Economics of Education. (Program Report).
Hoxby, Caroline M.
The NBER's Economics of Education Program has just celebrated
its first anniversary, having started officially in September 2001.
However, the program was created to recognize the large and rapidly
growing body of economic research on education. It was felt that
education, as a topic, needed a home of its own, partly to encourage
progress and partly to encourage rigor. Progress happens faster when
economists researching the same topic talk to one another, instead of
each presenting research to his own field audience. Education topics
force researchers to draw upon several economic fields, so rigor is
enhanced when public economists ensure that their fellow researchers get
the public economics right, macroeconomists ensure that the
macroeconomics is right, and so on. Members of The Economics of
Education Program are drawn from labor economics, public economics,
macroeconomics and growth, industrial organization and contracts,
development economics, and urban economics. Every field makes its
special contributio n. For instance, macroeconomics emphasizes the
intergenerational consequences of education investment; development
economists offer up evaluations of striking policy experiments that
would be too daring for most developed countries. The necessarily brief
coverage of a program report lends itself to describing empirical work,
rather than theoretical work. However, many of the important
contributions to the Program have been made by theorists, whose Working
Papers and presentations have been crucial to moving the economics of
education forward.
In its first year, the Economics of Education Program held two
program meetings and two conferences. Members wrote 60-some Working
Papers on education. In addition, program members interested in higher
education attended two Higher Education Working Group meetings,
organized by Charles T. Clotfelter. The program has thus far spawned two
volumes: The Economics of School Choice (ESC), which will be published
in early 2003 by University of Chicago Press; and College Decisions: New
Economic Research on Higher Education (CD), which will be published
about a year later. Although most program members are drawn from
economics or similar departments, some are economists at graduate
schools of education who help the program stay in touch with that world
of research. The conferences have included policymakers and
administrators, as well as program members.
What is the operating environment of the Economics of Education
Program? Recent years have seen a host of policy developments for
economists of education to master, and these will be described later.
However, the most important development is probably not a policy one,
but the now-almost-ubiquitous realization that U.S. comparative
advantage and economic growth are highly dependent on skill-intensive
industries [9071, 8337, 7288, 68813. Americans, from "men on the
street" to legislators, have concluded that the economic future
depends on the supply of skilled workers, and this realization has given
urgency to education reform. There is, of course, a correspondingly
urgent need for education research.
With so much research going on, this report must be far more
selective than I would like. Rather than attempting to discuss all the
work, I focus on some recent policy changes that are driving research
and a few themes that appear and reappear in Program members' work.
K-12 Policy Developments that have been Stimulating Research
Several policy developments in elementary and secondary
("K-12") education are stimulating research. The most obvious
is the school choice movement, which naturally draws economists because
it raises interesting questions about incentives, market structure,
public financing, housing choice, and intergenerational investments in
human capital. The recent Supreme Court decision in Zelman versus
Simmons-Harris (the Ohio voucher case) is sure to provide a fillip to
research, as it will unleash a new wave of reforms. Owing to the Coures
advice, many of the reforms will be "mixed" (blending
vouchers, charter schools, magnet schools, intra-district choice, and
open enrollment among districts). Program members are eager to analyze
such mixed reforms: their research already suggests that different
choice plans generate different incentives.
For instance, empirical work suggests that magnet schools keep the
more affluent and education-oriented in central city districts (though
not, of course, in the same schools as most central city children.) [See
Julie Berry Cullen, Brian A. Jacob, and Steven Levitt, "Does School
Choice Attract Students to Urban Public Schools? Evidence from over
1,000 Randomized Lotteries," July 2002; 7888]. Other work
demonstrates that a district that enacts intra-district choice will lose
its most education-oriented families, and part of its tax base with them
[ESC, 7850]. Vouchers work differently when they are based on a
child's own household income, the incomes of a district's
children, or the failure of the child's school [ESC, 7956, 7239].
Although competition from both charter schools and vouchers seems to
raise the achievement of students in both choice schools and local
public schools, the achievement effect depends on the parameters of the
program [8873, 8343].
The 2002 No Child Left Behind (NCLB) act may provoke some
intra-district choice action, but NCLB is mainly an accountability
policy. Accountability is the second major policy movement stimulating
research. Partly because of Goals 2000 (which advocated accountability)
but mainly because of state legislatures' frustration with schools
that had not improved despite increased state funding, 49 states created
accountability systems during the 1990s. The systems vary widely, but
generally include statewide testing, school report cards, and some
guidance to schools about the curriculum for which they will be held
responsible. NCLB will regularize and give greater permanence to these
systems.
The accountability movement has stimulated research for two
reasons. First, it has unleashed a flood of data that has made analysis
of many topics more feasible. More than half of the recent NBER Working
Papers on education could not have been written without data generated
by accountability systems. [Studies that reveal the richness of the data
now available include 8916, 8918, 8599, 8502, 8156, and 7867.] Second,
accountability systems are inherently interesting: they pose fascinating
questions of incentive design.
Program members have been quick to point out the flaws in the
incentives generated by the first generation of states'
accountability systems. For instance, accountability systems that focus
on year-to-year gains in achievement (as opposed to achievement levels,
or some combination of gains and levels) tend to over-reward and
over-penalize small schools, which are more likely to display unusually
large or small gains, simply because noisy measures of students'
achievement are less likely to average out [8156]. Systems that have
only one cut-off (such as pass-fail) or a few cut-offs tend to focus
schools' effort on the group of students whose performance is just
below the cut-off [8968, 7875]. Cut-offs also can have unintended
effects on house prices, property tax bases, and ultimately school
budgets; house prices in the attendance areas of schools that just fail
to meet a cut-off can fall substantially relative to those in areas that
just meet it [8019, 9054]. Systems in which tests are unproctored and in
whic h there is no turnover of test items invite cheating. Lest all the
research sound like carping, it is nice to note that it has been
constructive. Some of the evidence described has influenced the
provisions and implemention of the NCLB act. Moreover, another study
demonstrates that sophisticated accountability systems cost only
trivially more than the simplest ones [8855].
School finance reforms, which change the ways in which states raise
revenue for schools and redistribute among them, provide the impetus for
important work on school finance -- not just empirical analysis of
American data, but also innovative theoretical work and analysis of the
distinctive systems used in other countries. Recent school finance
reforms that have attracted attention include those of New York,
Michigan, Texas, and Massachusetts. Analyzing such reforms has proved to
be a classic problem that demonstrates the challenges and promises of
the economics of education. Researchers have found that it is essential
to know the institutions; but applying public economics and urban
economics is equally necessary for progress [8355, 8269]. School finance
reforms have been shown to interact with property tax limitations, and
there is increasing evidence that suggests that school finance reforms
and property tax limitations are not independent (reforms cause
limitation and vice versa).
Working out the implications of school finance for economic growth
and income inequality has proven to be a fascinating, complex problem
for macroeconomists and calibrators [8588, 8377, 8101, 7986, 7450,
7132]. It is difficult to draw simple implications from this literature
because much depends on the degree to which ability is inherited and
whether peer effects are important. A splendid development in this
literature is the incorporation of political economy, so that the
parameters of the school finance system arise endogenously in recent
models [ESC]. Another development worth highlighting is the increasingly
close relationship between school finance and school choice research.
For instance, calibration suggests that income-equalizing vouchers are a
school finance method that raises growth and reduces inequality relative
to other currently available systems [ESC]. (Intuitively, vouchers can
be better targeted because they are individual-specific; also, with
vouchers, greater redistribution is sustainable i n a realistic
political economy.)
College Policy Developments that have been Stimulating Research
The last several years have seen important changes in the nature of
government intervention in higher education. The most obvious has been
states' shifting toward merit scholarships and away from
subsidizing tuition at public colleges (a policy that benefits all
college-going students similarly, regardless of their need and merit).
Many people know about Georgia's Hope Scholarship, which eliminates
tuition at in-state public colleges and provides substantial
scholarships to in-state private colleges for B+ students. However,
similar programs exist in 12 other states and many other states have
reallocated their higher education budgets towards meritorious students
in other ways. Merit scholarships appear to be gaining sway because
states are worried about being left behind by the "new"
skilled-based economy. Not surprisingiy, the shift toward merit
scholarships has occurred disproportionately in areas where this worry
is greatest: the South, the Southwest, and the Rust Belt.
Recent research shows that state aid based on merit tends not to
increase enrollment greatly but does induce students to attend public
universities more often [CD, 7756]. Even California's Calgrants
program, a generous scholarship based on both merit and need, raises
enrollment only modestly [See Thomas Kane, "A Quasi-Experimental
Estimate of the Impact of Financial Aid on College-Going," August
2002]. The limited effects on enrollment probably reflect the fact that
the most meritorious students would have attended college in any case.
Interestingly, there is also no evidence of significant reductions in
attendance at out-of-state private universities, suggesting that
students whose decisions are most affected by the aid were not likely to
attend college out-of-state anyway. Other recent work explores the value
of keeping meritorious students in-state [CD, 8555].
Many people are surprised to hear that the largest federal program
for education is not the Pell Grant or Title I, but the tuition tax
credits enacted in 1998. Called the Hope and Lifelong Learning Tax
Credits, these programs are not only large now, but are likely to grow
much larger as they become more familiar. Currently, only a small share
of eligible taxpayers take the credits. Essentially, the tax credits are
a middle class tax cut with unusual incidence (middle class because the
credits cannot be used in conjunction with a Pell grant and because the
phase outs exclude upper-income households). Research suggests that the
credits have very limited effects of enrollment, leading only to some
"upgrading" of college attendance [CD].
If there is any theme to the recent evidence on aid and college
attendance, it is that less recent federal aid programs, including the
GI Bill, raised enrollment [7452, 7655, 7422], but that credit
constraints are no longer a serious problem for students who are
prepared for college. So, aid tends to alter the college they choose,
rather than whether they go to college at all [9228, 9055, 7761].
Saving for college is a tricky issue because savers are taxed
implicitly by need-based aid [4032]. However, recent research suggests
that college savings may be receiving a "shot in the arm" from
three new tax-preferred college savings programs: Coverdell savings
accounts; states' 529 college savings accounts; and states'
pre-paid college savings plans [CD]. The Coverdell savings account is a
Roth IRA designed for college saving: interest accumulates tax-free and
qualified withdrawals are untaxed. The states' 529 accounts are
similar, but are more generous: contribution limits are higher and some
contributions are tax-deductible. States' pre-paid plans are the
least flexible: account-holders are constrained to use them at certain
colleges or lose most of the benefits.
Teachers
Teachers are attracting a great deal of attention, not because
policies are changing much, but because researchers are overcoming
obstacles that prevented them from assessing teachers'
effectiveness. Newly released data have been essential in this area.
There is increasing evidence that differences among teachers account for
much of the variation in achievement associated with schools (as opposed
to families or innate ability). However, the evidence is not what one
might expect. It suggests that a teacher's effect, though important
and separately identifiable, is unrelated to her credentials and even
in-service training [6691, 8916, but see 6781, 8432, and 7866]. Other
work shows that teachers, perhaps because pay is so compressed, decide
where to teach mainly on the basis of convenient location and
students' socio-demographics. A teacher may accept a pay cut to get
a job closer to her home and with more affluent students [See Donald
Boyd, Hamilton Lankford, Susanna Loeb, and James Wyckoff, "The
Joint Decisio ns of Teachers and Schools: How Teachers Sort on Initial
Job Matches," August 2002; 8599; 7082]. Recent studies have added
evidence to the longstanding suspicion that teacher quality has declined
in the United States [9180, 8898, 8263]. Evidence from an Israeli
experiment suggests that teachers respond constructively when offered
monetary incentives to ensure that their students pass a college
preparation exam [See Victor Lavy, "Rank Order Tournaments among
Teachers as Performance Incentive Schemes: Experimental Evidence about
Their Effect on Students Outcomes," August 2002].
Peer Effects
Peers effects are another important theme in recent research. (I am
construing peer effects broadly to include all spillovers caused by the
presence of a peer, regardless of the channel.) Peer effects arise
frequently for several reasons. First, they are often the crucial
element in models linking education and economic growth [8101]. Second,
the market for higher education is almost impossible to explain
coherently without postulating the presence of peer effects [CD].
Finally, many debates on school choice hinge on peer effects [ESC, 7854,
7850]. In all three cases, the form and not the mere existence of peer
effects is key. As a rule, interesting theories require peer effects
that are nonlinear, but require different nonlinearities that are
mutually exclusive. For instance, growth models often posit that low
achieving students benefit most from high achieving peers; higher
education models posit the reverse. Fortunately, Program members
recently have devised clever ways to identify peer effects empirically
(a very difficult thing to do because, as a rule, people select their
own peers). Randomly assigned roommates and other natural experiments
have been used to study peer effects in college and graduate school
[9025, 7469]. Researchers of K-12 education have exploited natural and
policy experiments from population variation, desegregation, and housing
mobility programs [9263, 8741, 8502, 8345, 7999, 7973, 7867, 7444].
Educational policies in developing countries sometimes shift peers
substantially -- these also have been exploited to identify peer
effects. As a rule, the evidence suggests that peer effects exist, but
their forms (especially non-linearities) are barely understood as yet.
Education Expansion in Developing Countries
Making primary education universal is a common goal for developing
countries, but what are the effects of policies designed to greatly
expand enrollment? Indonesia's experience is that an aggressive
school building program raises enrollment but then depresses the return
to education when the more educated cohorts hit the labor market [8710,
7860]. Incentives for school building can lead to an inefficient number
of schools even though they raise enrollment [see Michael Kremer, Sylvie
Moulin, and Robert Namunyu, "The Political Economy of School
Finance in Kenya," August 2002]; and changes in school resources
that seem incredibly cheap by American standards also raise enrollment
substantially [8481, 7399]. If there is any theme in the evidence, it is
that greater resources for schools in developing countries bring more
children and more marginal children into school, so that researchers
find it harder to identify improvements in achievement than to identify
increases in enrollment.
Technology
So far, I have not mentioned "education production
functions" (the attempt to estimate the relationship between school
inputs and outputs) which once were the staple fare in the economics of
education. Many of the studies described above have education production
functions embedded in them, but recent work scarcely resembles the
conventional linear regression of a test score on a series of school
characteristics. This is not because researchers have gotten tired of
class size or school spending, but because recent work tends to exploit
interesting policy or natural experiments or carefully explores the
foundations and implications of different education production functions
[9054, 8918, 9040, 7820, 7656, 7349]. Technology is the one truly new
school input. Program members have studied the effects of computers in
the classroom [7424], of federal internet subsidies [9090], and even, in
developing countries, of flip-charts [8018]. So far, the evidence seems
to suggest that technology has at best weak effects on achievement.
Undoubtedly, much more evidence will be forthcoming in this area as
technology spreads and our measures of it improve.
In Conclusion
Education-related research is likely to remain a growth area in
economics for some time, largely because of the importance of skills for
understanding economic growth and income inequality. However, other
conditions are favorable as well. Education is an excellent area for the
arbitrage and elaboration of existing theory: many of the problems are
inherently rich, amenable to analysis, and under-studied. It is also
unusually easy to observe the behavior of key "actors" because
they operate in a semi-public domain. (It is much easier to find out
what a private college does than what a private firm does.) Data
availability is improving continuously -- partly because of technology,
partly because of accountability, and partly because economists gain
better access as they become ever more significant contributors to the
field.
Caroline M. Hoxby *
* Hoxby is the Director of the NBER's Program on Economics of
Education and a Professor of economics at Harvard University. Most of
the numbers in brackets throughout this report refer to NBER Working
Papers. A complete list of NBER Education Working Papers can be found at
h://papers.nber.org/papersbyprog//ED.html