Some perspective on capital flows to emerging market economies.
Reinhart, Carmen M.
From Hume's discussion of the specie-flow mechanism under the
gold standard to the Keynes-Ohlin debate on the transfer problem
associated with German reparations after the WWI, understanding the flow
of capital across national borders has been central to international
economics. My work on the topic has focused mainly on the flow of funds between rich and poor countries. Theory tells us that, for the
recipient, foreign capital put to good use can finance investment and
stimulate economic growth. For the investor, capital flows can increase
welfare by enabling a smoother path of consumption over time and,
through better risk sharing as a result of international
diversification, a higher level of consumption.
The reality is that the effects of such flows--as seen from either
recent experience or the longer sweep of history--do not fit neatly into
those theoretical presumptions. As a result, my research has mostly been
directed at shedding light on four questions:
1. What motivates rich-to-poor capital flows?
2. Why doesn't capital flow more from rich to poor countries?
3. What are the consequences of a surge of capital inflows for an
emerging market economy?
4. How do policymakers typically respond to an incipient inflow of
capital?
The Causes of Capital Inflows
The surge in capital inflows to emerging market economies in the
early part of each of the past two decades was attributed initially to
domestic developments, such as sound policies and stronger economic
performance, implying both the good use of such funds in the recipient
country and the informed judgment of investors in the developed world.
(1) The widespread nature of the phenomenon became clearer over time,
though, as most developing countries--whether they had improved,
unchanged, or impaired macroeconomic fundamentals--found themselves the
destination of capital from global financial centers. The single factor
encouraging those flows was the sustained decline in interest rates in
the industrial world. (2) For example, short-term interest rates in the
United States declined steadily in the early 1990s and by late 1992 were
a their lowest level since the early 1960s. Lower interest rates in
developed nations attracted investors to the high yields offered by
economies in Asia and Latin America. Given the high external debt burden
of many of these countries, low world interest rates also appeared to
improve their credit-worthiness and to reduce their default risk. Those
improvements were reflected in a marked rise in secondary market prices
of bank claims on most of the heavily indebted countries and pronounced
gains in equity values. Thus, the tightening of monetary policy in the
United States and the resulting rise in interest rates made investment
in Asia and Latin America relatively less attractive, triggering market
corrections in several emerging stock markets and a decline in the
prices of emerging market debt.
This experience strongly suggests multiple forms of investor
myopia: The initial decision to invest seemed more motivated by reaching
for yield without an appropriate appreciation of risk, and the sudden
withdrawal similarly looked more like a quick dash for the exit door
than a reasoned assessment of fundamentals. Looking back, one is struck
by an overwhelming sense of "deja vu." It certainly seems a
mystery why these wide swings in capital flows recur, in spite of the
major costs associated with them. The common theme is that investors
enter each episode of upsurge in capital flows confident in the belief
that "this time it is different" and look to international
financial institutions to make them whole when they later learn that it
really wasn't different.
Rich-to-Poor Capital Flows
To some, the mystery of cross-border flows is not these recurrent
cycles unanchored from country conditions but rather the restricted
volume of these flows overall. Most famously, Robert Lucas argued that
it was a puzzle that more capital does not flow from rich countries to
poor countries, given back-of-the envelope calculations suggesting
massive differences in physical rates of return in favor of capital poor
countries. (3) Lucas argued that the paucity of capital flows to poor
countries must be rooted in fundamental economic forces, such as
externalities in human capital formation favoring further investment in
already capital rich countries. My perspective, informed by work with
Kenneth Rogoff and Miguel Savastano, is quite different. (4)
Throughout history, governments have demonstrated that "serial
default" is the rule, not the exception. Argentina has famously
defaulted on five occasions since its birth in the 1820s. However,
Argentina's record is surpassed by many countries in the New World
(Brazil, Liberia, Mexico, and Uruguay, Venezuela, and Ecuador) and by
almost as many in the Old World (France, Germany, Portugal, Spain, and
Turkey). Rogoff, Savastano, and I argue that this history of repeated
defaults makes some countries less able to bear debt. These "debt
intolerant" countries typically have other indicia of governmental
failures, including bouts of high inflation, variable macroeconomic
policies, and a weak rule of law.
From this perspective, the key explanation to the
"paradox" of why so little capital flows to poor countries may
be quite simple--countries that do not repay their debts have a
relatively difficult time borrowing from the rest of the world. The fact
that so many poor countries are in default on their debts, that so
little funds are channeled through equity, and that overall private
lending rises more than proportionally with wealth, all strongly support
the view that credit markets and political risk are the main reasons why
we do not see more capital flows to developing countries. If credit
market imperfections abate over time because of better institutions,
then human capital externalities or other "new growth"
elements may come to play a larger role. But as long as the odds of
non-repayment are as high as 65 percent for some low-income countries,
credit risk seems like a far more compelling reason for the paucity of
rich-poor capital flows.
The Consequences of Capital Inflows
The experience of many emerging market economies is that attracting
global investors' attention is a mixed blessing of macroeconomic
imbalances and attendant financial crises. As to the imbalances, a
substantial portion of the surge in capital inflows tends to be
channeled into foreign exchange reserves. For instance, from 1990 to
1994, the share devoted to reserve accumulation averaged 59 percent in
Asia and 35 percent in Latin America. Moreover, in most countries the
capital inflows were associated with widening current account deficits.
This widening in the current account deficit usually involves both
an increase in national investment and a fall in national saving. As one
would expect from the fall in national saving, private consumption
spending typically rises. While disaggregated data on consumption are
not available for all emerging market economies, the import data are
consistent with the interpretation that the consumption boom is heavily
driven by rising imports of durable goods. (This held with particular
force in the Latin American experience of the early 1990s.) In almost
all countries, capital inflows were accompanied by rapid growth in the
money supply--both in real and nominal terms--and sharp increases in
stock and real estate prices. For example, during 1991, a major equity
index in Argentina posted a dollar return in excess of 400 percent,
while Chile and Mexico provided returns of about 100 percent.
Then comes the crisis because the surge in capital flows never
proves durable. Unlike their more developed counterparts, emerging
market economies routinely lose access to international capital markets.
Furthermore, given the common reliance on short-term debt financing, the
public and private sectors in these countries often are asked to repay
their existing debts on short notice. Even with the recent large-scale
rescue packages, official financing only makes up for part of this
shortfall. Hence, the need for abrupt adjustment arises.
More often than not, contagion followed on the heels of the initial
shock. The capacity for a swift and drastic reversal of capital
flows--the so-called "sudden stop" problem--played a
significant role. (5) An analysis of the experience of contagious
financial crises over two centuries (with my colleagues Graciela
Kaminsky and Carlos Vegh) finds typically that the announcements that
set off the chain reactions came as a surprise to financial markets. (6)
The distinction between anticipated and unanticipated events appears
critical, because advance warning allows investors to adjust their
portfolios in anticipation of the event. In all cases where there were
significant immediate international repercussions, a leveraged common
creditor was involved--be it commercial banks, hedge funds, mutual
funds, or individual bondholders--who helped to propagate the contagion
across national borders.
Additional work with Graciela Kaminsky indicates that contagion is
more regional than global. (7) We find that susceptibility to contagion
is highly nonlinear. A single country falling victim to a crisis is not
a particularly good predictor of crisis elsewhere, be it in the same
region or in another part of the globe. However, if several countries
fall prey, then it is a different story. That is, the probability of a
domestic crisis rises sharply if a core group of countries are already
infected. Is the regional complexion of contagion attributable to trade
links, as some studies have suggested, or to financial
links--particularly through the role played by banks? Our results
suggest that it is difficult to distinguish between the two, because
most countries linked in trade are also linked in finance. In the Asian
crises of 1997, Japanese banks played a similar role in propagating
disturbances to that played by U.S. banks in the debt crisis of the
early 1980s.
I identify the links between these episodes of currency crises and
banking crises in another paper with Graciela Kaminsky. (8) In
particular, problems in the banking sector typically precede a currency
crisis, creating a vicious spiral in which the currency strains then
deepen the banking problems. The anatomy of these episodes suggests that
crises occur as the economy enters a recession, following a prolonged
boom in economic activity that was fueled by credit, capital inflows,
and accompanied by an overvalued currency.
The Policy Response
Given this experience of wide swings in foreign funding, it is not
surprising that policymakers in many emerging market economies have come
to fear large current account deficits, irrespective of how they are
financed, but particularly if they are financed by short-term debt. The
capital inflow slowdown or reversal could push the country into
insolvency or drastically lower the productivity of its existing capital
stock. These multiple concerns have produced multiple responses to
capital inflows.
The policy of first recourse across countries and over time has
been sterilized intervention. (9) To avoid some (or all) of the nominal
exchange rate appreciation that would have resulted from the capital
inflow, monetary authorities have tended to intervene in the foreign
exchange market and accumulate foreign exchange reserves. To offset some
or all of the associated monetary expansion, central banks have most
often opted to sell Treasury bills or central bank paper. Central banks
also have tools to neutralize the effects on the money stock of their
foreign exchange operations beyond offsetting domestic open market
transactions. Importantly, the effect of the sale (purchase) of domestic
currency can be offset by raising (lowering) reserve requirements to
keep the money stock constant. (10) However, as long as domestic
reserves do not pay a competitive interest rate, reserve requirements
are a tax on the banking system. Changes in the tax can have real
effects, including on the exchange value of the currency. Moreover,
depending on the incidence of the reserve tax, domestic spending and
production may change as well.
Fiscal austerity measures, particularly on the spending side, have
been used to alleviate some of the pressures on the real exchange rate
and to cool down overheating in the economy. Furthermore, fiscal
surpluses deposited at the central bank have helped to
"sterilize" the expansive monetary effects of foreign exchange
purchases.
The process of trade liberalization has been accelerated in some
cases, in the hope that productivity gains in the nontraded sector could
dampen pressures on the real exchange rate. Moreover, reducing
distortions associated with controls on trade may temporarily widen the
current account deficit--effectively absorbing some of the inflows
without boosting domestic demand.
Liberalization of capital outflows also has been a popular response
to rising capital inflows. By permitting domestic residents to hold
foreign assets, the conventional wisdom holds, gross outflows would
increase--thereby reducing net.
Various forms of controls on capital inflows--whether in the form
of taxes, quantitative restrictions, or in the guise of "prudential
measures"--have been imposed on the financial sector, usually with
the aim of deterring short-term inflows. (11) (Sometimes these controls
take the form of prudential measures to curb the exposure of the
domestic banking sector to the vagaries of real estate prices and equity
markets.) One main finding of my paper with Todd Smith, however, is that
the tax rate on capital inflows must be very high in order to have much
effect on the capital account balance. (12) For instance, a reduction in
the capital account balance by 5 percent of GDP would require a tax rate
on net interest payments on foreign-held debt on the order of 85 percent
for one year or 60 percent for two years.
Allowing the nominal exchange rate to appreciate (or be revalued in
cases where the exchange arrangement is less flexible) also has to be
considered as part of the menu of viable policy responses, particularly
as inflows become persistent. As noted in my paper with Reinhart,
long-lived attempts to avoid a nominal appreciation via unsterilized
foreign exchange market intervention will fuel a monetary expansion
(owing to the accumulation of foreign exchange reserves), which may
prove inflationary. While sterilized intervention may curtail the
monetary expansion, it can become both increasingly difficult to
implement and costly over time. In some cases, the authorities reached
the conclusion that, if an appreciation of the real exchange rate was
inevitable, it was better that it occur through a change in the nominal
exchange rate than through a pick-up in domestic inflation.
Often, policymakers have resorted to some combination of these
polities. A repeated lesson is that the law of unintended consequences
has not been repealed. Multiple policy responses to capital inflows have
tended to interact in ways that were probably not anticipated by the
framers of such policies. Most likely, even the best policy mix cannot
altogether avoid the eventual reversal of capital flows, given that they
are so sensitive to the behavior of investors in financial centers. The
appropriate policy mix may dampen the amplitude of the swings in capital
flows, thus ensuring a softer landing when international investors
retrench. The strongest policy lesson is that conservative fiscal policy
and zealous supervision of the domestic financial sector are essential
at all times, especially when expectations are buoyant.
(1) The experience of the early 1990s is discussed in G.A. Calvo,
L. Leiderman, and C.M. Reinhart, "Inflows of Capital to Developing
Countries in the 1990s," Journal of Economic Perspectives, 10 (2)
(Spring 1996), pp. 123-39. Comparisons between that episode and the
Asian crises are drawn in G. L. Kaminsky and C.M. Reinhart,
"Financial Crises in Asia and Latin America: Then and Now,"
American Economic Review, (May 1998), pp. 444-8.
(2) Regression evidence on the determinants of regional capital
flows is provided in C.M. Reinhart and V. R. Reinhart, "What Hurts
Most: G-3 Exchange Rate or Interest Rate Volatility?" in S. Edwards
and J. A. Frankel, eds. Preventing Currency Crises in Emerging Markets,
Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 2001, pp. 73-99.
(3) R. Lucas, "Why Doesn't Capital Flow from Rich to Poor
Countries," American Economic Review, (May 1990), pp. 92-6.
(4) C.M. Reinhart and K.S. Rogoff, "Serial Default and the
'Paradox' of Rich-to-Poor Capital Flows," NBER Working
Paper No. 10296, February 2004, and American Economic Review, 94 (2),
(May 2004), pp. 53-9, and C.M. Reinhart, K.S. Rogoff, and M. Savastano,
"Debt Intolerance," NBER Working Paper No. 9908, August 2003,
and Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, (Spring 2003), pp. 1-74.
(5) A term coined by Guillermo A. Calvo (see the discussion in G.A.
Calvo and C.M. Reinhart, "When Capital Inflows Come to a Sudden
Stop: Consequences and Policy Options" in E Kenen and A. Swoboda,
eds., Reforming the International Monetary and Financial System,
Washington DC: International Monetary Fund, 2000, pp. 175-201.)
(6) G.L. Kaminsky, C.M. Reinhart, and C.A. Vegh, "The Unholy
Trinity of Financial Contagion," NBER Working Paper No. 10061,
November 2003, and Journal of Economic Perspectives, 17 (4), (Fall
2003), pp. 51-74.
(7) G.L. Kaminsky and C.M. Reinhart, "The Center and the
Periphery: The Globalization of Financial Shocks," NBER Working
Paper No. 9479, February 2003, forthcoming in C.M. Reinhart, C. A. Vegh
and A. Velasco, eds. Capital Flows, Crisis, and Stabilization: Essays in
Honor of Guillermo A. Calvo.
(8) For a fuller discussion, see G.L. Kaminksy and C.M. Reinhart,
"The Twin Crises: The Causes of Banking and Balance-of-Payment
Problems," American Economic Review, 89 (3), (June 1999), pp.
473-500.
(9) I have documented the typical policy responses in C.M. Reinhart
and V.R. Reinhart, "Some Lessons for Policy Makers Who Deal with
the Mixed Blessing of Capital Inflows," in M. Kahler, ed., Capital
Flows and Financial Crises, Council on Foreign Relations Book, Ithaca,
NY: Cornell University Press, 1998, pp. 93-127.
(10) This is discussed in C.M. Reinhart and V.R. Reinhart, "On
the Use of Reserve Requirements in Dealing with the Capital-Flow
Problem," International Journal of Finance and Economics, 4 (1),
(January 1999), pp. 27-54.
(11) A survey of the literature on capital controls is provided in
N. Magud and C.M. Reinhart, "Capital Controls: An Evaluation"
in S. Edwards, ed., International Capital Flows, forthcoming from the
University of Chicago Press.
(12) C.M. Reinhart and R.T. Smith, "Temporary Controls on
Capital Inflows," NBER Working Paper No. 8422, August 2001, and
Journal of International Economics, 57 (2), August 2002, pp. 327-51.
Carment M. Reinhart, Reinhart is a Research Associate in the
NBER's Program on International Finance and Macroeconomics and a
professor of economics at the University of Maryland. Her profile
appears later in this issue.