Strategic Asset Allocation: Portfolio Choice for Long-Term Investors.
Campbell, John Y.
John Y. Campbell [*]
Academic finance has had a remarkable impact on many financial
services. Yet, financial planners offering portfolio advice to long-term
investors have received curiously little guidance from academic
financial economists.
Mean-variance analysis, developed almost 50 years ago by Harry
Markowitz, [1] has provided a basic paradigm for portfolio choice. This
approach usefully emphasizes the ability of diversification to reduce
risk, but it ignores several critically important factors. Most notably,
the analysis is static; it assumes that investors care only about risks
to wealth one period ahead. However, many investors -- both individuals
and institutions, including charitable foundations or universities --
seek to finance a stream of consumption over a long lifetime. In
addition, mean-variance analysis treats financial wealth in isolation
from income. Long-term investors typically receive a stream of income
and use it, along with financial wealth, to support their consumption.
Robert Merton showed 30 years ago that the solution to a long-term
portfolio choice problem can be very different from the solution to a
short-term problem. [2] In particular, if investment opportunities vary
over time, then long-term investors care about shocks to investment
opportunities -- the productivity of wealth -- as well as shocks to
wealth itself. They may seek to hedge their exposures to wealth
productivity shocks, and this gives rise to intertemporal hedging
demands for financial assets. Michael Brennan, Eduardo Schwartz, and
Ronald Lagnado [3] have coined the phrase "strategic asset
allocation" to describe this farsighted response to time-varying
investment opportunities.
Unfortunately, Merton's intertemporal model is hard to solve.
Until recently, solutions to the model were available only in those
trivial cases in which it reduces to the static model. Therefore, the
Merton model has not become a usable empirical paradigm, has not
displaced the Markowitz model, and has had minimal influence on
financial planners and their clients. This situation has begun to change
recently as a result of advances in both analytical and numerical
methods. A new empirical paradigm is emerging. Interestingly, this
paradigm both supports and qualifies traditional rules of thumb used by
financial planners. It also sheds new light on important issues of
public policy such as the design of the Social Security system.
Who Should Buy Long-Term Bonds?
An important difficulty with mean-variance analysis becomes clear
when one considers the classic problem of allocating a portfolio among
three broad asset classes: stocks, bonds, and money market funds
("cash"). One of the most famous results in mean-variance
analysis is James Tobin's mutual fund theorem of portfolio choice,
according to which all investors should combine cash with a single
portfolio or "mutual fund" of risky assets. [4]
The mutual fund theorem directs all investors, conservative or
aggressive, to hold the same portfolio of stocks and bonds, mixing the
portfolio with more or less cash depending on the investor's
aversion to risk. Thus, if an aggressive investor holds 80 percent
stocks and 20 percent bonds, a conservative investor should maintain the
same 4:1 ratio of stocks to bonds at a lower scale, perhaps 40 percent
equities and 10 percent bonds, with 50 percent of the portfolio in cash.
This is quite different from the way conservative investors actually
behave and are advised to behave by financial planners. In practice,
conservative investors favor bonds relative to equities so that a
conservative portfolio might consist of 40 percent equities, 40 percent
bonds, and 20 percent cash. Investors and financial planners do not seem
to take mean-variance analysis seriously.
Furthermore, it is hard to explain -- using mean-variance analysis
-- why any investors hold large positions in bond. Mean-variance
analysis treats cash as the riskless asset, and treats bonds merely as
another risky asset like stocks. Bonds are valued only for their
potential contribution to the short-run excess return, relative to risk,
of a diversified risky portfolio. This view tends to relegate bonds to a
minor supporting role in the recommended portfolio, since excess bond
returns historically have been fairly low and bond returns have been
highly variable in the short run. From 1970-96, for example, the average
excess return on long-term U.S. Treasury bonds over three-month Treasury
bills was less than 2 percent, while the standard deviation of this
return was almost 11 percent. The ratio of average excess return to
standard deviation (the short-term reward-risk ratio or "Sharpe
ratio") for bonds was only 0.18. Over the same period, the U.S.
equity market had an average excess return of almost 6 perce nt and a
standard deviation of 17 percent, implying a Sharpe ratio that was
almost twice as high at 0.34. The comparison looks even less favorable
for bonds if one studies the early postwar period of slowly rising
inflation or the very recent period of spectacular stock returns.
A long-horizon analysis treats bonds very differently and assigns
them a much more important role in the optimal portfolio. For long-term
investors, money market investments are not riskless because they must
be rolled over at uncertain future interest rates. Just as borrowers
have come to appreciate that short-term debt carries a risk of having to
refinance at high rates during a financial crisis, so long-term
investors must appreciate that short-term investments carry the risk of
having to reinvest at low real rates in the future. For long-term
investors, an inflation-indexed long-term bond is actually less risky
than cash. Such a bond does not have a stable market value in the short
term, but it delivers a predictable stream of real income and thus
supports a stable standard of living in the long term.
Luis M. Viceira and I [5] recently completed an empirical analysis
of optimal portfolio choice for long-term investors. Using a statistical
model of nominal interest rates, real interest rates, inflation, and
stock prices, we calculated optimal portfolios for long-lived investors
with varying attitudes toward risk. We concluded that aggressive
investors should hold portfolios with almost 100 percent equity, but
that more conservative investors should shift largely into bonds,
putting a modest allocation into cash. (A larger cash position can be
justified as a contingency reserve to meet unexpected consumption needs,
but we do not attempt to model this sort of cash demand.)
The conventional wisdom of financial planners holds up well under
this analysis: buyers of long-term bonds should be conservative
long-term investors, or such institutions as pension funds acting on
their behalf. There is one important qualification, however. Our
analysis looks at data from 1983--96, during which time monetary policy
successfully contained inflation. If we consider historical data from
the entire postwar period of 1952-96, then we estimate a much larger
risk of inflation, which could erode the real value of long-term nominal
bonds. When there is a significant risk of inflation, nominal bonds are
far less appealing because they are not good substitutes for
inflation-indexed bonds and are not in any sense riskless for long-term
investors. Conservative long-term investors who are concerned about the
possible return of inflation should hold U.S. Treasury inflation-indexed
bonds instead.
Is the Stock Market Safer for Long-Term Investors?
Traditionally, equities have been regarded as risky assets. They
may be attractive because of their high average returns, but these
returns represent compensation for risk; thus equities should be treated
with caution by all but the most aggressive investors. However, in
recent years it has become commonplace to argue that equities are
actually relatively safe assets for certain investors to hold for the
long term. An extreme version of this revisionist view is promoted by
James Glassman and Kevin Hassett, [6] who argue that stocks are actually
just as safe as bonds or Treasury bills, and that investors will bid
stock prices up to unprecedented levels as they come to realize this.
The revisionist view that stocks are safe assets is not based on
any reduction in their short-term volatility. The volatility of market
index returns has moved up and down -- most recently up, after an
unusually quiet period in the mid-1990s -- but it shows no downward
trend. Rather, the revisionist view is based on evidence that stock
returns are less volatile, relative to bond or bill returns, when they
are measured over long holding periods.
This sort of evidence has been presented by Jeremy Siegel, [7] who
uses it to promote an aggressive strategy of buying and holding
equities. Looking at U.S. data over a period of almost 200 years
(1802-1997), Siegel compares the range of variation of real returns on
stocks, long-term bonds, and Treasury bills, In their best single year,
stocks delivered a real return of 67 percent, while in their worst
single year they returned negative 39 percent, for a range of 106
percent. The one-year range for bonds is far smaller at 57 percent, and
the one-year range for Treasury bills is still smaller at 40 percent. A
similar pattern emerges if one compares standard deviations of annual
real returns as measures of risk. In the 1802-1997 data, the standard
deviation of the annual return is 18 percent for stocks, 9 percent for
bonds, and 6 percent for bills. For an investor with a one-year holding
period, stocks appear to be considerably riskier than fixed-income
investments.
The picture is very different for long holding periods of a decade
or more. The average annualized real stock return over the best decade
between 1802 and 1997 was 17 percent, while the average return over the
worst decade was negative 4 percent, for a range of 21 percent. The
ranges for bonds and bills over a decade are 18 percent and 17 percent,
respectively. Over 20-year periods, the ranges for all three assets are
almost identical at 12 percent, and over 30-year periods the range is
actually smaller for stocks at 8 percent than it is for bonds and bills
at 9 percent. Standard deviations of real returns follow the same
pattern when measured over long holding periods; over 20-year periods
they are roughly equal, and over 30-year periods they are lower for
stocks than for bonds or bills. It would appear that stocks are no
riskier than bonds and bills for long-term investors who can hold their
positions for at least a decade. Similar patterns are visible in some
international markets, although reliable long- term data are harder to
come by overseas. [8]
These findings create a puzzle. How can short-term stock market
risk largely disappear at long horizons? Where does the risk go? The
revisionists devote little attention to this question, but it turns out
that the answer is important and it undermines the revisionist case for
aggressive investment in equities.
Mathematically, there can be a difference between the short-term
risk and the long-term risk of an asset only if its expected return varies over time. With constant expected returns, the annualized
standard deviation over a long holding period (N years) is the standard
deviation over one year divided by the square root of N. Thus, with
constant expected returns the annualized standard deviations of all
assets would shrink along with the square root of the holding period,
but they would shrink together; we would not see the standard deviation
of stock returns shrinking more rapidly than the standard deviations of
bond and bill returns. Evidence for reduced relative risk of stocks at
long horizons is therefore indirect evidence for predictable variation
in stock returns.
The type of return variation that reduces long-term risk is known
as mean-reversion. If unusually good stock returns today lower the
expectation of returns in the future, then bull markets tend to be
followed by corrections and bear markets tend to be followed by
recoveries; stock prices revert toward a long-run average or mean, and
stocks are said to be mean-reverting. Under these circumstances, stock
market risk declines more rapidly with the investment horizon than the
square-root rule would imply.
Siegel's risk measurements provide indirect evidence for
mean-reversion, but more direct evidence is also available. One approach
is to look at a smoothed P/E ratio for the S&P 500 Index. The
smoothed PIE ratio divides current price by an average of earnings over
the past decade, in order to eliminate the effects of temporary earnings
declines that occur in recessions. There is a very strong negative
relationship between smoothed P/E and subsequent long-term growth in
real stock prices; years with high initial P/E ratios -- such as 1929 or
1966 -- tend to have poor average returns over the next decade, while
years with low initial P/E ratios, such as 1918 or 1982, tend to have
high average returns over the next decade. [9]
In joint work with Viceira, I have calculated the stock holdings
that are optimal for investors with constant risk aversion when stocks
are mean-reverting. It turns out that for conservative long-term
investors, the optimal policy involves a higher allocation to stocks on
average, as recommended by Siegel, but the allocation depends on past
returns. At a time like the present, when past returns have been high
and mean-reversion implies low future returns, the allocation may be no
higher -- it may even be lower -- than would be implied by a traditional
short-term analysis assuming a constant equity premium. [10]
Many investors today are attracted to the stock market by the
prospect of high returns combined with low long-term risk. These
investors are trying to have their cake and eat it too. If expected
stock returns are constant over time, then one can hope to earn high
stock returns in the future similar to the high returns of the past. But
in such a case, stocks are much riskier than bonds in the long term,
just as they are in the short term. If stocks mean-revert instead, then
they are relatively safe assets for long-term investors; but in that
case, future returns are likely to be meager, because mean-reversion
unwinds the spectacular stock market run-up of the past decade.
Investing for Retirement
Even if the stock market does not mean-revert, it may be
appropriate for young investors to hold riskier portfolios than older
investors because the young typically rely more on income and less on
financial wealth to support their consumption. Consider an investor who
knows her income in advance with perfect certainty and can borrow and
lend freely at the riskless interest rate. For this investor, the
present value of labor income, discounted at the riskless rate, is
equivalent to a position in a riskless asset. Her financial portfolio
thus should be tilted toward risky assets to offset this position. [11]
Risk in labor income will reduce the magnitude of this tilt toward risky
assets, but not reverse it if there is no correlation between labor
income risk and investment risk. [12] Only investors who have volatile
labor income that is highly correlated with stock returns, such as
investment bankers and executives who are compensated largely through
executive stock options, should tilt their portfolios toward safe
assets.
A typical investor starts her working life with a small income and
very little financial wealth. In early adulthood, income tends to grow
fairly rapidly, but people accumulate little wealth since they
anticipate higher income in the future and use their current income to
support current consumption. In early middle age, asset holdings begin
to increase rapidly as investors save for retirement, while current
labor income flattens out, and the approach of retirement reduces the
discounted value of future labor income. Thus, the discounted value of
future income, relative to financial wealth, follows a hump shape over
the life cycle. It rises at the very start of a person's career,
then peaks fairly early, and declines as retirement approaches. This
pattern implies that fairly young investors should have the strongest
desire to take stock market risk.
Joao F. Cocco, Francisco J. Gomes, Pascal J. Maenhout, and I [13]
have explored the magnitude of these effects in a life-cycle model
calibrated to U.S. data on individual income and aggregate asset
returns. We model income as having a deterministic component with a hump
shape over working life, and a random component with both permanent and
temporary shocks. Permanent shocks to income can be correlated with
stock returns. We use household data from the Panel Study of Income
Dynamics to estimate the income process for households with different
levels of education (college, high school, or no high school diploma)
and different employment status (regular employment or self-employment,
sector of employment). We find that households with higher education levels experience smaller temporary income shocks but larger permanent
shocks: career risk as opposed to layoff risk. Most household income
shocks are correlated only weakly with stock returns, even if we allow
for a lag in the effect of the stock market on income . Thus, we
estimate that young households should hold more stocks than older
households.
In practice, households choose their portfolios subject to various
types of constraints. It is extremely difficult for most households to
borrow against their future labor income and it is also difficult for
most households to borrow to finance a leveraged position in the stock
market. George M. Constantinides, John B. Donaldson, and Rajnish Mehra [14] recently have argued that this fact helps to explain the large
historical returns to stocks: young adults are the natural holders of
stocks, but they are constrained from taking as much equity risk as they
would like. This forces middle-aged investors to take up the slack,
which they do only at depressed stock prices that imply high average
stock returns.
If financial constraints indeed restrict the investment policies of
many households, then government policy may be able to help or hurt
households by affecting the severity of the constraints. Cocco, Gomes,
Maenhout, and I use our model to evaluate proposals to reform Social
Security by investing Social Security funds in the stock market. Such
proposals increase the equity exposure of constrained young households
and may also allow for a reduction in payroll tax rates, thus increasing
the consumption of constrained young households. If we assume that
households save optimally given the constraints they face, then reform
will benefit households through both channels. If we assume instead that
households do not save adequately on their own, then increased equity
exposure will still be beneficial, but it would be a mistake to reduce
payroll taxes.
Challenges for Future Research
I have described several factors that may lead long-term investors
to choose different portfolio strategies from short-term investors,
including changing real interest rates, mean-reversion in stock returns,
and labor income. [15] Other factors also can be important, notably
taxation and uncertainty about the processes driving interest rates,
stock returns, and income. These factors have not yet been integrated in
a single empirically usable model, but the construction of such a model
is now a realistic ambition. This offers the exciting prospect that
financial economists will be able at last to offer relevant and
scientifically grounded investment advice.
(*.)John Y Campbell is a Research Associate in the NBER'S
Program on Asset Pricing and a professor of economics at Harvard
University.
(1.) H. Markowitz, "Portfolio Selection," Journal of
Finance, 7(1952), pp. 77-91.
(2.) R. Merton, "Lifetime Portfolio Selection under
Uncertainty. The Continuous Time Case," Review of Economics and
Statistics, 51 (1969), pp. 247-57; "Optimum Consumption and
Portfolio Rules in a Continuous-Time Model," Journal of Economic
Theory, 3 (1971), pp. 373-413; "An Intertemporal Capital Asset
Pricing Model," Econometrica, 41 (1973), pp. 86-87.
(3.) M. Brennan, E. Schwartz, and R. Lagnado, "Strategic Asset
Allocation," Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control, 21 (1997),
pp. 1377-1403.
(4.) J. Tobin, "Liquidity Preference as Behavior Towards
Risk," Review of Economic Studies, 25 (1958), pp. 68-85.
(5.) J. Y. Campbell and L. M. Viceira, "Who Should Buy
Long-Term Bonds?," NBER Working Paper No. 6801, November 1998;
forthcoming in American Economic Review.
(6.) J. Glassman and K. Hassett, Dow 36,000, New York: Times Books,
1999.
(7.) J. Siegel, Stocks for the Long Run, 2nd ed., New York.
McGraw-Hill, 1998.
(8.) Comparative international evidence on stock and bond market
performance is reported in J. Y Campbell, "Asset Prices,
Consumption, and the Business Cycle," Ch. 19 in Handbook of
Macroeconomics Vol. 1, J. Taylor and M. Woodford, eds., Amsterdam:
North-Holland, 1999.
(9.) J. Y Campbell and R. Shiller, "Valuation Ratios and the
Long-Run Stock Market Outlook," Journal of Portfolio Management
(Winter 1998), pp. 11-26. Earlier work on mean-reversion includes E.
Fama and K French, "Permanent and Temporary Components of Stock
Prices," Journal of Political Economy, 96(1988), pp. 246-73 and
"Dividend Yields and Expected Stock Returns," Journal of
Financial Economics, 22 (1988), pp. 3-27; J. Campbell and R. Shiller,
Stock Prices, Earnings, and Expected Dividends," Journal of
Finance, 43 (1988), pp. 661- 76; J. Poterba and L. Summers,
"Mean-Reversion in Stock Returns: Evidence and Implications,"
Journal of Financial Economics, 22 (1988),pp. 27-60.
(10.) J. Y. Campbell and L. M. Viceira, "Consumption and
Portfolio Decisions When Expected Returns Are Time Varying,"
Quarterly Journal of Economics (May 1999), pp. 433-95. This paper
assumes that interest rates are constant. Similar results are reported
in J. Y. Campbell, Y. L. Chan, and L. At. Viceira, "A Multivariate Model of Strategic Asset Allocation," a forthcoming NBER Working
Paper for a model with time-varying interest rates. An obvious concern
about the portfolio rules developed in these papers is that they require
all investors to buy or sell stocks simultaneously, which is not
possible in general equilibrium. One possible resolution of this problem
is that most investors have attitudes toward risk that are not stable
but shift over time, as proposed by J. Y. Campbell and J. H. Cocbrane,
"Habit Formation: A Consumption-Based Explanation of Aggregate
Stock Market Behavior," Journal of Political Economy, 107 (1999),
pp. 205-51.
(11.) Z. Bodie, R. Merton, and W. Samuelson, "Labor Supply
Flexibility and Portfolio Choice in a Life-Cycle Model," Journal of
Economic Dynamics and Control, 16 (1991), pp. 427-49. These authors
emphasize that the tilt toward risky financial investments is
strengthened if investors are able to adjust their labor supply, work
harder or delay retirement in response to poor returns on risky assets.
(12.) L. M. Viceira, "Optimal Portfolio Choice for
Long-Horizon Investors with Nontradable Labor Income," NBER Working
Paper No. 7409, October 1999, forthcoming in the journal of Finance.
(13.) J. Y. Campbell, J. F Cocco, F. J. Gomes, and P. J. Maenhout,
"Investing Retirement Wealth: A Life-Cycle Model," NBER
Working Paper No. 7029, March 1999; forthcoming in Risk Aspects of
Investment-Based Social Security Reform, J. Y. Campbell and At.
Feldstein, eds., from University of Chicago Press. This paper relies
heavily on the specification developed in J. F Cocco, F. J. Gomes, and
P. J. Maenhout, "Consumption and Portfolio Choice over the Life
Cycle," unpublished paper Harvard University, 1998.
(14.) G. M. Constantinides, J. B. Donaldson, and R. Mehra,
"junior Can't Borrow: A New Perspective on the Equity Premium
Puzzle," NBER Working Paper No. 6617, June 1998.
(15.) Luis M. Viceira and I are currently writing a book that
reviews these factors in greater detail, Strategic Asset Allocation:
Portfolio Choice for Long-Term Investors, forthcoming from Oxford
University Press.