take all this risk?
One set of explanations has to do with incentive structures.
Douglas W. Diamond and I (14739) argue that given the competition for
talent, traders have to be paid generously based on performance. But,
many of the compensation schemes paid for short-term risk-adjusted
performance. This gave traders an incentive to take risks that were not
recognized by the system, so that they could generate income that
appeared to stem from their superior abilities, even though it was in
fact only a market-risk premium. The classic case of such behavior is to
write insurance on infrequent events, such as defaults, taking on what
is termed "tail" risk. If traders are allowed to boost their
bonuses by treating the entire insurance premium as income instead of
setting aside a significant fraction as a reserve for an eventual
payout, then they will have an excessive incentive to engage in this
sort of trade. Indeed, traders who bought AAA mortgage backed securities
were essentially getting the additional spread on these instruments
relative to corporate AAA securities (the spread being the insurance
premium) while ignoring the additional default risk entailed in these
untested securities. Regulators also seemed to ignore these risks in
setting capital requirements.
Tail risk taking may not have been unprofitable for bank
shareholders ex ante, especially if there were implicit guarantees from
the authorities to bail out the system when a crisis occurred. Andrei
Shleifer and Robert W. Vishny (14943) propose an explanation of booms
and busts in lending where bank managers' interests are perfectly
aligned with those of shareholders. The driving force in their model is
investor sentiment--essentially a willingness by market investors to
overpay for securitized debt in good times. Banks have to contribute
some money of their own to securitizations so as to assure investors
that they have "skin in the game." In good times (high
sentiment), banks will use up all of their available financing capacity
in order to create financing packages that can be sold. They thereby
maximize their profits from the cheap funding available from markets. In
bad times (low sentiment), banks may have to liquidate some of their
portfolio at low fire sale prices. But the losses incurred then are more
than made up for by the profits obtained by stretching the balance sheet
in good times.
Finally, Veronica Guerrieri and Peter Kondor (14898) propose a
model in which manager career concerns drive booms and busts. Good
managers know the true state of the world next period--whether it will
be the good state where risky projects will pay off in full so that risk
taking makes sense or the bad state where they will default. Normal
managers do not know the state--they only know probabilities. Normal
managers would like to be seen by the market as good managers. When good
times are likely and defaults are likely to be low, normal managers are
likely to take on risky projects--reducing the overall risk premium for
risky assets excessively. When bad times are likely and defaults are
likely to be high, normal managers will take safe projects, increasing
the overall risk premium for risky assets. Thus managerial career
concerns could explain the changes in sentiment towards risky assets
that Shleifer and Vishny allude to, and could explain the recent boom
and bust.
The evidence on bank behavior is accumulating. Andrea Beltratti and
Rene M. Stulz (15180) find that bank shares that had high stock market
returns in 2006 fared very poorly in 2007-8. They also find that banks
with more shareholder-friendly boards performed worse during the crisis.
These findings are consistent with the notion that bank CEOs may have
been maximizing shareholder value by taking on risk (or that the market
did not realize the risk they were taking)--when the risk materialized,
their share price tanked. Rudiger Fahlenbrach and Stulz (15212) find
that CEOs like Richard Fuld of Lehman who had the highest equity
holdings in their firms in 2006 performed the worst during the crisis.
They suggest that monetary incentives seem not to have mattered in
driving behavior in this crisis. The precise reason is unclear. Perhaps
CEOs accumulated equity through risky behavior in the past, and did not
realize that times had changed. Perhaps the probability of a tail event
like the one that occurred in September 2008 was small enough that they
ignored it. Or perhaps CEOs felt they had to take risk in order to shine
or even survive in their jobs, an objective far more important than any
expected monetary loss they might suffer.
Financing with Short-Term Debt
Why were the banks financed with short-term debt? Diamond and Rajan
(14739) argue that given the complexity of bank risk-taking, and the
potential breakdown in internal control processes, investors would have
demanded a very high premium for financing a bank long term. By
contrast, they would have been far more willing to hold short-term
claims on the bank, since that would give them the option to exit--or
get a higher premium--if the bank appeared to be getting into trouble.
So, investors would have demanded lower premiums for holding short-term
secured debt in light of potential agency problems at banks.
Of course, short-term debt carries refinancing or liquidity risk
(the risk that financial market conditions will not be so favorable when
it comes time to refinance). Indeed, Heitor Almeida, Murillo Campello,
Bruno Laranjeira, and Scott Weisbenner (14990) show that firms that had
debt maturing during the crisis reduced investment by about one third
the pre-crisis level relative to their peers, suggesting a substantial
cost of illiquidity. Perhaps one reason that bank managers paid less
attention to illiquidity was that it too was a tail risk.
Another reason, though, might be that banks discounted the cost of
illiquidity because of implicit promises made by the Fed. Diamond and
Rajan (15197) argue that if the Fed is perceived as being accommodative
in the future, or if it is viewed as unwilling to allow system-wide
stress, then banks have an incentive to move to more illiquid assets
financed with short-term debt. Authorities may want to commit to a
specific policy of interest rate intervention to restore appropriate
incentives. For instance, to offset incentives for banks to make more
illiquid loans, authorities may have to commit to raising rates when
low, to counter the distortions created by lowering them when high.
Marcin Kacperczyk and Philipp Schnabl (15538) argue that in the
1980s and early 1990s, the off-balance sheet conduits set up by banks to
hold commercial paper tended to invest in short-term commercial paper
while financing themselves with short-term issuances. It is only in the
late 1990s and in this century that they moved to holding longer-term
illiquid assets, thus incurring the liquidity mismatch. This suggests
either that excessive risk taking, or great confidence in the Fed's
willingness to pump in liquidity when needed, may have prompted the rise
in asset-liability mismatches.
I have already described one rationale for the bank financing with
very short-term debt: it reduced the risk that the lender would see his
investment wasted by the bank. Another rationale is that short-term
secured debt, because of its effective seniority in the normal course
(overnight secured debt is effectively repaid every day before anyone
else gets to assert their claim) is information-insensitive. So a large
pool of uninformed investors (money market funds, pension funds, wealth
funds) can hold these claims, unlike corporate debt or equity, because
they are near riskless. The problem, of course, occurs when liquidity
starts drying up in the markets. At such times, Gary Gorton and Andrew
Metrick (15273) argue, investors will not lend against the full value of
collateral--they will impose a "haircut" on the amount they
are willing to lend against collateral, with the extent of the haircut
signifying the extent to which there will be a price decline in the
value of the collateral if it is sold conditional on default. A greater
haircut obviously implies that the bank can raise less debt against its
assets, which also means it either has to have more equity or sell
assets. If it is hard to raise equity, then in an illiquid market there
will be asset sales which further depress prices, raise haircuts, and so
on.
The Panic and Fire Sales
A number of papers address the panic itself: Zhiguo He and Wei
Xiong (15482) start with a model in which creditors are willing to roll
over their loans to a bank only when current fundamentals provide a
margin of safety. In figuring out this margin, today's maturing
creditors have to guess what kinds of margins tomorrow's maturing
creditors will demand. If today's maturing creditors anticipate
that tomorrow's creditors will demand a high threshold of safety,
today's creditors will demand an even higher threshold. This
precipitates a dynamic rat race, such that if creditors anticipate a bad
enough future scenario, lending could dry up today, even though
fundamentals do not warrant it.
A related argument, but across creditor chains, underlies the work
of Ricardo Caballero and Alp Simsek (14997, 15479). Essentially, the
idea is that as asset prices fall, more banks are likely to become
distressed. Banks now need to monitor not only their immediate
borrowers, but also borrowers of their borrowers, and so on. As banks
cut back on lending, more entities are forced to sell at fire sale
prices, implying that still more banks become distressed, and increasing
the complexity that each bank has to deal with. At some point, the
environment could become so complex that all lending stops.
A number of papers thus argue that downward spirals in asset prices
could occur, and they explain the various ways the spirals could become
self-reinforcing. Arvind Krishnamurthy (15040) offers a nice overview of
such models including his work with Caballero on models of Knightian
uncertainty as applied to finance. Diamond and Rajan (14925) argue that
if there is an "overhang" of impaired banks that may be forced
to sell illiquid assets in the future, this can reduce the current price
of illiquid assets sufficiently that the weak banks have no interest in
selling them. Intuitively, if a bank today expects to fail in the future
conditional on being forced to sell assets, then it has no interest in
selling them today, even if that would assure it is solvent in all
future states--the insurance it buys from current cash sales essentially
is a direct transfer to the bank's creditors. At the same time,
anticipating a potential future fire sale, cash rich buyers have high
expected returns to holding cash, which also reduces their incentive to
lock up money in term loans. Thus the prospect of future fire sales
could impair current lending. The potential for a worse fire sale than
necessary, as well as the associated decline in credit origination,
could make the crisis worse. That is one reason it may make sense to
clean up the system and to deal with the "walking wounded"
banks, even in the midst of the crisis.
Finally, Krishnamurthy (15542) offers a careful empirical overview
of the kinds of problems that pervaded debt markets. He focuses on the
provision of risk capital, the willingness to undertake "repo"
financing without demanding huge haircuts, and the willingness to take
on counterparty risk. He then shows how these problems can explain a
variety of interesting anomalies during the panic, including seemingly
large arbitrage opportunities in the markets. For instance, he explains
why the 30-year swap rate being below the Treasury rate implies an
almost certain money making opportunity, but only if the arbitrageur has
the risk capital, can assure market participants of his own good
standing (counterparty risk), and can absorb the haircuts in borrowing
that are applied in such stressed times. Given that all of these
attributes were in short supply during the crisis, the arbitrage
persisted for a while, available only to the most solid market
participants (who indeed made extraordinary profits over this interval).
The Rescue Efforts
We now turn to the rescue efforts (or the bailouts, as some would,
perhaps correctly, characterize them). Takeo Hoshi and Anil K Kashyap
(14401) summarize the experience of the Japanese financial crisis and
draw lessons about the design and the timing of bank rescue programs.
The conclude that to effectively rebuild the balance sheet of banks,
some mix of recapitalization and asset purchase is probably
necessary--neither step alone is likely to be powerful enough to achieve
this goal. They call attention to the importance of rigorous bank
inspections prior to recapitalization to evaluate the size of the
problem, and they observe that if the goal is to prevent further
deterioration of asset values, troubled assets need to be restructured
swiftly. They emphasize that macroeconomic recovery can help, and be
helped by, bank recovery.
Pietro Veroncsi and Luigi Zingales (15458) calculate the costs and
benefits of U.S. government intervention in September-October 2008. They
conclude that on net the intervention increased the value of financial
claims on the banks by about $131 billion, at a cost to taxpayers of
between $25 and $47 billion. They conclude that a bankruptcy would have
destroyed about 22 percent of failing banks' value (they do not
compute what the loss to the economy would have been if the banks
failed, only the cost to the claimants on the banks). Their calculations
suggest that the rescue plan came at a cost to taxpayers, but benefited
the economy overall.
What did not cause the panic?
We have many theories of what caused the panic and the subsequent
credit crunch, but also some theories of what did not. Christian Laux
and Christian Leuz (15515) argue that it is unlikely that fair value
accounting--roundly criticized by bankers--was responsible for the
crisis. First of all, market values rather than accounting values enter
many market contracts (such as how much collateral to demand). These
would have been unaffected by fair value accounting. Second, not all
changes in fair value enter the computation of bank's regulatory
capital. Indeed, the researchers argue that from about the third quarter
of 2007, banks used cash-flow-based models to value mortgage related
securities, and therefore it is a myth that marking-to-market pricing
was widespread for mortgage related securities. Third, even where flair
value was used, it appears that if anything, banks overvalued their
assets, especially where they had discretion. More generally, in my
view, to the extent that regulatory capital binds, it would seem that
rather than making accounting less transparent, regulators should have
the ability to weaken capital requirements if they so choose. Moreover,
the real problem with accounting in the midst of a crisis is the wide
discretion that banks have--which reduces the transparency of their
balance sheets--rather than the fact that they mark assets to
unrepresentative prices.
Other Issues
The crisis led to a "sudden stop" of international
capital flows into a large number of emerging markets. Hui Tong and
Shang-Jin Wei (15207) analyze whether the volume and composition of
capital flows into a country affected the extent of the crunch faced by
its manufacturing sector. They find that on average the decline in stock
prices was more severe for firms that were more dependent on external
finance to fund their working capital. Further, while the overall volume
of the pre-crisis capital flow into a country was not related to the
severity of the stock price decline for dependent firms, the composition
of capital inflows mattered. Dependent firms in countries that got more
non-FDI (Foreign Direct Investment) inflows pre-crisis were affected by
the crunch, while the effect was reversed in countries that had more
exposure to FDI inflows pre-crisis. This adds to the literature
suggesting not all forms of foreign capital inflows are risky, and that
FDI inflows might be preferable to portfolio inflows. Of course, because
one does not quite know whether the countries that get FDI inflows are
special in a particular way, the results are suggestive rather than
conclusive.
Finally, an overarching issue is whether an overpaid financial
sector, contributing little to overall economic welfare, got the rest of
the economy into trouble. Certainly, this is behind many reform
proposals. Thomas Phillipon and Ariell Reshef (14644) address this issue
and find that before the 1929 stock market crash, and before the Crash
of 2008, finance jobs were indeed highly paid relative to the rest of
the economy. In part, they attribute this to the greater complexity of
finance jobs, and to the greater skills they required during this
period. They do relate the higher required skill levels to deregulation,
which seemed to expand access to credit to more corporations (as
measured by Initial Public Offerings) and the greater willingness of the
financial sector in taking credit risk. Finally, they conclude that
people in the financial sector do seem to have been overpaid by between
30 and 50 percent over the most recent period, despite the more complex
work they did. The natural conclusion from all this is that as
regulation clamps down on risk taking, finance salaries will come back
to earth, but so will access to credit. Making finance boring will have
costs but, as this article suggests, regardless of the reforms that are
carried out, research in corporate finance promises to be interesting
for years to come!
Raghuram G. Rajan *
* Rajan directs the NBER's Program on Corporate Finance and is
the Eric J. Gleacher Distinguished Service Professor of Finance at the
University of Chicaso's Booth School of Business. In this article,
the numbers in parentheses refer to NBER Working Papers.