Local Corruption and the Global Economy.
Wei, Shang-Jin
Shang-Jin Wei [*]
Corruption, like cockroaches, has co-existed with human society for
a long time. Its role in economic development is controversial.
According to Samuel P. Huntington, the distinguished Harvard political
scientist "[i]n terms of economic growth, the only thing worse than
a society with a rigid, over-centralized, dishonest bureaucracy is one
with a rigid, overcentralized and honest bureaucracy." [1] On the
other hand, Lawrence Summers, the current Secretary of the U.S. Treasury and previously a Harvard economics professor and NBER Research
Associate, said otherwise: "If you look under most banking crises,
there's always a degree of fraud and abuse, and there's often
a large amount of criminal activity. Corruption threatens growth and
stability in many other ways as well: by discouraging business,
undermining legal notions of property rights and perpetuating vested
interests." [2]
In this report, I summarize some papers that explore different
consequences
of corruption, particularly its interaction with international
investment and finance. [3] The goal is to address a number of
questions: Does corruption on balance add "grease" or
"sand" to the wheels of commerce? How costly is corruption to
international investors relative to the effect of a tax? And, does
corruption increase the chance of a currency crisis?
Bribery in the Economies: Grease or Sand?
Mauro conducted the first empirical study of the relationship
between corruption and economic growth. [4] Within a standard growth
regression, he embedded a subjective measure of corruption across
countries devised by the "in-house experts" at Business
International (a consulting firm) and found that countries perceived to
be more corrupt tend to grow more slowly. A potential problem with
studies based on crosscountry regressions, though, is that many things
in a country are correlated, so it may be difficult to disentangle the
effects attributable solely to corruption. For example, corruption may
be highly correlated with the poor quality of public servants, a factor
that may retard growth whether corruption exists or not.
One way to get around this is to examine evidence at the firm
level. In what we believe is the first study of this kind, Daniel
Kaufmann and [5] use three worldwide firm surveys to examine the
"efficient grease hypothesis"; namely, that firms that pay
more bribes face less red tape and have better access to public funds and bank loans (hence reducing their cost of capital). In short, we
examine the hypothesis that bribery "greases the wheels" of
commerce. To guide our analysis, we first derive a simple model. As the
literature suggests, [6] the "bribery-as-grease" hypothesis
depends on the assumption that red tape is set exogenously. In our
model, we therefore let the bureaucrat who takes the bribes also set the
red tape. We distinguish between nominal bureaucratic harassment (for
example, statutory tax and tariff rates, or the waiting time for a
permit without bribery) and effective harassment (for example, actual
tax and tariff rates, or queuing time after the firm pays a bribe).
Furthermore, we assume that different firms have different outside
options because of their individual characteristics. This implies that
the maximum degree of harassment tolerated also would vary across firms.
For example, foreign firms would tolerate less harassment than domestic
ones because they could relocate more easily to a different country.
Overall, U.S. firms may tolerate the least harassment because, up until
very recently, the United States was the only major source country that
fined and criminalized its firms for paying bribes to foreign officials.
[7] Finally, firms dependent on more specialized inputs from the host
country (for example, oil or gold) are less able to resist bribery
demands from corrupt officials.
Not surprisingly, in equilibrium the bureaucrat would impose just
enough nominal harassment to obtain the maximum bribes without inducing
the firm to leave the country. As a consequence, nominal harassment and
bribes are correlated positively across firms. But this is not the end
of the story. In our model, for firms with weak outside options (and
hence more willing to tolerate higher bribe demands), nominal harassment
can be sufficiently high that in equilibrium across firms, effective
harassment and bribes are correlated positively. This is in strong
contrast to the efficient grease hypothesis.
The firm-level evidence that we examine comes from three sources:
the Global Competitiveness Report (GCR) survey in 1995 (for its 1996
Report) of 1,537 firms in 48 countries; the OCR survey in 1996 (for its
1997 Report) of 2,827 firms in 58 countries; and the World Bank survey
in 1996--in preparation for its 1997 World Development Report (WDR) --
of 3,866 firms in 73 countries. The GCR and the WDR surveys do not
sample the same countries, so they complement each other. Because
measures of firm-level bribes are inferred from the firms'
qualitative rating of corruption in a country, it is useful to
cross-validate using different surveys. We look at several proxies for
effective bureaucratic harassment: extent of regulatory burden, extent
of regulatory discretion, time spent by senior managers with government
officials discussing changes and interpretations of laws and regulation,
and cost of capital. We find that across firms, each of these measures
of effective red tape is correlated positively with bribery.
Because measures of harassment and bribery are all based on
subjective survey responses, the positive correlation could be
attributable to response biases that are correlated positively across
the survey questions. For example, assume that firms A and B face the
same demand for bribery and the same degree of harassment. However, the
manager in firm A likes to complain (in Yiddish, "kvetch")
more about government action, and thus may report more bribery and more
harassment. In this case, bribery and harassment appear positively
correlated across firms in the survey answers even though in reality
they shouldn't be. Our study develops a method to deal with what we
label this "kvetch effect." We construct a measure of possible
perception bias at the individual firm level based on the firm's
rating of the provision of public goods and services that arguably are
identical across firms (that is, a rating of overall infrastructure,
power supply, and mail delivery). When such measures of perception bias
are included in regressions of effective harassment on bribery, the
co-efficients on bribery generally become smaller (suggesting the
presence of the kvetch effect) but they remain positive and
statistically significant. These results are consistent with our simple
model and not with the efficient grease hypothesis.
Using a unique survey of Uganda firms that includes direct
information on the monetary value of bribes, Jakob Svensson [8] has
shown that bribery tends to rise with firms' profitability and to
decline with reversibility of investment. His findings also are
consistent with our model and our empirical findings. These results do
not suggest that, in a generally corrupt environment, an individual firm
necessarily can do better by paying fewer bribes. What they suggest is
that measures that increase all firms' ability to resist bribe
demands may not only reduce bribes but also reduce red tape. One example
of such a measure is the recent OECD (Organization for Economic
Cooperation and Development) Convention that criminalizes bribery in
international transactions.
How Taxing Is Corruption on International Investors?
Intuitively, we think that corruption deters foreign investment.
Using data on U.S. outward investment, James R. Hines, Jr. [9] has found
that U.S. direct investment in more corrupt countries grew more slowly
than in other countries during 1977-82. He interpreted this as the
effect of the U.S. Foreign Corrupt Practices Act (FCPA) of 1977.
However, it is possible that corruption deters investment from all
source countries. Corruption is a symptom that the government is
malfunctioning in many ways, which adds costs to foreign investment.
Also, even if bribes are necessary, then U.S. "ingenuity"
might allow firms to find substitutes for cash bribes. The Kaufmann-Wei
model discussed earlier suggests that FCPA sometimes could help U.S.
firms to face less red tape and bribe demands: U.S. firms credibly could
say that they cannot pay bribes. (On the other hand, the "speed
money" exception in the FCPA for bureaucrats' "routine
work" and the existence of substitutes for cash bribes might reduce
U.S. firms' abilities to commit and hence raise the bribe demands
that they face.) For all of these reasons, it is useful first to test if
major source countries invest less in more corrupt countries, and then
to examine whether U.S. firms behave differently from those of the other
source countries.
It is also useful to find out the magnitude of the effect of
corruption on foreign investment. Many developing countries eager to
attract foreign direct investment (FDI) have placed an emphasis on cheap
labor, tax incentives, and education, However, it is possible that
severe local corruption may deter more FDI than what cheap labor or
generous tax giveaways can bring in. Further, one useful ingredient in
an effective anticorruption reform is a public awareness campaign, for
which one needs an idea of the size of investment lost to corruption.
Using data on a matrix of bilateral FDI from 14 source countries to
41 host countries, I estimate the magnitude of the negative effect of
corruption relative to that of corporate income taxes. [10] The
corruption measures are based on perception indexes estimates by
Business International, International Country Risk Group, and
Transparency International. For example, on a one-to-ten scale, Mexico
is perceived to be more corrupt than Singapore by between six and seven
grades. I find that a worsening in the host government's corruption
level from what prevails in Singapore to what prevails in Mexico has the
same negative effect on inward FDI as raising the marginal tax rate by
42 percentage points. A different specification that includes zero
bilateral FDI produces an even bigger estimated effect: a worsening in
the host government's corruption level by the same extent (that is,
from the level of Singapore to that of Mexico) has the same negative
effect on inward FDI as raising the marginal tax rate by 50 perc entage
points. A possible explanation for the difference in the estimates is
that severe corruption is precisely the reason that small and faraway source countries don't bother to invest in these countries. In my
sample, while the U.S. firms appear to be more averse to corrupt host
countries than firms in the other major source countries, the difference
is not statistically significant. [11]
Is China Exceptional?
China appears to be a puzzle. On the one hand, there is rampant
corruption there. On the other hand, foreign investors appear to rush
into China, Newspapers and magazines use the phrase "China
fever" to describe the FDI rush or call China "the
world's biggest magnet for FDI." Is China truly an exception,
so corruption becomes less of a deterrent there?
Of course China is a large country; with a vast supply of cheap
labor, and has been growing faster than the world average. These are
reasons that Chinese inward FDI should be large in absolute terms.
Taking these factors into account, I find that as far as FDI from the
major source countries is concerned, there is no support for the notion
that China is a "superhost" of FDI or that corruption in China
has a smaller negative effect on FDI than corruption in other countries.
Indeed, there is some evidence that China may even be a substantial
underachiever as a host country for FDI from these countries. [12]
Does Corruption Make a Country More Vulnerable to Currency Crises?
The recent currency crises in East Asia, Russia, and Latin America have stimulated research on their causes. On the one hand, it is common
to hear the assertion that so-called crony capitalism is partly
responsible for the crises (though very little systematic evidence has
been presented to substantiate this). On the other hand, many economists
argue that shifts in the (fragile) self-fulfilling' expectations by
international creditors are the real reason for the crises. To these
researchers, the composition of a country's capital inflows is a
very important predictor of the propensity of a country running into a
currency crisis. The two most important indicators of that composition
are the share of FDI in the total inflow and the ratio of short-term
credit to foreign exchange reserves.
Crony capitalism and self-fulfilling expectations typically are
presented as rival explanations. My recent research suggests that there
may be a natural link between the two that has not been explored fully.
[13] In particular, corruption may increase the likelihood that a
country has a composition of capital flows (in particular, reduced
inward FDI and increased borrowing from foreign banks) that makes it
more vulnerable to shifts in international investors' sentiments
and expectations. A quick look at selected countries suggests that this
hypothesis is plausible. During the early 1990s, New Zealand and
Singapore had low levels of corruption and also substantially more
inward FDI than foreign bank borrowing. On the other hand, Uruguay and
Thailand were highly corrupt and also had substantially less FDI than
foreign bank borrowing. This is consistent with the hypothesis that
corruption and the composition of capital flows are connected.
Is there logic behind the nexus between local corruption and the
composition of capital inflows? Corruption is at least annoying to both
international banks and direct investors. However, corruption may be
particularly detrimental to FDI. Relative to international bank lending,
direct investment involves a higher sunk cost ex post and more repeated
interactions with host-country government officials. This ex post
vulnerability makes international direct investors more averse to
corruption. Furthermore, the current international financial
architecture is such that international bank credits stand a far better
chance to be bailed out than international direct investment. Both of
these reasons would affect the composition of the capital inflows into a
corrupt country away from FDI and towards bank credits, hence increasing
the likelihood of a future currency crisis.
Is there systematic evidence for this hypothesis beyond these
anecdotes? I collected data from the Bank for International Settlement
and the OECD on bilateral bank loans and bilateral FDI during 1994-6 for
all country pairs for which such data are available. Consistently across
several different specifications and three different measures of local
corruption, I find that more corrupt countries tend to have a lower
ratio of FDI to bank credit (after I control for several characteristics
of the source and host countries and the source-host pairs). One can
find similar, albeit weaker, evidence from the balance of payments (BOP)
data across countries (as opposed to the data on bilateral FDI and bank
loans). The evidence from the BOP data is weaker because it has more
noise and because some of the determinants of FDI and loans are
bilateral in nature, To sum up, my empirical results are consistent with
the hypothesis that corruption indeed raises the probability of a
currency crisis by altering the composition of a country's capital
inflows.
Conclusion
While the theories may be ambiguous, the empirical evidence seems
one-sided: corruption deters investment and economic growth.
Furthermore, the quantitative impact of corruption is far from trivial.
Its negative effect on inward FDI, for example, can easily offset a
generous tax giveaway typical in developing countries. Finally, the
evidence suggests that corruption also may raise the probability of a
currency crisis by altering the composition of a country's capital
inflows (and probably by worsening the balance sheets of domestic banks
and firms) though the evidence on this awaits future research.
(*.) Wei is an NBER Faculty Research Fellow in the Programs on
International Finance and Macroeconomics and International Trade and
Investment, an associate professor of public policy at Harvard
University's Kennedy School of Government, and an Advisor at the
World Bank. His "Profile" appears later in this issue.
(1.) S. P. Huntington, Political Order in Changing Societies, New
Haven: Yale University Press, 1968, pp. 386.
(2.) L. Summers, "Speech to the Summit of Eight," Denver
Colorado, June 10, 1997.
(3.) For broader surveys see P. Bardban, "Corruption and
Development: A Review of Issues" Journal of Economic Literature,
Vol. XXXV (September 1997), pp. 1320-46; and S.J. Wei, "Bribery in
the Economies: Grease or Sand?" in World Bank Research Observer,
forthcoming.
(4.) Mauro, Quarterly Journal of Economics, 1995.
(5.) D. Kaufmann and S. J. Wei, "Does 'Grease Money'
Speed up the Wheels of Commerce?" NBER Working Paper No. 7093,
April 1999.
(6.) P. Bardban, "Corruption and Development: A Review of
Issues," Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. XXXV (September
1997), pp. 1320-46; A. Shleifer and R. W. Vishny,
"Corruption," Quarterly Journal of Economics, 108 (August
1993), pp. 599-617.
(7.) This is a consequence of the U.S. Foreign Corrupt Practices
Act (FCPA) of 1977. However the FCPA allows firms to pay bribes to speed
up the routine work that the host countries' bureaucrats would have
done anyway. On February 1999, the OECD Convention on Combating Bribery
in International Transactions formally took effect, which now
criminalizes the firms from all OECD countries (and from nine other
non-OECD signatories of the convention) for paying bribes to foreign
government officials. As of the beginning of 2000, some signatory countries (for example, France and Italy) have not completed their
domestic ratification process.
(8.) J. Svensson, "Who Must Pay Bribes and How Much?"
unpublished World Bank Working Paper, 1999.
(9.) J. R. Hines, Jr., "Forbidden Payment: Foreign Bribery and
American Business After 1977," NBER Working Paper No. 5266,
September 1995.
(10.) S. J. Wei, "How Taxing Is Corruption on International
Investors?" NBER Working Paper No, 6030, May 1997, and Review of
Economics and Statistics, forthcoming. See also S.J. Wei, "Why Is
Corruption So Much More Taxing Than Taxes? Arbitrariness Kills,"
NBER Working Paper No. 6255, November 1997.
(11.) Using data from a survey of Uganda firms, R. Fisman and J.
Svensson (1999) find that bribery reduces the growth rate of the firms
by a three-to-one ratio versus the same amount of tax. This is a useful
extension to S.J. Wei, "Why Is Corruption So Much More Taxing Than
Taxes? Arbitrariness Kills," op.cit.
(12.) S. J. Wei, "Foreign Direct In vestment in China: Source
and Consequences," in Financial Deregulation and Integration in
East Asia, T. Ito and A. O. Krueger eds. Chicago: University of Chicago
Press, 1996; and "Can China and India Double Their Inward Foreign
Direct Investment?" Harvard University and the World Bank.
(13.) S. J. Wei, "Corruption, Composition of Capital Flows,
and Currency Crisis," forthcoming as an NBER Working Paper.