Technology and inequality. (Research Summaries).
Acemoglu, Daron
Many OECD economies have experienced sharp increases in wage and
income inequality over the past several decades. In the United States,
for example, the college premium -- the wages of college graduates
relative to the wages of high school graduates -- increased by over 25
percent between 1979 and 1995. Overall earnings inequality also soared:
in 1971, a worker at the 90th percentile of the wage distribution earned
266 percent more than a worker at the 10th percentile. By 1995 this
number had risen to 366 percent. (1) Are new technologies -- in
particular, computers, computer-assisted machines and robotics, and
advances in communication technology -- responsible for these changes?
More generally, what are the implications of technical change for the
labor market?
Some economists now believe that, although other factors including
the decline in the real value of the minimum wage, de-unionization, and
globalization have played some role, the major driving force behind the
changes in the U.S. wage structure is technology. This consensus is
built on the notion of technology-skill complementarity: technical
change favors more skilled (educated) workers, replaces tasks previously
performed by the unskilled, and increases the demand for skills.
Consequently, many commentators see a direct causal relationship between
technological changes and these radical shifts in the distribution of
wages taking place in the U.S. economy. (2)
Although the consensus is now broad, the idea that technological
advances favor more skilled workers is a 20th-century phenomenon. In
19th-cenwry Britain, skilled artisans destroyed weaving spinning and
threshing machines during the Luddite and Captain Swing riots, in the
belief that the new machines would make their skills redundant. They
were right: the artisan shop was replaced by the factory and later by
interchangeable parts and the assembly line. Products previously
manufactured by skilled artisans came to be produced in factories by
workers with relatively few skills, and many previously complex tasks
were simplified, reducing the demand for skilled workers.
A major 19th-century technological advance, interchangeable parts,
in fact was designed to be "skill-replacing"
(un-skill-biased). Eli Whitney, a pioneer of interchangeable parts,
described the objective of this technology as: "to substitute
correct and effective operations of machinery for the skill of the
artist which is acquired only by long practice and experience; a species
of skill which is not possessed in this country to any considerable
extent." (3)
There are also no compelling theoretical reasons to expect
technological change always and everywhere to be skill-biased. On the
contrary, if replacing skilled workers is more profitable, new
technologies may attempt to replace skilled workers, just as
interchangeable parts did. Even the most purportedly skill-biased
technological advance, the microchip, can be used in scanners to
complement unskilled work just as effectively as in personal computers
to complement skilled workers.
Recent research takes these issues into consideration and analyzes
the origins of skill bias and the conditions under which new
technologies would be more or less skill biased. In this article, I
survey some of this recent research, and how it might shed light on the
recent increase in inequality. I also briefly discuss the links between
technology and trade, technology and changes in the organization of
production, the interaction between technical change and labor market
institutions, and potential reasons for cross-country differences in
inequality tends.
Technology and the Recent Changes in Wage Inequality
There is general agreement among economists that technical change
in the United States and the OECD over the past 60 years, or even over
the past century, has been skill-biased. That is because the past 60
years have seen a large increase in the supply of more educated workers,
yet returns to education have risen. In the absence of substantial skill
bias in technology, the large increase in the supply of skilled workers
would have depressed the skill premium, as the economy moved along a
downward-sloping relative demand curve -- in other words, as skilled
workers substituted for the unskilled in production and as consumers
substituted goods produced using skilled workers intensively for
labor-intensive goods. Because this did not happen, the relative demand
for skills must have increased, most likely because of changes in
technology. Of course here, "technology" needs to be construed
broadly: it is not simply the techniques and machines available to
firms, but also the organization of production, organization of labor
markets, consumer tastes, and so on.
Many commentators in fact believe that there has been an
acceleration in skill bias beginning in the 1970s or the 1980s. The most
popular, but by no means the only, version of this hypothesis claims
that there has been a notable acceleration in the skill bias of
technology, driven by advances in information technology, or perhaps a
"Third Industrial Revolution." A variety of studies document
how the introduction of many modern technologies often is associated
with an increase in the employment of and demand for more skilled
workers. (4) But probably the most powerful argument in favor of an
acceleration in skill bias is that returns to schooling rose over the
past 30 years despite the unusually rapid increase in the supply of
educated workers. As a result of the entry of the large and
well-educated baby-boom cohort starting in the late 1960s, and because
of the Vietnam-era draft laws and increasing government support for
higher education, the educational attainment of the US. labor force
increased sharply sta rting in the early 1970s. Consequently, the
relative supply of skills increased more rapidly on average in the three
decades following 1970 than in the previous three decades. Without an
acceleration in skill bias, we would expect a slower increase in the
returns to education in the post-1970 era. In contrast, the U.S. skill
premium increased rapidly during the past three decades, while it was
approximately constant in the pre-1970 era. Furthermore, during this
time period the U.S. labor market also experienced a sharp increase in
within-group inequality -- that is, inequality among similarly educated
workers, which likely indicates the presence of some new and powerful
forces. (5)
Endogenous Technical Change
Why did the demand for skills accelerate over this period? And why
has new technology favored more skilled workers throughout the 20th
century, but not during the 19th century as was discussed above? One
approach views technology as exogenous, stemming from advances in
science or from the behavior of entrepreneurs driven by a variety of
nonprofit motives. By this approach, demand for skills increased faster
during the past 30 years, this approach would maintain, because of a
technological revolution led by the microchip, personal computers, and
perhaps the Internet.
However, the fact that skill-biased technical change accelerated
more or less immediately after the relative supply of more educated
workers accelerated, starting in the early 1970s, is a bit of a
coincidence. This makes me lean towards a theory that links changes in
the relative supply of and the demand for skills, and attempts to
explain why new technologies have been skill-biased throughout the 20th
century and have become more so during the past 30 years. The first step
in the argument is the realization that technology is not simply an
outside force acting on the labor market and wage inequality. Rather it
is an outcome of the decisions made by firms and workers, in the same
way as the level of employment or wages are. In other words, technology
is "endogenous" (6)
The spinning and weaving machines of the 19th century were invented
because they were profitable. They were profitable because they replaced
the scarce and expensive factors -- the skilled artisans -- by
relatively cheap and abundant factors -- unskilled manual labor of men,
women, and children. Similarly, electrical machinery, air-conditioning,
large organizations all were introduced because they presented profit
opportunities for entrepreneurs. If various new machines and production
methods came into being when called forth by profit opportunities, it is
also likely that further skill-biased technical change and an
acceleration in skill bias are also, at least in part, responses to
profit incentives. Put simply and extremely, it can be argued that the
increased skill bias of technology throughout the 20th century and its
acceleration during the past 30 years resulted from the changes in
profit opportunities which were, in turn, a consequence of the steady
increase in the supply of skilled workers over the p ast century and its
surge starting in the early 1970s.
Directed Technical Change and the Demand for Skills
But why is the skill bias of technology related to the supply of
skilled workers? The basic idea is that technical change will be
directed towards more profitable areas. (7) In particular, when
developing skill-biased techniques is more profitable, new technology
will tend to be skill-biased.
Two factors determine the profitability of new technologies: the
price effect and the market size effect. When relative prices change,
the relative profitability of different types of technologies also
changes. Technologies used predominantly in the production of goods that
are now more expensive will be demanded more, and the invention and
improvement of these technologies will become more profitable.
Similarly, the potential market size for a technology is a first-order
determinant of its profitability. Everything else equal, it is more
profitable to introduce machines that will be used by a larger number of
workers because these greater market sizes will enable greater sales and
profits for the producers and inventors. It is through the market size
effect that an increase in the supply of skills induces technology to
become more skill biased. Consequently, when there are more skilled
workers around, the market size effect will make the production of
skill-complementary machines and technologies more profit able. Somewhat
surprisingly, this market size effect can be so strong that the relative
demand curve for skills can be upward sloping in contrast to the
standard downwardsloping relative demand curve. In this case, the skill
premium and returns to education will be higher when there are more
skilled workers in the economy.
In this light, the recent acceleration in the skill bias of
technology is potentially a response to the rapid increase in the supply
of skills starting in the early 1970s. As the market size for
skill-complementary technologies such as personal computers or
computer-assisted machinery expanded, it became more profitable to
create and introduce more such technologies. This hypothesis not only
explains the increase in the demand for skills, and the resulting rise
in the returns to education and inequality, but also helps us understand
the timing of the increase. New technologies take a while to be created
and brought to the market. Therefore, the first effect of a large
increase in the relative supply of skills might be to move the economy
along a downward-sloping constant-technology relative demand curve.
However, as new skill-biased technologies are brought to the market,
this constant-technology relative demand curve shifts out, increasing
returns to education, potentially even beyond its initial level. (8)
What about the secular skill-biased technical change throughout the
20th century? Perhaps there is a natural explanation: the relative
supply of skilled workers has been increasing throughout the century, so
we should expect steady skill-biased technical change. What about the
skill-replacing technologies of the 19th century? One possible,
conjectural argument is that the early 19th century was characterized by
skill-replacing developments because the increased supply of unskilled
workers in the English cities (resulting from migration from rural areas
and from Ireland) made the introduction of these technologies
profitable. (9) Therefore, a theory of directed technical change
provides us with an explanation for: secular skill-biased technical
change throughout the 20th century; the rise in inequality over the past
several decades; and, possibly, the skill-replacing technologies of the
early 19th century.
Globalization and Inequality
Another major economic development of the past 30 years is the
increased globalization of production, and greater trade between the
United States and less developed nations (LDCs). A number of
commentators have suggested that globalization and increased trade might
be responsible for the rise in U.S. inequality. The arguments above --
that technological change has been important in the rise in inequality
-- do not imply that other factors, such as globalization, have not
played a major role.
Nevertheless, most economists discount the role of globalization
and trade for a variety of reasons. First, the volume of trade is still
small. Second, the major intervening mechanism for the trade
explanation, a large increase in the relative prices of skill-intensive
goods because of greater world demand for these, has not been observed.
Third, inequality also has increased in many of the LDCs trading with
the United States, whereas the simplest trade and globalization
explanations predict a decline in inequality in relatively skill-scarce
economies, like the LDCs.
But trade and giobalization may have been more important than
traditionally assumed. Trade influences what types of technologies are
more profitable to develop. In particular, trade creates a tendency for
the price of skill-intensive products to increase. Then, via the price
effect emphasized above, the incentives for the introduction of new
skill-biased technologies are strengthened. In other words, trade and
giobalization induce further skillbiased technical change.
With this type of induced technical change, trade can have a larger
effect on inequality than traditional calculations suggest. Moreover, it
can do so without a large impact on the relative prices of
skill-intensive goods because the induced technical change will help
boost the supply of these goods. As a result, we may not even see much
evidence of the original triggering mechanism, the change in relative
prices. Finally, to the extent that the LDCs are also using technologies
developed in the United States and the OECD, there will be a force
towards increasing inequality in those countries as well, counteracting
the static equalizing effects of trade in economies with relative skill
scarcity. (10)
Changes in the Organization of Production
The increase in the demand for skills and inequality in the U.S.
economy may be as much attributable to the changes in the organization
of production as to the direct effect of new technologies. Today's
production relations, how jobs and monitoring are organized, and how
firms recruit employees are all very different from 30 years (11)
A perspective that views technology, and the organization of
production, as endogenous is also helpful in thinking about these
issues. An important driving force of the changes in production may be
the increased supply of skills. When skilled workers are scarce, it is
not profitable for firms to design their jobs specifically for skilled
workers and to be extremely selective in their recruitment. In such a
world, firms are often happy to hire many low-skill workers, train them,
and employ them in relatively well-paid jobs. In contrast, in a world
with many skilled workers, it pays to design jobs specifically for them
and to be more selective in recruiting. This increases the productivity
and pay of more skilled workers, and effectively excludes low- and
medium-skilled workers from well-paid jobs. (12)
Many of the developments in the U.S. labor market, including the
recent trends in recruitment and human resource practices, the
disappearance of middle-level-pay occupations, reduced training for
low-skill employees, the greater dispersion in capital-labor ratios
across industries, and the reduced mismatch between workers and jobs,
can be explained by a theory based on an induced change in the
organization of production and associated changes in recruiting
strategies. (13) Moreover, such an approach can explain the decline in
the real wages of low-skill workers -- a phenomenon that pure
technological theories have difficulty explaining -- because
technological change, even when it is skill biased, also should increase
the wages of low-skilled workers. With organizational change, though,
resources will get shifted away from low-skill workers and jobs that
paid them high wages will disappear.
Technology, Labor Market Institutions, and Social Norms
Emphasizing technology does not deny that changes in labor market
institutions have been important. The erosion in the real value of the
minimum wage and the declining role of unions undoubtedly have been
important for changes in U.S. inequality, especially at the bottom of
the wage distribution. (14) In addition, the late 1980s and the 1990s
have seen an explosion in CEO pay, which is difficult to explain with
changes in technology alone, and which suggests that there may have been
concurrent changes in social norms pertaining to inequality and
fairness. (15) Why have labor market institutions and social norms
related to inequality changed at about the same time that skill bias of
technology accelerated? This may be a coincidence, or the overall
changes in inequality may be the result of changing labor market
institutions and social norms, and less the product of technology. In my
view, a more fruitful approach is to acknowledge the independent effects
of both changes in technology and changes in labor marke t institutions
and social norms, and to link the two.
Recent research suggests how increases in inequality, for example
attributable to technological advances, might affect labor market
institutions and political preferences about redistribution. Similar
arguments also might be used to link social norms of inequality and
fairness to technology. Briefly, an increase in inequality might make it
harder for certain labor market arrangements, like unions, to survive.
Unions typically compress the wage structure, increasing the pay of less
skilled workers at the expense of more skilled workers. An increase in
the underlying inequality in the economy will make this more costly for
high-skill workers, who then will withdraw from the union sectors and
from unionized establishments. Similarly, an increase in inequality may
reduce the support that highly paid individuals give to the welfare
state or to redistributive government programs. These considerations
imply that technical change that increases the demand for skills can
have much amplified effects on inequality, beca use it also will change
labor market institutions and preferences towards redistribution. (16)
These forces might be amplified even more when technology also affects
social norms, for example, as it becomes acceptable for CEOs to be paid
much more than production workers.
Cross-Country Differences
While inequality increased in English-speaking economies, there was
much less of an increase in many continental European countries. To
date, there is no consensus for why there was such a divergence in
inequality trends among these relatively similar economies. Considering
endogenous technology choices may be useful here. Recent research
suggests that labor market institutions compressing the structure of
wages, as in many continental European economies, might induce firms to
introduce additional new technologies to be used with their unskilled
employees. Wage compression makes unskilled workers more expensive to
employ and, conditional on wishing to employ them, it increases the
value of raising their productivity. (17)
Therefore, labor market institutions, such as binding minimum
wages, union wage floors, and generous unemployment insurance programs,
may have an amplified role in reducing inequality. They will do so
directly and they will do so by encouraging technical change to be less
skill-biased.
Overall, however, our understanding of the reasons for
cross-country differences in inequality is weak, and much research is
necessary on this topic, as well as on the relationship between
technology and labor market institutions and social norms.
(1.) See L F. Katz and D. H. Autor, "Changes in the Wage
Structure and Earnings Inequality," in The Handbook of Labor
Economics, Vol. 3, O. Ashenfelter and D. Card, eds., Amsterdam:
Elsevier, 2000; or P. Gottschalk, "Inequality in Income, Growth and
Mobility: The Basic Facts," Journal of Economic Perspectives, 11
(1997) pp. 21-40, for recent surveys of the changes in the U.S. wage
structure; and P. Gottschalk and M. Joyce, "Cross-National
Differences in the Rise in Earnings Inequality: Market and Institutional
Factors," Review of Economics and Statistics, 80 (1998), pp.
489-502; R. B. Freeman and L. F. Katz "Introduction and
Summary," in R. B. Freeman and L. F. Katz, eds., Differences and
Changes in Wage Structures, Chicago: The University of Chicago Press,
1995, pp. 1-22, for cross-country trends.
(2.) See, for example, D. H. Autor, A. B. Krueger, and L. F. Katz,
"Computing Inequality: Have Computers Changed the Labor
Market?" NBER Working Paper No. 5956, March 1997, and in Quarterly
Journal of Economics, 113 (1998), pp. 1169-214; E. Berman, J. Bound, and
S. Machin, "Implications of Skill-Biased Technological Change:
International Evidence," NBER Working Paper No. 6166, September
1997, and in Quarterly Journal of Economics, 113 (1998), pp. 1245-80; F
Caselli, 'Technological Revolutions," American Economic
Review, 87 (1999), pp. 78-102; O. Galor and O. Maov, "Ability
Biased Technological Transition, Wage Inequality and Economic
Growth," Quarterly Journal of Economics, 115 (2000), pp. 469-98; J.
Greenwood and M. Yorukoglu, "1974," Carnegie-Rochester
Conference Series on Public Policy, 46 (1997), pp. 49-95; A. B. Krueger,
"How Computers Have Changed the Wage Structure: Evidence from
Microdata, 1984-1989," NBER Working Paper No. 3858, October 1991,
and in Quarterly Journal of Economics, 110 (1993), pp. 33- 60. See D.
Card and J. E. DiNardo, "Skill-Biased Technological Change and
Rising Wage Inequality: Some Problems and Puzzles," NBER Working
Paper No. 8769, February 2002, for the case against the role of
technology in the changes in the U.S. wage structure.
(3.) Quoted in H. J. Habakkuk, American and British Technology in
the 19th Century, London: Cambridge University Press, 1962.
(4.) See, for example, D. H. Autor, A. B. Krueger, and L. F. Katz,
"Computing Inequality: Have Computers Changed the Labor
Market?" And A. P. Bartel, C. Ichniowski, and K. L. Shaw, "New
Technology, Human Resource Practices and Skill Requirements,"
Carnegie-Mellon mimeo, 2002.
(5.) See D. Acemoglu, 'Technical Change, Inequality and the
Labor Market," NBER Working Paper No. 7800, July 2000, and in
Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. 40 (2002), pp. 7-72, for a
discussion of the case for and against an acceleration in skill bias.
(6.) See P. David, Technical Choice, Innovation and Economic
Growth: Essays on American and British Experience in the 19th Century,
London: Cambridge University Press, 1975; H. J. Habakkuk, American and
British Technology in the 19th Century; and especially J. Schmookler,
Invention and Economic Growth, Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press,
1966. For early historical discussions of endogenous technology, see P.
Aghion and P. Howitt, Endogenous Growth Theory, Cambridge, MA: MIT Press, 1998; G. Grossman and E. Helpman, Innovation and Growth in the
Global Economy, Cambridge, MA: MIT Press, 1991; and P. M. Romer,
"Endogenous Technological Change," Journal of Political
Economy, 87 (1990), pp. 71-102, for analyses of endogenous aggregate
technological change.
(7.) For the basic idea and models of directed technical change,
see D. Acemoglu, "Why Do New Technologies Complement Skills?
Directed Technical Change and Wage Inequality," Quarterly Journal
of Economics, 113 (1998), pp. 1055-90; and D. Acemoglu, "Directed
Technical Change," NBER Working Paper No. 8287, May 2001, and in
Review of Economic Studies, 69 (2002), pp. 781-810.
(8.) D. Acemoglu, "Why Do New Technologies Complement Skills?
Directed Technical Change and Wage Inequality."
(9.) See D. Acemoglu, "Technical Change, Inequality and the
Labor Market," and D. Acemoglu, "Directed Technical
Change," for more details on this argument.
(10.) See D. Acemoglu, "Patterns of Skill Premia," NBER
Working Paper No. 7018, March 1999, forthcoming in Review of Economic
Studies. See A. Wood, North-South Trade, Employment and Inequality:
Changing Fortunes in a Skill Driven World, Oxford: Clarendon Press,
1994, for the argument that trade with the LDCs may lead to defensive
innovations. For more recent models of trade affecting inequality by its
impact on technology, see M. Thoenig and T. Verdier, "Trade Induced
Technical Bias and Wage Inequalities: A Theory of Defensive
Innovations," Delta mimeo, 2002, forthcoming in American Economic
Review, and P. Epifani and G. Gancia, "The Skill Bias of World
Trade," MIT mimeo, 2002.
(11.) See D. H. Autor, F. Levy, and R. J. Murnane, "The Skill
Content of Recent Technological Change: An Empirical Exploration,"
NBER Working Paper No. 8337, June 2001; P. Cappelli and S. Wilk,
"Understanding Selection Processes: Organization Determinants and
Performance Outcomes," Wharton School mimeo, 1997; and R. J.
Murnane and F. Levy, Teaching the Basic New Skills, NY: The Free Press,
1996, for changes in the organization of production and the recruitment
process; and T. F. Bresnahan, E. Brynjolfsson, and L. M. Hitt,
"Information Technology, Workplace Organization, and the Demand for
Skilled Labor: Firm-level Evidence," NBER Working Paper No. 7136,
May 1999, and in Quarterly Journal of Economics, 117 (2002), pp. 339-76;
and E. Caroli and J. van Reenen, "Skill-Biased Organizational
Change: Evidence from a Panel of British and French
Establishments," Quarterly Journal of Economics, 116 (2002), pp.
1449-92, for the effect of firm organization on the demand for skills.
(12.) See D. Acemoglu, "Changes in Unemployment and Wage
Inequality: An Alternative Theory and Some Evidence," NBER Working
Paper No. 6658, July 1998, and in American Economic Review, 89 (1999),
pp. 1259-78; and also M. Kremer and E. Maskin, "Segregation by
Skill and the Rise in Inequality," Harvard mimeo, 1999.
(13.) See D. Acemoglu, "Changes in Unemployment and Wage
Inequality: An Alternative Theory and Some Evidence, "for a summary
of this evidence.
(14.) See D. Card, "The Effect of Unions on the Structure of
Wages: A Longitudinal analysis," Econometrica, 64 (1996), pp.
957-79; J. E. DiNardo, N. M. Fortin, and T. Lemieux, "Labor Market
Institutions, and the Distribution of Wages, 1973-1992: A Semiparametric
Approach," NBER Working Paper No. 5093, April 1995, and in
Econometrica, 64 (1995), pp. 1001-44; R. B. Freeman, "How Much Has
Deunionization Contributed to the Rise of Male Earnings
Inequality?" NBER Working Paper No. 3826, August 1991; and D. S.
Lee, "Wage Inequality in the U S. During the l980s: Rising
Dispersion or Falling Minimum Wage?" Quarterly Journal of
Economics, 114 (1999), pp. 941-1024, for the effect of the minimum wage
and deunionization on inequality.
(15.) See E. Saez and T. Piketty, "Income Inequality in the
United States: 1913-1998," NBER Working Paper No. 8467, September
2001, forthcoming in Quarterly Journal of Economics, on the rise in
inequality at the top of the U.S. income distribution, and a discussion
of changing social norms.
(16.) See D. Acemoglu, P. Aghion, and G. Violante, "Technical
Change, Deunionization, and Inequality," "Carnegie-Rochester
Conference Series On Public Policy, 2002, on the effect of inequality on
deunionization; and J. Hassler, S. Mora, K. Storlesseten, and F.
Zilibotti, "Survival of the Welfare State," Stockholm mimeo,
2002, forthcoming in American Economic Review; and R. Benabou,
"Human Capital, Technical Change, and the Welfare State,"
Princeton mimeo, 2002, forthcoming in European Economic Review.
(17.) D. Acemoglu, "Cross-country Inequality Trends,"
NBER Working Paper No. 8832, March 2002, forthcoming in Economic
Journal.
Daron Acemoglu *
* Acemoglu is a Research Associate in the NBER's Program on
Labor Studies and a professor of economics at MIT. His profile appears
later in this issue.