Banking Crises.
Calomiris, Charles W.
The current global financial crisis grew out of banking losses in
the United States related to subprime lending. How well do economists
understand the origins of such crises and how they spread? Was this
crisis something new or a replay of familiar historical phenomena? Will
policy interventions be able to mitigate its costs ? The history of
banking crises provides informative perspectives on these and other
important questions.
Crises Are Not All the Same
When considering the history of banking crises, it is useful to
distinguish between two phenomena associated with banking system
distress: exogenous shocks that produce insolvency, and pressures on
banks that arise from rapid withdrawals of debt or failures to rollover debt during "panics." These two contributors to distress often
do not coincide. For example, in the rural United States during the
1920s, large declines in agricultural prices cause many banks to fail,
often with high losses to depositors, but those failures were not
associated with systemic panics. (2) In 1907, the opposite pattern was
visible. The United States experienced a systemic panic, originating in
New York, which was precipitated by small aggregate shocks but had large
short-term systemic effects associated with widespread withdrawals of
deposits. Although some banks failed in 1907, failures and depositor
losses were not much higher than in normal times. (3) That crisis was
resolved only after banks had suspended convertibility and after
uncertainty about the incidence of the shock had been resolved.
The central differences between these two episodes relate to the
information about the shocks producing loan losses. In the 1920s, the
shocks were loan losses in agricultural banks, geographically isolated
and fairly transparent. Banks failed without subsequent system-wide
concerns. During 1907, although the ultimate losses for New York banks
were small, the incidence of the shock was not clear (loan losses
reflected complex connections to securities market transactions, with
uncertain consequences for some New York banks).
Sometimes, large loan losses and confusion regarding their
incidence occur together. In Chicago in mid-1932, for example, large
losses resulted in many failures and also in widespread withdrawals from
banks that did not ultimately fail. Despite the confusion about the
incidence of the shock, and the consequent widespread temporary
disruptions to the financial system, the banks that failed were
exogenously insolvent; solvent Chicago banks experiencing withdrawals
did not fail. In other episodes, however, bank failures may have
reflected illiquidity resulting from runs, rather than exogenous
insolvency. (4)
Today's financial turmoil is closer to the Chicago experience
in 1932 than to either the banking shocks of the 1920s or those of 1907.
(5) The shock that prompted the turmoil was of moderate size (subprime
and Alt-A loans totaled roughly $3 trillion, including those on the
balance sheets of Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac, and total losses are
likely to generate total losses of roughly half a trillion dollars), and
its consequences were significant for both solvent and insolvent banks.
Unlike the Chicago Panic, today's turmoil probably has produced the
failures of financial institutions that were arguably solvent prior to
their liquidity problems (for example, Bear Stearns).
Banking crises can differ according to whether they coincide with
other financial events. Banking crises coinciding with currency collapse
are called "twin" crises (as in Argentina in 1890 and 2001,
Mexico in 1995, and Thailand, Indonesia, and Korea in 1997). A twin
crisis can reflect two different chains of causation: an expected
devaluation may encourage deposit withdrawal to convert to hard currency
before devaluation (as in the United States in early 1933); or, a
banking crisis can cause devaluation, either through its adverse effects
on aggregate demand or by affecting the supply of money (when a costly
bank bailout prompts monetization of government bailout costs).
Sovereign debt crises can also contribute to bank distress when banks
hold large amounts of government debt (for example, in the banking
crises in the United States in 1861, and in Argentina in 2001). (6)
Shifting Perceptions of Banking Crises and the Desirability of
Government Protection
The consensus views regarding banking crises' origins
(fundamental shocks versus confusion), the extent to which crises result
from unwarranted runs on solvent banks, the social costs attending runs,
and the appropriate policies to limit the costs of banking crises
(government safety nets and prudential regulation) have changed
dramatically, and more than once, over the course of the nineteenth and
twentieth centuries. Historical experience played a large role in
changing perspectives toward crises, and the U.S. experience had a
disproportionate influence on thinking. Although panics were observed
throughout world history (as early as Hellenistic Greece, and in Rome in
33 A.D.), prior to the 1930s, in most of the world, banks were perceived
as stable; large losses from failed banks were uncommon; banking panics
were not seen as a great risk; and there was little perceived need for
formal safety nets (for example, deposit insurance). In many countries,
ad hoc policies among banks, and sometimes including central banks, to
coordinate bank responses to liquidity crises (as, for example, during
the failure of Barings investment bank in London in 1890), seemed
adequate for preventing systemic costs from bank instability.
The unusual experience of the United States was a contributor to
changes in thinking which led to growing concerns about banks runs, and
the need for aggressive safety-net policies to prevent or mitigate runs.
In retrospect, the extent to which U.S. banking instability informed
thinking and policy outside the United States seems best explained by
the size and pervasive influence of the United States; in fact, the U.S.
crises were unique and reflected peculiar features of U.S. law and
banking structure.
The U.S. Panic of 1907 (the last of a series of similar U.S.
events, including 1857, 1873, 1884, 1890, 1893, and 1896) precipitated
the creation of the Federal Reserve System in 1913 as a means of
enhancing systemic liquidity, reducing the probability of systemic
depositor runs, and mitigating the costs of such events. (7) This
innovation was specific to the United States (other countries either had
established central banks long before, often with other purposes in
mind, or had not established central banks), and reflected the unique
U.S. experience with panics--a phenomenon that the rest of the world had
not experienced since 1866, the last British banking panic.
For example, Canada did not suffer panics like those of the United
States and did not establish a central bank until 1935. Canada's
early decision to permit branch banking throughout the country ensured
that banks were geographically diversified and thus resilient to large
sectoral shocks (like those to agriculture in the 1920s and 1930s), able
to compete through the establishment of branches in rural areas (because
of low overhead costs of establishing additional branches), and able to
coordinate the banking system's response in moments of confusion to
avoid depositor runs (the number of banks was small, and assets were
highly concentrated in several nationwide institutions). Outside the
United States, coordination among banks facilitated systemic stability
by allowing banks to manage incipient panic episodes to prevent
widespread bank runs. In Canada, the Bank of Montreal occasionally would
coordinate actions by the large Canadian banks to stop crises before the
public was even aware of a possible threat. (8)
The United States, however, was unable to mimic this behavior on a
national or regional scale. U.S. law prohibited nationwide branching,
and most states prohibited or limited within-state branching. U.S.
banks, in contrast to banks elsewhere, were numerous (for example,
numbering more than 29,000 in 1920), undiversified, insulated from
competition, and unable to coordinate their behavior to prevent panics.
The structure of U.S. banking explains why the United States
uniquely had banking panics in which runs occurred despite the health of
the vast majority of banks. The major U.S. banking panics of the
postbellum era (listed above) all occurred at business cycle peaks, and
were preceded by spikes in the liabilities of failed businesses and
declines in stock prices; indeed, whenever a sufficient combination of
stock price decline and rising liabilities of failed businesses
occurred, a panic always resulted. (9) Owing to the U.S. banking
structure, panics were a predictable result of business cycle
contractions that, in other countries, resulted in an orderly process of
financial readjustment.
The United States, however, was not the only economy to experience
occasional waves of bank failures before World War I. Nor did it
experience the highest bank failure rates, or banking system losses of
that era. None of the U.S. banking panics of the pre-World War I era saw
nationwide banking distress (measured by the negative net worth of
failed banks relative to annual GDP) greater than the 0.1 percent loss
of 1893. Losses were generally modest elsewhere, but Argentina in 1890
and Australia in 1893, the most severe cases of banking distress during
the 1875-1913 era, suffered losses of roughly 10 percent of GDP. Losses
in Norway in 1900 were roughly 3 percent of GDP and in Italy in 1893
roughly 1 percent of GDP. With the possible exception of Brazil (for
which data have yet to be collected to measure losses), there were no
other cases in 1875-1913 in which banking loss exceeded 1 percent of
GDP.
Loss rates tended to be low because banks structured themselves to
limit their risk of loss, by maintaining adequate equity-to-assets
ratios, sufficiently low asset risk, and adequate asset liquidity. Most
importantly, market discipline (the fear that depositors would withdraw
their funds) provided incentives for banks to behave prudently. The
picture of small depositors lining up around the block to withdraw funds
has received much attention, but perhaps the more important source of
market discipline was the threat of an informed (often
"silent") run by large depositors (often other banks). Banks
maintained relationships with each other through inter-bank deposits and
the clearing of public deposits, notes, and bankers' bills. Banks
often belonged to clearinghouses that set regulations and monitored
members' behavior. A bank that lost the trust of its fellow bankers
could not long survive. (10)
This perception of banks as stable, as disciplined by depositors
and inter-bank arrangements to act prudently, and as unlikely to fail,
was common prior to the 1930s. The banking crises of the Great
Depression changed that perception. U.S. bank failures resulted in
losses to depositors in the 1930s in excess of 3 percent of GDP. Bank
runs, bank holidays (local and national government-decreed periods of
bank closure to attempt to calm markets and depositors), and widespread
bank closure suggested a chaotic and vulnerable system in need of
reform. The Great Depression saw an unusual raft of banking regulations
and interventions, especially in the United States, many of which have
subsequently been discredited as unwarranted and undesirable, including
restrictions on bank activities (the separation of commercial and
investment banking, subsequently reversed in the 1980s and 1990s), and
government insurance of deposits. Targeted bank recapitalizations were
also implemented via the Reconstruction Finance Corporation, in an
innovative program that proved quite successful at little cost to
taxpayers. (11)
Academic perspectives on the Depression fueled the portrayal of
banks as crisis-prone. The most important of these was the treatment of
the 1930s banking crises by Milton Friedman and Anna J. Schwartz in
their book, A Monetary History of the United States (1963). Friedman and
Schwartz argued that many solvent banks were forced to close as the
result of panics, and that fear spread from some bank failures to
produce failures elsewhere. Their views that banks were inherently
unstable, that irrational depositor runs could ruin a banking system,
and that deposit insurance was a success, were particularly influential
coming from economists known for their skepticism of government
interventions.
Since the publication of A Monetary History of the United States,
however, other scholarship has led to important qualifications of the
Friedman-Schwartz view of 1930s' bank distress, and particularly of
the role of panic in producing distress. (12) Detailed studies of
particular regions and banks' experiences do not confirm the view
that panics were a nationwide phenomenon during 1930 or early 1931, or
an important contributor to nationwide distress until very late in the
Depression (that is, early 1933). Regional bank distress often was
localized and traceable to fundamental shocks to the values of bank
loans. Indeed, recent scholarship in banking has emphasized that
government protections of banks, including the U.S. federal deposit
insurance, can undermine market discipline of bank risk taking, and
contribute significantly to the risk of a banking crisis.
Interestingly, the theory behind the problem of destabilizing
protection has been well-known for over a century, and was the basis for
Franklin Roosevelt's opposition to deposit insurance in 1933 (an
opposition shared by the Fed, the Treasury, and Senator Carter Glass).
Deposit insurance was seen as undesirable special-interest legislation
designed to benefit small banks. Numerous attempts to introduce it
failed to attract support in the Congress. (13) Deposit insurance
removes depositors' incentives to monitor and discipline banks, and
frees bankers to take imprudent risks (especially when they have little
or no remaining equity at stake, and see an advantage in
"resurrection risk taking"). The absence of discipline also
promotes banker incompetence, which leads to unwitting risk taking.
Empirical research on the banking collapses of the last two decades
of the twentieth century has produced a consensus that the greater the
protection offered by a country's bank safety net, the greater the
risk of a banking collapse. (14) Studies of historical deposit insurance
reinforce that conclusion. Indeed, the basis for the opposition to
federal deposit insurance in the 1930s was the disastrous
experimentation with insurance in several U.S. states during the early
twentieth century, which resulted in banking collapses in all the states
that adopted insurance. (15)
Macroeconomic Consequences
As macroeconomists increasingly have emphasized, when banks respond
to losses, deposit outflows, and increased risk of loan loss by
curtailing the supply of credit, that can aggravate the cyclical downturn, magnifying declines in investment, production, and asset
prices, whether or not bank failures occur. Recent research explores the
linkages among bank credit supply, asset prices, and economic activity,
and focuses in particular on the adverse macroeconomic consequences of
"credit crunches" that result from banks' attempts to
limit their risk of failure. (16)
This new literature provides evidence in support of a
"shock-and-propagation" approach to understanding the
contribution of financial crises to business cycles. This approach has
empirical implications that can distinguish it from other theories of
the origins, propagation, and consequences of bank distress. For
example, this approach helps us to understand why it was that during
previous severe banking panics in the United States, in the face of
severe asymmetric-information problems and associated adverse-selection
costs of potential bank equity offerings in the wake of banking crises,
it was prohibitive for banks to issue new equity in support of
continuing lending. Interestingly, following the subprime shock, nearly
$500 billion of new capital was raised prior to any announcement of
public injections of funds. This unusual behavior reflected improvements
in the structure of the U.S. banking system since the 1980s, which
resulted from nationwide branching and the diversification of banking
income through the deregulation of bank activities, which mitigated
problems of adverse selection (in comparison with the 1930s or the
1980s). Although it is sometimes wrongly believed that deregulation
promoted the recent instability of banks, in fact subprime lending and
securitization were in no way linked to deregulation, and whatever
prudential regulatory failures attended the subprime boom and bust, the
last decade has seen substantial increases in those regulations, not a
relaxation of prudential regulation. (17)
The shock-and-propagation approach to understanding the origins and
transmission of banking crises also implies that regulatory policy and
policy interventions that are targeted to respond to the shocks
buffeting banks (like the bank rccapitalizations recently employed by
the G7 countries) can be used very effectively to offset the harmful
macroeconomic consequences of shocks to banks' balance sheets, just
as the Reconstruction Finance Corporation's preferred stock purchases helped to stabilize the banking sector and restart the flow of
credit after 1933. (18)
(1) A longer treatment of many of the issues surveyed in this
article appears as C. W. Calomiris, "Bank Failures in Theory and
History: The Great Depression and Other 'Contagious'
Events," NBER Working Paper No. 13597, November 2007.
(2) C.W. Calomiris, "Do 'Vulnerable' Economies Need
Deposit Insurance? Lessons from the U.S. Agricultural Boom and Bust of
the 1920s," in If Texas Were Chile: A Primer on Banking Reform, P
Brock, ed., ICS Press, 1992, pp. 237-314, 319-28, and 450-8.
(3) C.W. Calomiris and G. Gorton, "The Origins of Banking
Panics: Models, Facts, and Bank Regulation," in Financial Markets
and Financial Crises, R. G. Hubbard, ed., University of Chicago Press,
1991, pp. 109-73. See also R.F. Bruner and S. D. Carr, Money Panic:
Lessons from the Financial Crisis of 1907 (2007).
(4) C. W. Calomiris and J. R. Mason, "Contagion and Bank
Failures During the Great Depression: The June 1932 Chicago Banking
Panic," NBER Working Paper No.4924, November 1994, and American
Economic Review 87, December 1997, pp. 863-83.
(5) C. W. Calomiris, "The Subprime Turmoil: What's Old,
What's New, and What's Next," in "Maintaining
Stability in a Changing Financial System" Federal Reserve Bank of
Kansas City Symposium Proceedings, 2008.
(6) For a discussion of the Argentine experience, see C. W.
Calomiris, "Devaluation with Contract Redenomination in
Argentina," NBER Working Paper No. 12644, October 2006, and Annals of Finance 3, January 2007, pp. 155-92.
(7) The national banking era panics are discussed in Calomiris and
Gorton (1991); the Panic of 1857 is treated in C. W. Calomiris and L.
Schweikart, "The Panic of 1857: Origins, Transmission, and
Containment," Journal of Economic History, December 1991, pp.
807-34.
(8) C. W. Calomiris, US Bank Deregulation in Historical
Perspective, Cambridge University Press (2000).
(9) Calomiris and Gorton (1991).
(10) For a theoretical perspective on market discipline, see C. W.
Calomiris and C. 34. Kahn, "The Role of Demandable Debt in
Structuring Optimal Banking Arrangements," American Economic Review
81, June 1991, pp. 497-513. For historical evidence, see C. W. Calomiris
and J. R. Mason, "Fundamentals, Panics and Bank Distress During the
Depression," American Economic Review 93, December 2003a, pp.
1615-47, and C. W. Calomiris and B. Wilson, "Bank Capital and
Portfolio Management: The 1930s 'Capital Crunch' and Scramble
to Shed Risk," Journal of Business 77, July 2004, pp. 421-55. A
modern-day example of market discipline (Argentina 1991-9) is analyzed
in C. W. Calomiris and A. Powell, "Can Emerging Market Bank
Regulators Establish Credible Discipline?" NBER Working Paper No.
7715, May 2000, in Prudential Supervision: What Works and What
Doesn't, F. S. Mishkin, ed., University of Chicago Press, 2001,
pp.147-96.
(11) See J. R. Mason, "Do Lender of Last Resort Policies
Matter? The Effects of' Reconstruction Finance Corporation
Assistance to Banks During the Great Depression," Journal of
Financial Services Research 20, 2001, pp. 77-95; C. W. Calomiris and J.
R. Mason, "How to Restructure Failed Banking Systems: Lessons from
the U.S. in the 1930s and Japan in the 1990s," NBER Working Paper
No. 9624, April 2003, and in Governance, Regulation, and Privatization in the Asia-Pacific Region, T. Ito and A. Krueger, eds., University of
Chicago Press, 2004, pp. 375-420.
(12) J. L. Lucia, "The Failure of the Bank of United States: A
Reappraisal," Explorations in Economic History 22, 1985, pp.
402-16; E. Wicker, The Banking Panics of the Great Depression, Cambridge
University Press, 1996; Calomiris and Mason (1997); Calomiris and Mason
(2003a).
(13) C. W. Calomiris and E. N. White, "The Origins of Federal
Deposit Insurance," in The Regulated Economy: A Historical Approach
to Political Economy, C. Goldin and G. Libecap, eds., University of
Chicago, 1994.
(14) See, for example, J. Barth, G. Caprio, and R. Levine,
Rethinking Bank Regulation: Till Angels Govern, Cambridge University
Press, 2006.
(15) C. W. Calomiris, "Is Deposit Insurance Necessary ? A
Historical Perspective," Journal of Economic History, June 1990,
pp. 283-95.
(16) B. S. Bernanke, "Nonmonetary Effects of the Financial
Crisis in the Propagation of the Great Depression," NBER Working
Paper No. 1054, 1983, and American Economic Review 73, June 1983, pp.
257-76; B. S. Bernanke and M. Gertler, Financial Fragility and Economic
Performance," NBER Working Paper No. 2318, July 1987, and Quarterly
Journal of Economics 105, February 1990, pp. 87-114; C. W. Calomiris,
"Financial Factors in the Great Depression," Journal of
Economic Perspectives, 7, Spring 1993, pp. 61-85; C. W. Calomiris and
J.R. Mason, "Consequences of Bank Distress During the Great
Depression," NBER Working Paper No. 7919, September 2000, and
American Economic Review 93, June 2003b, pp. 937-47; Calomiris and
Wilson (2004); F. Allen and D. Gale, "Financial Fragility,
Liquidity, and Asset Prices," Journal of the European Economic
Association 2, 2004, pp. 1015-48.
(17) Calomiris (2008).
(18) Mason (2001) and Calomiris and Mason (2004).
Charles W. Calomiris, Calomiris is a Research Associate in the
NBER's Program on the Development of the American Economy and the
Henry Kaufman Professor of Financial Institutions at Columbia
University's School of International and Public Affairs. His
profile appears later in this issue.
Management Practice Dimension 4 ("Performance tracking")
Score 1 Score 3 Score 5
Scoring grid
Measures tracked do Most key performance Performance is
not indicate indicators are continuously
directly if tracked formally. tracked and
overall business Tracking is over-seen communicated, both
objectives are being by senior management. formally and
met. Tracking is an informally, to all
ad-hoc process staff using a range
(certain processes of visual management
aren't tracked tools.
at all).
Sample firm
A manager tracks a At a firm every A firm has screens
range of measures product is bar-coded in view of every
when he does not and performance line, to display
think that output indicators are tracked progress to daily
is sufficient. throughout the target and other
He last requested production process. performance
these reports However, this indicators. The
about 8 months information is not manager meets daily
ago and had them communicated to with the shop floor
printed for a workers to discuss
week until output performance metrics,
increased again. and monthly to
Then he stopped present a larger
and has not view of the company
requested goals and direction.
anything since. He even stamps
canteen napkins
with performance
achievements.