Exchange rate regimes, globalization, financial crises, and monetary policy.
Bordo, Michael D.
My research in the past decade has concentrated largely on four
related themes that I discuss in this article: Exchange Rate Regimes,
Globalization, Financial Crises, and Monetary Policy.
Exchange Rate Regimes
As discussed in the Fall 1999 NBER Reporter, much of my earlier
work focused on the gold standard and related monetary regimes. A series
of papers with Finn Kydland, Ronald MacDonald, and Hugh Rockoff
emphasized the importance of credible commitment mechanisms in the
design of monetary regimes, focusing on the gold standard. (1) My recent
work extends this approach.
The choice of exchange rate regimes, between fixed and floating
exchange rates, evolved considerably in the past hundred years. (2)
Before 1914, advanced countries adhered to gold while periphery
countries either emulated the advanced countries or floated. Some
peripheral countries were especially vulnerable to financial crises and
debt default, in large part because of their extensive external debt
obligations denominated in core country currencies. This left them with
the difficult choice of floating but restricting external borrowing or
devoting considerable resources to maintaining an extra hard peg.
Today while advanced countries can successfully float, emergers who
are less financially mature and must borrow abroad in advanced country
currencies are afraid to float, for the same reason as their nineteenth
century forbearers were. To obtain access to foreign capital, they may
need a hard peg to the core country currencies. In my paper with Marc
Flandreau the key distinction between core and periphery countries, both
then and now, is financial maturity, evidenced in the ability to issue
international securities denominated in domestic currency (3) (or the
absence of "original sin", a phrase coined by Eichengreen and
Haussman (1999) (4)).
However, a case study by Chris Meissner, Angela Redish, and myself
of the debt history of several former colonies of Great Britain (the
United States, Canada, Australia, New Zealand, and South Africa), who
had largely overcome the problem of original sin by the third quarter of
the twentieth century, finds that sound fiscal institutions, high
credibility of the monetary regimes, and good financial development are
not sufficient to completely break free from original sin. Conversely,
poor performance in these policy realms is not, for the most part, a
necessary condition for Original Sin. The factor we emphasize for the
common progress toward borrowing in domestic currencies across the five
countries is the presence of shocks, such as wars, massive economic
disruption, and the emergence of global markets. The differences in
evolution between the United States and the Dominions we attribute to
differences in size, the role of a key currency, which characterized the
United States and not the others, and to membership in the British
Empire. The importance of major shocks suggests that the establishment
of a domestic bond market that mitigated these effects involved
significant start-up costs, while the importance of scale suggests that
network externalities and liquidity were pivotal in the emergence of
overseas markets in domestic currency debt. (5)
The limiting case of a fixed exchange rate regime is a monetary
union. My study of the history of monetary unions (MUs) with Lars Jonung
(6)--based on the examples of the United States, Germany, and
Italy--suggests that the success of MUs of the past has been intimately
linked with both fiscal and political unification. The implementation of
EMU was largely driven by the political will of elites and its ultimate
success may also depend upon the political will of the citizenship.
Globalization
Globalization--the integration of goods, labor, and capital
markets--has been one of the dominant issues in the past several
decades. The present era of globalization was preceded by an earlier era
in the late nineteenth century--from 1870 to World War I. Globalization
in historical perspective was the subject of a recent NBER conference
volume, edited with Man Taylor and Jeffrey Williamson. The articles in
the book covered many aspects of the globalization experience, including
the integration of markets, growth convergence, inequality, financial
development, the transmission of shocks, and the political economy of
the backlash in the interwar period that ended the first era of
globalization.
My research with Barry Eichengreen and Douglas Irwin (7) focused on
a comparison of the record of financial and commercial globalization in
the two eras of globalization. (8) The empirical evidence we survey
suggests that, while in some respects the financial integration of the
pre-1914 era remains unsurpassed, in other respects today's
financial markets are even more closely integrated than those in the
past. The difference today is that new
information-generating-and-processing technologies have reduced the
market-segmenting effects of asymmetric information. In consequence, the
range of financial claims that are traded internationally has broadened.
While in the past entities (governments, railroads, and mining
companies) with tangible and therefore relatively transparent assets
were predominant, now international investors transact freely in a much
broader range of securities.
We also find that the commercial integration before World War I was
more limited. Given that integration today is even more pervasive than a
hundred years ago, it is surprising that trade tensions and financial
instability have not been worse in recent years. Institutional
innovations that have taken place in the past century, such as the
evolution of sound monetary and fiscal policies, the establishment of
the Bretton Woods Institutions, GATT and the WTO, may be part of the
explanation.
Financial Crises and Financial Instability
The recent era of globalization has been characterized by a large
number of financial crises, both currency and banking crises, especially
in the emerging markets. (9) My research with Barry Eichengreen and
others considers whether this is a new phenomenon. Using a database for
21 countries from 1880-1997, we compiled evidence on the incidence,
duration, and costs of various types of crises across four exchange rate
regimes. (10) Like the evidence on financial integration, ours came with
a strong feeling of deja vu. The incidence and duration of currency
crises have increased since earlier eras of globalization, while those
of banking crises are similar. The output losses of crises are quite
similar across eras of globalization except for twin crises, which have
been worse. Moreover, we find that crises seem to reflect both economic
structure and bad policies. One possible determinant of crises in
emerging countries is the presence of original sin.
My work with Chris Meissner finds, in both eras of globalization,
an increased probability that emerging countries with original sin
experienced debt, currency, and banking crises. Furthermore, crises were
more likely to be a problem for middle-income merging countries that
were less financially developed. In the first era of globalization,
countries like Italy, Portugal, Argentina and Brazil were more
crisis-prone than Australia, Canada, Denmark, and Sweden.
Another part of this research program focuses on the transmission
of financial crises. (11) Antu P. Murshid and I (2000) (12) present
evidence from weekly data on sovereign bond prices and interest rates
for episodes of financial turbulence from 1880 to 1997. We find little
evidence for contagion, defined as an incidence in bilateral
cross-market correlations, adjusted for heteroscedasticity. However, we
do find evidence suggestive of transmission via fundamentals-based trade
channels. A related paper (Bordo and Murshid, 2002) (13), using
principal components analysis on monthly spreads on long-term bond
yields, finds that financial market shocks were more globalized before
1914 than they are now. (14)
Financial crises represent an extreme form of financial
instability. Michael Ducker, David C. Wheelock, and I (2000, 2002) (15)
construct indexes of financial stability for the United States and the
United Kingdom for 1790-1997. We find that aggregate price level and
inflation shocks contributed to financial instability in the 1790-1933
and 1986-97 periods.
Finally, my research has examined the role of policy in preventing,
managing, and resolving crises. Anna J. Schwartz and I (1998) examine
the historical record over the past two centuries on international
rescues. We contrast the experiences before 1973 of rescues of monetary
authorities of advanced countries that were temporarily short of
liquidity with the experience in the 1990s of bailouts of insolvent
emerging countries. In a later paper, we assess the impact of IMF loans
on the macro performance of the recipients. (16) A simple with without
comparison of countries receiving IMF assistance during crises in the
periods 1973-98, with countries in the same region not receiving
assistance, suggests that the real performance of the former group was
possibly worse than the latter. Similar results are obtained after
adjusting for self-selection bias and counterfactual policies (17).
Monetary Policy
Economic history has long provided a useful laboratory for the
practitioners of monetary policy. My research in the area has focused on
deflation and monetary policy and asset prices.
Deflation in historical perspective
The return in the 1990s to an environment of low inflation has
raised the specter in the United States of deflation and the collapse of
prices such as occurred in the 1930s. My work with Angela Redish focuses
on the deflationary experience of 1870-96 during the pre-1914 classical
gold standard period. That episode has resonance for today because the
gold standard regime, anchored by a credible commitment to maintaining
long-run price stability, conveys similarities to today's central
bank commitment to low inflation, and in both eras globalization was
present with major technology shocks. We use a structural VAR
methodology to distinguish between good deflation, reflecting
productivity-driven increases in aggregate supply, and bad deflation,
driven by collapses in aggregate demand. Our findings for the United
Kingdom and Germany are that deflation was primarily of the good
variety; for the United States, these results generally prevail with the
exception of a banking-panic-induced demand-driven deflation episode in
the mid-1890s. (18) Andrew Filardo and I (2004) (19) generalized this
finding to a panel of over twenty countries for the past two centuries.
With the exception of the interwar period we find that deflation was
generally benign.
Monetary Policy and Asset Prices
The link between monetary policy and asset price movements has been
of perennial interest to policymakers. Should the monetary authorities
intervene to offset an asset boom before it turns into a bubble that
bursts, with severe consequences for the real economy? Olivier Jeanne
and I (2002) (20) present some stylized facts on boom-bust dynamics in
stock and property prices in twenty OECD countries in the past thirty
years, as well as for the United States for the past 150 years. We find
that asset booms turning into busts are infrequent events, but when they
happen they are sometimes associated with considerable economic
distress. We develop a theoretical framework that outlines the
circumstances under which a central bank may consider following a
preemptive policy to prevent the consequences of a bust.
Wheelock and I (2004) (21) examine the economic environment in
which past U.S. stock market booms occurred as a first step toward
understanding how these booms come about and whether monetary policy
should be used to defuse them. In genera], we find that booms in the
past century and a half occurred in periods of rapid real growth and
productivity advance, suggesting that booms are driven at least partly
by fundamentals. We find no consistent relationship between inflation
and stock market booms, though; booms have typically occurred when money
and credit growth were above average.
(1) M.D. Bordo and F. Kydland, "The Gold Standard as a Rule:
An Essay in Exploration", Explorations in Economic History (1995);
M. D. Bordo and H. Rockoff, "The Gold Standard as a 'Good
Housekeeping Seal of Approval'", Journal of Economic History
(1996); and M.D.Bordo and R. MacDonald, "Violations of the
"Rules of the Game and the Credibility of the Classical Gold
Standard, 1880-1904", NBER Working Paper No. 6115, July 1997.
(2) J. A. Frankel, "Experience of and Lessons from Exchange
Rate Regime in Emerging Economies", NBER Working Paper No. 10032,
October 2003. Also M. D. Bordo and H. James, "One World Money, Then
and Now", NBER Working Paper No. 12189, May 2006, posits that in
today's world of globalization and large shifts in relative prices,
the Einsteinian or relative conception of money implicit in floating
exchange rates is more suitable than the Newtonian view that underlies
the case for fixed exchange rates.
(3) M.D. Bordo and M. Flandreau, "Core Periphery, Exchange
Rate Regimes, and Globalization", in Globalization in Historical
Perspective, M. D. Bordo, A. Taylor, and J Williamson, eds., Chicago:
University of Chicago Press (2003); and M. D. Bordo, "Market
Discipline and Financial Crisis Policy: An Historical Perspective,"
Research in Financial Services: Private and Public Policy, Vol. 18,
(2004), pp 154-82.
(4) B. Eichengreen and R. Haussman, "Exchange Rates and
Financial Fragility", NBER Working Paper No. 7418, November 1999.
(5) M. Flandreau and N. Sussman, "Old Sins: Exchange Rate
Clauses and European Foreign Lending in the 19th Century", in Other
People's Money: Debt Denomination and Financial Instability in
Emerging Markets Economies, B. Eichengreen and R. Hausmann, eds.,
Chicago and London: University of Chicago Press (2005).
(6) M.D. Bordo and L. Jonung, "The Future Of EMU: What Does
the History of Monetary Unions Tell Us?" NBER Working Paper No.
7365, September 1999. Also see M. D. Bordo, "The United States as a
Monetary Union and the Euro: A Historical Perspective", Cato
Journal, Vol. 24, No. 1-2, Spring/Summer 2004, pp. 163-70.
(7) M.D. Bordo, B. Eichengreen, and J. Kim, "Was There Really
an Earlier Period of International Financial Integration Comparable to
Today?", NBER Working Paper No. 6738, September 1998; and M. D.
Bordo, B. Eichengreen, and D. Irwin, "Is Globalization Today Really
Different than Globalization a Hundred Years Ago?," in Brookings
Trade Policy Forum, S. Collins and R. Lawrence, eds, Brookings
Institution, Washington, D.C. (1999).
(8) Also see M. Obsfeld and A. Taylor, Global Capital Markets:
Integration, Crisis, and Growth, Cambridge University Press, (2004).
(9) In "Why Clashes Between Internal and External Stability
Goals End in Currency Crises, 1797-1994, NBER Working Paper No. 5710,
June 1997, Michael D. Bordo and Anna J. Schwartz present a narrative of
the history of currency crises from 1797-1994, which reflects a clash
between internal and external stability goals. In "Some Historical
Evidence 1870-1933 on the Impact and International Transmission of
Financial Crises", NBER Working Paper No. 1606, September 1986,
Bordo examines some historical experience on banking crises.
(10) M. D. Bordo and B. Eichengreen, "Crises Now and Then:
What Lessons from the Last Era of Financial Globalization", NBER
Working Paper No. 8716, January 2002; M. D. Bordo, B. Eichengreen,
D.Klingebiel, and S.Martinez-Peria, "Is the Crisis Problem Growing
More Severe?" Economic Policy, (2001); and M. D. Bordo and B.
Eichengreen, "Is Our Current International Economic Environment
Unusually Crisis Prone?", in International Financial System:
Conference Proceedings, (1999), D. Gruen and L. Cower, eds., Reserve
Bank of Australia, Sydney.
(11) Earlier evidence on the transmission of banking crises is in
M. D. Bordo, "Some Historical Evidence 1870-1933 on the Impact and
Transmission of Financial Crises", NBER Working Paper No. 1606,
September 1986; and M. D. Bordo, B. Mizrach, and A. J. Schwartz,
"Real Versus Pseudo International Systemic Risk: Some Lessons From
History", Review of Pacific Basin Financial Markets and Policies,
(1998).
(12) M. O. Bordo and A. P. Murshid, "Are Financial Crises
Becoming Increasingly More Contagious? What is the Historical Evidence
on Contagion?", NBER Working Paper No. 7900, September 2000.
(13) M. D, Bordo and A. P. Murshid, "Globalization and
Changing Patterns in the International Transmission of Shocks in
Financial Markets", NBER Working Paper No. 9019, June 2002.
(14) This differs from Paulo Mauro, Nathan Sussman, and Yishay
Yafeh, "Emerging Market Spreads: Then Versus Now", Quarterly
Journal of Economics 117, (2002), pp. 695-733, which may be attributed
to the use of different country samples. Our sample contains both
advanced and emerging countries while theirs was based solely on
emerging countries. In "Have National Business Cycles Become More
Synchronized?", NBER Working Paper No. 10130, December 2003, Bordo
and Thomas Helbling also find evidence that global shocks are the key
determinant of the synchronization of business cycle movements observed
across exchange rate regimes from 1880 to the present.
(15) M. D. Bordo, M. Dueker, and D. C. Wheelock, "Aggregate
Price Shocks and Financial Instability: An Historical Analysis",
NBER Working Paper No. 7652, April 2000, and "Aggregate Price
Shocks and Financial Stability: The United Kingdom 1796-1999", NBER
Working Paper No. 8583, November 2001.
(16) In "The International Monetary Fund: Its Present Role in
Historical Perspective," NBER Working Paper No. 7724, June 2000,
Michael D. Bordo and Harold James describe the evolution of the IMF from
its origins as the guardian of the Bretton Woods adjustable peg exchange
rate system and financier of temporary current account deficits for
advanced countries to its present primary roles as development financier
and crisis manager for the emerging world.
(17) In "Keeping Capital Flowing: The Role of the IMF",
NBER Working Paper No. 10834, October 2004, Michael D. Bordo, Ashoka
Mody, and Nienke Oomes find evidence that following the adoption of an
IMF program, both macroeconomic aggregates and capital flows improve,
although they may initially deteriorate somewhat. Consistent with
theoretical predictions and earlier empirical findings, they also find
that IMF programs are most successful in improving capital flows to
countries with bad, but not very bad, fundamentals. In such countries,
IMF programs are also associated with improvements in the fundamental
themselves.
(18) M. D. Bordo and A. Redish, "Is Deflation Depressing?
Evidence from the Classical Gold Standard"; NBER Working Paper No.
9520, March 2003; and M. D. Bordo, J. L. Lane, and A. Redish, "Good
versus Bad Deflation: Lessons from the Gold Standard Era," NBER
Working Paper No. 10329, February 2004.
(19) M. D. Bordo and A. Filardo, "Deflation and Monetary
Policy in a Historical Perspective: Remembering the Past or Being
Condemned to Repeat It?", NBER Working Paper No. 10833, October
2004.
(20) M. D. Bordo and O. Jeanne, "Boom-Busts in Asset Prices,
Economic Instability, and Monetary Policy", NBER Working Paper No.
8966, May 2002.
(21) M. D. Bordo and D. C. Wheelock, "Monetary Policy and
Asset Prices: A Look Back at Past U.S. Stock Market Booms", NBER
Working Paper No. 10704, August 2004.
Michael D. Bordo *
* Bordo is a Research Associate in the NBER's Programs on
Monetary Economics and the Development of the American Economy. He is
also a Professor of Economics at Rutgers University. During 2006-7, he
is the Pitt Professor of Economic History at Cambridge University and a
Fellow at Kings College Cambridge.