Understanding aggregate fluctuations: the importance of building from microeconomic evidence.
Haltiwanger, John C.
In recent research using longitudinal establishment-level data, a
pervasive finding is that idiosyncratic factors dominate the
distribution of growth rates of output, employment, investment, and
productivity across establishments. Seemingly similar plants within the
same industry exhibit behave quite differently in terms of real activity
at cyclical and longer-run frequencies. Even in the fastest-growing
industries, a significant fraction of establishments decline
substantially; similarly, a large fraction of establishments in the
slowest-growing industries grow dramatically. During severe recessions
virtually all industries decline, but within each industry a substantial
fraction of establishments grow. Likewise, during robust recoveries, a
substantial fraction of establishments contract. Simply put, the
underlying gross microeconomic changes in activity dwarf the net changes
that we observe in published aggregates.
The tremendous observed within-sector heterogeneity raises a
variety of questions for our understanding and measurement of key macro
aggregates. Much of macroeconomic research and our measurement of
aggregates is predicated on the view that building macro aggregates from
industry-level data is sufficient for understanding the behavior of the
macro economy. The implicit argument is that, at least at the detailed
industry level, the assumption of a representative firm or establishment
is reasonable.
The finding of tremendous within-industry heterogeneity is not by
itself sufficient to justify abandoning this useful assumption. There is
undoubtedly considerable canceling out of the impact of idiosyncratic
shocks (for example, taste, cost, and technology) that underlie the
heterogeneous fortunes across individual producers. Evidence from recent
establishment-level studies of employment, investment, and productivity
growth, however, suggests that this canceling out is far from complete.
It is becoming increasingly apparent that changes in the key macro
aggregates at cyclical and secular frequencies are best understood by
tracking the evolution of the cross-sectional distribution of activity
and changes at the micro level.
A number of different factors are potentially important in this
context. The observed heterogeneity in output, employment, and
investment growth rates within sectors implies a large, continuous pace
of reallocation of real activity across production sites. Such
reallocation inherently involves substantial frictions. One obvious and
important friction is that it is time- and resource-consuming for
workers (and for other inputs) to reallocate across production sites.
High- and low-frequency changes in key macro aggregates are likely
associated with the interaction of these frictions and the pace of
reallocation. The level of unemployment, as well as the growth rate of
aggregate measures of real activity (for example, real output or
productivity), will reflect the efficiency of the economy in
accommodating the pace of reallocation. Changes in institutions,
regulation, the pace of technological change, and the sectoral mix of
activity all may alter the intensity of reallocative activity and the
economy's ability to accommodate the reallocation.
Relatedly, it is important to consider the nature of the adjustment
costs at individual production sites in changing the scale and scope of
activity. Accumulating evidence of lumpy microeconomic adjustment of
inputs such as employment and capital suggests the presence of
nonconvexities in micro-level adjustment costs, or, at a minimum, it
implies highly nonlinear adjustment at the micro level. The combination
of nonlinear micro adjustment with micro heterogeneity has important
implications for aggregate fluctuations. One key implication is
time-varying elasticities of aggregates with respect to aggregate
shocks. Roughly speaking, time-varying elasticities arise in this
context because the impact of an aggregate shock depends on the
distribution of individual producers' relative positions to their
adjustment thresholds. From this perspective, characterizing aggregate
fluctuations requires tracking how the distribution of shocks and
adjustments has evolved.
Job Creation and Destruction
Much of the recent empirical analysis documenting and analyzing the
connection between micro heterogeneity and aggregate fluctuations has
focused on employment dynamics. My recent work, much of it with Steven
J. Davis, focuses on job creation and destruction.(1) Job creation is
defined as the sum of employment gains at expanding and new
establishments. Job destruction is defined as the sum of employment
losses at contracting and closing establishments. In manufacturing (the
sector with the most readily available establishment-level data for the
longest period), annual job creation and destruction rates are large in
absolute terms. In a typical year, roughly one in ten manufacturing jobs
is created and one in ten jobs is destroyed. In nonmanufacturing (with
spottier information based on tabulations from selected states for
relatively short sample periods), job creation and job destruction rates
are slightly higher on average.
The large pace of implied job reallocation (measured as the sum of
job creation and job destruction) in both manufacturing and
nonmanufacturing sectors highlights the remarkable fluidity in the
distribution of job opportunities across locations in the U.S. economy.
Much of this fluidity reflects shifts within narrowly defined sectors,
rather than between sectors. For example, only 13 percent of job
reallocation in manufacturing reflects shifts of employment
opportunities between four-digit sectors.
One important issue for the relevance of these statistics for
aggregate fluctuations is the nature of time-series variation in the
pace of job reallocation. In U.S. manufacturing, the pace of job
reallocation varies systematically throughout the cycle at annual and
quarterly frequencies. During downturns, job destruction rises sharply
and job creation falls relatively mildly. Given the observed magnitude
and time-series variation of job reallocation, even modest frictions are
likely to yield important implications for aggregate fluctuations. In
recent years, some economists have begun developing theories to explain
the magnitude and cyclical behavior of job (and worker) flows and the
connection to aggregate fluctuations.(2) Two types of theories have
received the most attention. One treats fluctuations over time in the
intensity of allocative shocks as an important driving force behind
aggregate fluctuations. The other maintains that aggregate shocks are
the primary driving forces underlying business cycles, but that the
propagation of aggregate shocks involves intertemporal substitution effects changing the incentives for the timing of reallocation. Of
course, there is an important debate about the direction of causality and thus the relative contribution of aggregate and allocative
disturbances to aggregate fluctuations.(3) Regardless of the direction
of causality, though, the relevant point is that understanding aggregate
fluctuations requires tracking how the distribution of microeconomic
changes has evolved.
Nonlinear Micro Adjustment
Thus far I have focused on the aggregate consequences generated by
the resource- and time-consuming nature of reallocation. A closely
related issue is that the adjustment at the individual producer level
may be nonlinear. For example, about two-thirds of annual job creation
and destruction are accounted for by establishments with growth rates
above 25 percent in absolute magnitude. Of this group, plant start-ups
account for 12 percent of annual job creation, while plant shutdowns
account for about 23 percent of annual job destruction. Thus the
distribution of establishment-level employment changes exhibits both
considerable heterogeneity and fat tails. The lumpy changes at the micro
level in combination with the heterogeneity in turn have consequences
beyond those discussed earlier.
Building on the literature about the aggregation of (S,s) models, a
useful means of organizing micro data to characterize the interaction of
nonlinear micro adjustment and heterogeneity is the adjustment hazard
framework. My work with Ricardo J. Caballero and Eduardo M. Engel has
used this approach to characterize the micro and macro employment
dynamics.(4) Using a measure of the gap between desired and actual
employment at the micro level, the adjustment hazard measures the
relationship between the size of this gap and the fraction of it that is
closed by the establishment. The standard convex adjustment cost model
implies a constant (flat) hazard, but our findings using micro data
reveal a highly nonlinear hazard, with businesses with large absolute
gaps closing a disproportionately high fraction of the gap. The
combination of a nonlinear micro hazard and considerable micro
heterogeneity in the cross-sectional distribution of the gaps has
important implications for aggregate adjustment. Time-varying aggregate
elasticities of aggregate employment emerge as the impact of an
aggregate shock depends on the underlying cross-sectional distribution
at the time of the shock and the endogenous dynamics of the
cross-sectional distribution interacting with the nonlinear micro
adjustment. Our findings indicate that the marginal responsiveness for
employment varies as much as 70 percent over time. Furthermore, the
impact of the time-varying marginal response is especially large during
recessions; for example, the decline in the 1974-5 recession was 59
percent larger than it would have been in the absence of nonlinear
adjustment.
Investment Dynamics
Nonlinearities in the adjustment dynamics of capital, driven by
irreversibilities and related nonconvexities in the adjustment costs of
capital, have analogous implications for aggregate investment dynamics.
Several recent studies of establishment-level investment dynamics
support the view that micro investment dynamics exhibit lumpy
adjustment. Plant-level investment is dominated by large-scale
investment episodes. Denoting these large-scale investment episodes as
spikes, Russell Cooper, Laura Power, and I show that the probability of
an investment spike is increasing in the time since the previous spike,
lending additional support to the view of a microeconomic environment
with nonconvexities in the adjustment technology,s Using the adjustment
hazard approach in this context, my work with Caballero and Engel shows
a highly nonlinear relationship between investment and fundamentals.(6)
For plants with positive excess capital, the adjustment hazard is quite
flat and close to zero, which is consistent with irreversibilities in
investment. In contrast, plants with large shortages of capital adjust
proportionally more than do plants with small shortages of capital.
As with employment dynamics, the nonlinear adjustment hazard yields
time-varying elasticities of aggregate investment with respect to
aggregate shocks. For investment, the marginal responsiveness is highly
procyclical and varies by as much as 70 percent. The time-varying
elasticities suggest a possible explanation for the often-puzzling
response of aggregate investment to cost of capital and other shocks.
The basic idea is that the empirical aggregate investment literature has
difficulty in quantifying the relationship between aggregate investment
and the cost of capital because of the failure to incorporate the
time-varying responsiveness generated by the interaction of nonlinear
micro adjustment and heterogeneity.
Productivity Dynamics
Several of the findings discussed earlier raise a variety of
conceptual and measurement questions regarding our understanding of
aggregate productivity growth. Several key, related findings are of
interest. First, there is large-scale, ongoing reallocation of outputs
and inputs across individual producers. Second, the pace of this
reallocation varies over time (both secularly and cyclically) and across
sectors. Third, much of this reallocation reflects within-sector rather
than between-sector reallocation. In addition, recent evidence shows
large differentials in the levels and rates of productivity growth
across establishments within the same sector. The rapid pace of output
and input reallocation along with differences in productivity levels and
growth rates are necessary for the pace of reallocation to play an
important role in aggregate (that is, industry) productivity growth. My
recent work with Lucia Foster and C. J. Krizan suggests that
reallocation plays a significant role in the changes in productivity
growth at the industry level.(7) While measurement-error problems cloud
the results somewhat, two aspects of the results clearly point in this
direction. First, our results show a large contribution from the
replacement of less productive exiting plants with more productive
entering plants when productivity changes are measured over five- or
ten-year horizons. Second, the contribution of net entry is
disproportionate - that is, the contribution of net entry to
productivity growth exceeds that which would be predicted by simply
examining the share of activity accounted for by entering and exiting
plants. These results are particularly striking for selected
service-sector industries that we investigate. There is tremendous
reallocation of activity across service establishments, with much of
this reallocation generated by entry and exit. The productivity growth
in the selected service industries we examine is dominated by entry and
exit effects. For example, the primary source of productivity growth
between 1987 and 1992 for the automobile repair shop industry is
accounted for by the exit of very low productivity plants.
1 For an overview of this work, see S. J. Davis and J. C.
Haltiwanger, "Gross Job Flows," in Handbook of Labor
Economics, O. Ashenfelter and D. Card, eds. Amsterdam: North Holland,
forthcoming; and S. J. Davis, J. C. Haltiwanger, and S. Schuh, Job
Creation and Destruction, Cambridge: MIT Press, 1996.
2 See, for example, R. J. Caballero and M. Hammour, "On the
Timing and Efficiency of Creative Destruction," NBER Working Paper
No. 4768, June 1994; published in Quarterly Journal of Economics, 111
(August 1996), pp. 805-52; and D. Mortensen and C. Pissarides, "New
Developments in Models of Search in the Labor Market," in Handbook
of Labor Economics, O. Ashenfelter and D. Card, eds. Amsterdam: North
Holland, forthcoming.
3 See, for example, S. J. Davis and J. C. Haltiwanger,
"Driving Forces and Employment Fluctuations: New Evidence and
Alternative Explanations," NBER Working Paper No. 5775, September
1996.
4 R. J. Caballero, E. M. Engel, and J. C. Haltiwanger,
"Aggregate Employment Dynamics: Building from Microeconomic
Evidence," NBER Working Paper No. 5042, February 1995; published in
American Economic Review, 87 (March 1997), pp. 115-37.
5 R. Cooper, J. C. Haltiwanger, and L. Power, "Machine
Replacement and the Business Cycle: Lumps and Bumps," NBER Working
Paper No. 5260, September 1995; forthcoming in American Economic Review.
6 R. J. Caballero, E. M. Engel, and J. C. Haltiwanger,
"Plant-Level Adjustment and Aggregate Investment Dynamics,"
Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, 2 (1995), pp. 1-39.
7 L. Foster, J. C. Haltiwanger, and C. J. Krizan, "Aggregate
Productivity Growth: Lessons from Microeconomic Evidence," NBER
Working Paper No. 6803, November 1998.
John C. Haltiwanger is an NBER Research Associate in the Programs
on Economic Fluctuations and Growth and Productivity and a Professor of
Economics at the University of Maryland. His "Profile" appears
later in this issue.