The economics of school reform.
Hoxby, Caroline M.
Structural reforms for elementary and secondary (K-12) schools are
being seriously debated these days. The majority of U.S. states have now
enacted at least some form of choice among public schools, for example a
charter school program, open enrollment among school districts, or
choice within the district. While state legislatures have been much less
inclined to enact programs such as vouchers and tax incentives that
increase parents' ability to choose private schools, private donors
particularly like voucher programs.(1)
In addition, there have been major changes in the structure of public
school finance in America over the last 30 years. Increasingly, school
finance has been centralized at the state level and has been affected
strongly by "school finance equalization" (a term that
encompasses a variety of methods for redistributing monies from
"property-rich" to "property-poor" school
districts).(2)
It is clear why Americans are so interested in structural school
reform for K-12 education. On a per-pupil basis, American public
education is the most expensive system in the world. Yet, American K-12
students perform only moderately well on international tests of
mathematics, science, and language arts achievement. The per-pupil
expense for K-12 education has grown by nearly 80 percent (after
adjusting for inflation) since 1970, yet student achievement has been
almost fiat over the period.(3) Since 1970, most states' school
finance systems have been revised in order to target more funds to
disadvantaged students. As a result, differences in funding have
narrowed, but there has been very little narrowing of the differences in
the outcomes of students from advantaged and disadvantaged
backgrounds.(4)
There are three reasons why economics is valuable for the analysis of
school reform. First, econometric methods and evaluation techniques
developed over the last decade (especially in labor and public
economics) are very useful for analyzing school reforms. Second, many of
the puzzles in K-12 schooling are related to financing, and most
structural school reforms are loosely based on economic arguments. For
instance, school choice is related to the competitive-market metaphor,
and school finance equalization is based loosely on progressive taxation
of income and wealth. These arguments (and the related policies) need to
be made rigorous and subjected to empirical examination.
Third, economists broadly agree that educational systems ought to
solve the problem of investment in human capital, which involves some
capital market failures and spillovers.(5) This consensus is important
because it facilitates analytic progress. In contrast, popular and legal
debates about education often become mired in struggles over whether it
is best to maximize enrollment, maximize achievement, maximize the
equality of achievement among students, or do something else entirely.
In my own work on school reform, I have attempted to bring all three
advantages of economics to bear: modern empirical methods, rigorous
economic argument, and a consistent focus on solving the human capital
investment problem.
Empirical Evidence on School Choice
Analysis of the various reforms should begin with the two basic,
traditional forms of school choice in the United States: choice among
public school districts and choice between public and private schools.
These two existing options give certain parents a substantial degree of
choice, and the effects of their choices are useful for predicting the
effects of other reforms. Moreover, empirical evidence on how
traditional choice affects students is the only way we can learn about
the general equilibrium and long-term effects of school choice.
For instance, several studies (including one I am conducting) are
currently evaluating charter and voucher schools, using randomized "treatment" and "control" groups of students.(6)
These studies can inform us about the effects of voucher or charter
schools only on those students who actually use them. The studies tell
us nothing about the effects that a widespread voucher or charter school
policy would have on public school attendance or on how public schools
would respond to competition. But analysis of the two traditional forms
of choice does inform us about these crucial issues. Furthermore, school
choice reforms are always layered on top of traditional choice, and
households will make different decisions about traditional choices as
the reforms are added.
Evidence on Choice Among Public School Districts
Choice among public school districts occurs when households can pick
their residences. To analyze the effects of such choice, I compare
metropolitan areas among which there are long-term differences in
parents' ability to choose a school district? Ease of choice
depends both on the number of districts in the area and on the evenness
with which enrollment is spread over those districts. Choice is easier
in a metropolitan area in which parents choose among 20 districts of
equal size than in an area where three-quarters of enrollment falls into
one of 20 districts, which in turn is easier than in an area with only
one school district.
Great variation exists among metropolitan areas in the degree of
choice that is available. For instance, Boston has 70 school districts
within a 30-minute commute of the downtown area, while the much larger
Miami metropolitan area has only one school district (Dade County).
These differences are largely a result of history and geography, but a
district's enrollment can also reflect its success: an efficient
district attracts a disproportionate share of metropolitan area
enrollment and gets other districts to consolidate with it. In simple
comparisons among metropolitan areas, this introduces a bias against
finding that greater choice among districts has positive effects.
To obtain unbiased estimates, I identify geographic and historical
factors that increase a metropolitan area's tendency to contain
many, small, independent school districts but that are unrelated to
contemporary public school quality. For example, I use the fact that
metropolitan areas with more streams have more natural barriers and
boundaries; because they increase students' travel time to school,
they may cause the lines drawn to define smaller districts. The
resulting (IV) estimates based on cross-section data (including rich
demographic data on each school) allow me to identify the causal effect
of greater availability of public school districts, while controlling
for a wide range of background variables and differentiating the effects
of choice on self-segregation.
I find that a one standard deviation change in a Herfindahl index of
enrollment concentration, which corresponds to a substantial increase of
choice among districts (for instance the difference between having 4 and
100 equal-sized districts) causes a statistically significant but small
(2 percentile points) improvement in students' reading and math
scores.(8) However, school efficiency improves dramatically, because the
same increase in choice causes schools' per-pupil costs to fall by
17 percent. The powerful implications occur because the effects are
opposite in sign: an increase in choice improves student achievement
even while accomplishing substantial cost savings.
Choice among districts turns out to have little effect on the degree
of segregation among students. The reason is that, empirically, the
degree of racial, ethnic, and income segregation that a student
experiences is related to the degree of choice among schools in a
metropolitan area, but not to the degree of choice among districts. In
other words, students are just as segregated in metropolitan areas that
contain few districts as they are in metropolitan areas that contain
many districts. Households sort themselves into neighborhoods inside
districts; neighborhoods and schools are small enough relative to
districts that district boundaries have little effect on segregation.
This result demonstrates how important it is to compare realistic
alternatives. The realistic alternative to a metropolitan area with a
high degree of choice among districts is not a metropolitan area in
which all schools are perfectly desegregated and every student is
exposed to similar peers. The realistic alternative is a metropolitan
area with a low degree of choice among districts and a substantial
degree of segregation among schools.
In another study that examines how parents exercise choice, I find
that parents who have more choice within the public sector favor schools
with strict disciplinary and academic atmospheres. They are also more
involved in their children's schooling: a single standard deviation
increase in the degree of choice causes a 33 percent increase in the
probability that a parent visits his child's school in the course
of a year.(9)
Choice among public school districts is especially helpful for
analyzing charter school and open enrollment reforms because such
analyses require that we know: 1) on what bases parents choose among
schools; 2) how public schools differentiate themselves, given that they
are subject to public scrutiny and public constraints; 3) whether public
providers react to competition for students by improving their programs;
4) how the degree of choice among public providers affects parents'
willingness to pay for private school alternatives; and 5) how students
self-segregate among schools when they can choose but receiving schools
cannot discriminate amongst them. The main limitation of using choice
among public school districts to understand charter school and open
enrollment reforms is that the reforms' financial arrangements
typically have different properties than the finance that results from
traditional choice.
Empirical Evidence on Choice between Public and Private Schools
I have also studied the effects of the second way in which parents
traditionally exercise choice: enrolling their children in private
schools.(10) The schooling offered and the tuition charged by private
schools in the United States vary tremendously. Approximately 90 percent
of private school students attend schools affiliated with religious
groups, but these schools have tuitions that range from token
("$100 or what parents can pay") to over $10,000. The
remaining 10 percent of private school students attend
"independent" schools, which are disproportionately likely to
be exclusively college-preparatory, and which charge more than $5,000
per year in tuition.
More than 65 percent of U.S. private school students attend a school
affiliated with the Catholic Church, although these vary from modest
parochial elementary schools to elite, college-preparatory schools. The
modal private school student in the United States attends a Catholic
school that charges a tuition of about $1,000 dollars (elementary
school) or $2,250 (secondary school) per year.
American private schools typically subsidize tuition with monies from
donations or (less often) income from an endowment. The share of
schooling cost that is covered by subsidies is larger in schools that
serve low-income students, but even the relatively expensive private
schools subsidize tuition. For instance, tuition revenue covers between
55 and 75 percent of the costs of the average Catholic school (depending
on the type), but tuition revenue also covers only 80 percent of the
costs of expensive Friends schools. Private schools that charge highly
subsidized tuition in low-income communities frequently must ration school places.
In a paper that attempts to determine the effects of private school
competition on public schools, I compare metropolitan areas with and
without substantial private school enrollment. Metropolitan areas have
private school attendance rates that vary from, a low of 3 percent to a
high of 33 percent of students. (Private school attendance of 10 to 15
percent is typical.) This variation is created by historical accident,
the donations available for subsidizing private schools in an area, and
the quality of public schools. In particular, low quality public schools
raise the demand for private schools. Thus, simple comparisons will
confound the effect of greater private school competitiveness with the
increased demand for private schools in areas where the public schools
are of poor quality.
To obtain unbiased estimates, I use the fact that a
denomination's private schools can provide more tuition subsidies
if they inherited an endowment (which may be partly in buildings and
land) from a population that was historically comprised mainly of the
affiliated denomination. I use metropolitan areas' historical
religious population densities as instrumental variables that shift the
supply of private schools but are not related to idiosyncratic differences in recent public school quality. I also control for a
variety of background factors that might be correlated both with the
demand for private schools and with public school quality. In
particular, I can control for a household's denomination - so that
if being Catholic, say, affects a household's demand for public
school spending or the achievement of its children, then this effect is
not confounded with the effect of greater availability of Catholic
schools.
My estimates suggest that if private schools in an area receive
sufficient resources to subsidize each student's tuition by 1000
dollars, then the achievement of public school students is higher,
regardless of whether it is measured by test scores, ultimate
educational attainment, or wages. Mathematics and reading scores improve
by 8 percentile points; there is an 8 percent increase in the
probability of graduating from high school, and a 12 percent increase in
the probability of getting a baccalaureate degree; wages (for those who
work, later in life at ages 29-37) improve by 12 percent.
My estimates indicate that competition from private schools does not
have a significant effect on public school spending per pupil. This is
because there are offsetting forces. On the one hand, an increased
supply of private schools tends to draw parents into the private sector
who might have supported generous public school spending had their
children remained in public schools. On the other hand, the students who
are drawn into the private school sector would otherwise have had to be
educated at public expense.
Like the effects of choice among public school districts, the effects
of private school competition on segregation of students are small and
statistically insignificant. This is because, first, public schools are
already quite segregated along lines of race, ethnicity, parents'
income, and students' performance. Second, private school
competition typically increases segregation slightly in public schools
and decreases segregation slightly in private schools.
Evidence on traditional private school choice is most useful for
predicting the effects of vouchers and tax credits. However,
policymakers can more easily control the fiscal impact of vouchers and
tax credits on public schools than the fiscal impact of traditional
private school choice on public schools. The size and funding of the
vouchers or tax credits determines their direct fiscal effect. For
instance, most vouchers proposed thus far have been considerably smaller
than per-pupil spending in the sending public school district - so that
every marginal student who uses a voucher to attend private school
leaves monies to be spread among the remaining students.
I also find that parents act as though choice among public school
districts and choice between public and private schools can be
substitutes to some degree.(11) A single standard deviation increase in
the degree of choice among public school districts lowers the share of
children who attend private schools by about 1 percentage point (or,
equivalently, by about 10 percent).
Parents also may be willing to substitute different forms of school
choice reforms for one another, to some degree. For instance, a charter
school program is likely to reduce the demand for voucher and open
enrollment programs.
School Reform
Along with increasing empirical evidence, there have been significant
advances in recent years in the economic theory of school reform.
Specifically, three types of theories have developed, about 1) the
allocative efficiency effects, or how students sort themselves among
schools, the average level of school funding, and which schools receive
funds; 2) the productive efficiency effects, that is, whether schools
use funds efficiently or extract rents; and 3) the effects on income
inequality, intergenerational income mobility, and macroeconomic growth.
Theoretical analysis of the allocative efficiency consequences of
school reform evolves naturally from the literature on local public
goods that is associated with Tiebout. In two papers, Nechyba and Epple
and Romano have analyzed the implications of vouchers and open
enrollment for housing markets, voting on property tax rates, and the
allocation of students among schools.(12) This type of analysis is
difficult because it must be completely general equilibrium, and the
housing market and politics must both "clear" - that is, a
political mechanism for choosing property tax rates must be specified,
allowed to function, and allowed to affect the housing market.
From this literature, we learn that the allocative consequences of
most school choice reforms are ambiguous. For example, reforms affect
mainly the type, not the level of segregation that occurs. If a voucher,
charter school, and open enrollment plan all increase school segregation
for a particular attribute (such as ability, income, or race), then the
same plan decreases residential segregation along that line. Moreover,
an increase in school segregation for one attribute (say, ability) might
decrease segregation for other attributes (say, income) and affect
school funding, in a direction which depends on the spillover function.
Only empirical evidence that enables us to weigh magnitudes can help us
resolve these ambiguities and allow us to rank types of school choice as
solutions to the problem of investment in human capital. Inherent
ambiguity might be the reason that both forms of traditional choice have
statistically insignificant effects on student segregation and why
private school competition has a statistically insignificant effect on
public school funding.
Theory illuminating the effect of school reform on productive
efficiency is at a much less advanced stage than theory on allocative
efficiency. Yet, whether schools are using funds efficiently is an
increasingly important question, especially because the quandaries of
K-12 education, described in the opening paragraphs, appear to be
problems of productivity rather than of allocation. That is, the United
States already supports a high average level of school spending (either
as a share of income or compared to other advanced economies), and the
states have increased their aid to districts that serve disadvantaged
children almost continually over the last 30 years.
Fortunately, the effects of school reform on productive efficiency
are relatively straightforward compared to the effects on allocative
efficiency. Productive inefficiencies are made possible largely by
mobility costs and similar barriers that lead to a group in a school
district of incumbent residents from whom rent can be extracted. While
it is difficult to predict how a school reform will affect people's
choice of residence, where students attend school, and how people vote
on property taxes (for all the general equilibrium reasons described
earlier); it is usually quite easy to characterize how a school reform
affects mobility costs. One of my papers which uses a principal-agent
framework shows, for example, that an increased degree of traditional
choice among public school districts, combined with conventional
American local school finance, reduces the rent that a school
district's bureaucrats can extract from residents.(13) The logic
behind this is that house prices in a metropolitan area with many
similar school districts competing for residents provide a lot of
information about school quality. Because local school budgets depend on
local house prices (through the property tax), the information about
school quality that is embodied in house prices is used to reward school
bureaucrats through the size of their budgets.
Extending the argument to school reforms, including charter schools,
vouchers, and open enrollment programs, is not difficult. All of these
programs substantially lower mobility costs among schools because they
detach school choices from residential choices, and the largest mobility
costs are associated with residential moves. School choice programs also
provide direct links between parent choices and school finances, as
opposed to the indirect link through the housing market.
Appropriate financial arrangements are crucial for school reforms.
The ideal financial arrangements provide consistent and politically
stable rewards for successful schools - the rewards must be generous
enough to encourage expansion of successful schools and contraction of
unsuccessful schools. Many actual school reforms have financial
arrangements that are poorly designed. Indeed, some open enrollment
plans' financial arrangements encourage perverse behavior, such as
fiscal free-riding: that is, purposely locating a school in a district
with low property taxes which borders on a district with high property
taxes and generous school spending, and then using an open enrollment
plan to free-ride on taxpayers in the high property tax district. In the
long run, fiscal free-riding blunts everyone's incentives to
support public school funding.
Recent work by Benabou and Boldrin also links school reform to
macroeconomic growth, the distribution of income, and intergenerational
income mobility.(14) They suggest that the structure of school choice
and school finance both influence allocation - that is, the sorting of
students among schools and the level and distribution of school
spending. These allocative outcomes have consequences for the
nation's overall level of human capital, for whether investments in
human capital are distributed efficiently among people or on the basis
of some arbitrary factor like parents' income, and for the level of
human capital spillovers generated by a given level of financial
investment in human capital. Unfortunately, this macroeconomic
literature shares the difficulties of the microeconomic literature on
allocative consequences of school reform: the consequences are ambiguous
because school choice changes the kind, not the level, of segregation.
The macroeconomic literature also has yet to absorb fully the fact that
households do not distribute themselves in a perfectly desegregated way,
even when there is no school choice and there is centralized finance.
Indeed, quantitatively important, macroeconomic consequences of school
reform are not likely to occur through changes in allocative efficiency
and are more likely to occur through changes in productive efficiency.
I have investigated the relationship between income inequality and
school funding using Census and administrative data at the level of the
school district.(15) For Massachusetts, Illinois, and California at
decade intervals from 1900 to 1990, I find that inequality in school
funding fluctuates with changes in inequality of national income.
Decades of increasing income inequality, such as the 1930s and 1980s,
exhibited increases in school funding inequality (which were somewhat
smaller than the increase in income inequality). Decades of decreasing
income inequality, such as the 1940s and 1950s, showed decreasing
inequality in school funding. I find no evidence of the reverse
relationship - that is, that inequality in school funding for a
generation translates into greater income inequality for that generation
as adults. The fact that there is no evidence for this relationship does
not imply that it does not exist. Rather, it suggests that the
allocative consequences of the changes in school finance that have
occurred over the twentieth century are small when compared to the
powerful effect of the income distribution on the school spending
distribution.
Related Points: Fiscal Independence, Teachers' Unions, and
Higher Education
Up to this point, I have only mentioned in passing the financial
implications of school choice, and I have mainly discussed school
districts as though they were always fiscally independent. In fact, as I
show in two recent papers, this is far from true.(16) In 1950, the
typical American school district raised more than 65 percent of its
funds from a local tax base. By 1990, the typical district raised just
under 40 percent of its revenue this way. Moreover, state aid
increasingly has switched from being effectively "lump sum"
(so far as school districts are concerned) to being a marginal tax on
school districts' locally raised revenue.
In my work on school finance equalization, I use the states'
school finance formulas to calculate the marginal tax price of local
school spending for each school district in the United States in 1972,
1982, and 1992. I show that many school finance equalization schemes
create marginal taxes on the raising of local revenue for schools, and
that there generally has been a substantial decrease in the degree to
which districts are fiscally independent. One consequence of this is
that districts are taxed systemically on any increases they make in
productive efficiency. In other words, a state that reduces its
districts' financial independence (especially at the margin) also
reduces the districts' incentives for productive efficiency, even
if choice among public school districts is easy. For instance, I find
that in California, where (since the Serrano II decision) districts have
almost no financial independence, the positive effects of choice on
student achievement and cost savings are reduced by more than half
(making them statistically insignificant).(17)
How does a school district become more efficient in an environment
with more school choice? I attempt to answer this question in part in a
study of teacher unionization.(18) I use panel data on over 90 percent
of American public school districts in 1972, 1982, and 1992 in order to
see what happened to teacher salaries, the pupil-teacher ratio, school
spending, and student achievement when teachers unionized. I find that
unionization generally reduces school efficiency, but does so by a
smaller amount when the school faces competition from other public
school districts and private schools. For example, unionization makes
teachers' salaries rise less if the school district is in a
metropolitan area with more choice among public school - whether or not
student achievement is held constant - than if it is not.
I have also found it revealing to compare the structure of U.S.
higher education to that of K-12 education. In a recent article on
federal education policy, I discuss whether American colleges have high
international stature and success with a wide range of students partly
because they face a far more competitive market structure than
elementary and secondary schools.(19) College students are increasingly
mobile and active "choosers" of their schools, and they carry
their funds with them when they switch colleges. A much larger share of
colleges than K-12 schools are private, nonprofit institutions. Also,
most American colleges (including public colleges) are highly
financially independent, so they must attract students in order to
remain solvent. Still, colleges are not only successful with students
from elite backgrounds: Breneman demonstrates that some colleges,
especially community colleges, are inexpensive and successful providers
of remedial schooling for students who need basic secondary school
skills, such as writing, reading, and algebra.(20)
Conclusion
We still do not have an "economics of school reform," but
we are making steady progress on the empirical and theoretical analysis
of school choice policies and school finance policies. By making loose
economic arguments rigorous and bringing empirical evidence to bear, we
have uncovered at least some important stylized facts, for instance,
that the consequences of segregation on school reforms are more
ambiguous than initially thought, and that the productivity consequences
are clearer and probably of greater quantitative importance. Also, we
are increasingly thinking jointly about school choice and school finance
because financial incentives are the key to the way that school choice
actually works. The structure of school choice and school finance are
crucial to how individuals solve their human capital investment problems
and how much a society increases its human capital over time. The
implications for income inequality and macroeconomic growth are likely
to keep economists interested for some time to come.
[Note: Most of Hoxby's papers cited here are available through
her Web site, which can be reached through NBER's Web site
(www.nber.org).]
1 A.M. Tucker and W.F. Lauber, School Choice Programs: What's
Happening in the States. Washington, D.C.: The Heritage Foundation
Press, 1995. Also see J. Allen, School Choice Programs: What's
Happening in the States. Washington, DC: The Heritage Foundation Press,
1992.
2 C.M. Hoxby, "Is There An Equity-Efficiency Trade-Off in Local
School Finance?" NBER Working Paper No. 5265, September 1995. See
also S. Peltzman, "The Political Economy of the Decline of American
Public Education," Journal of Law and Economics, (Winter/Spring
1993), 36(1-2), pp. 331-70.
3 C.M. Hoxby, "Are Efficiency and Equity in School Finance
Substitutes or Complements?" Journal of Economic Perspectives,
(Fall 1996), 10(4), pp. 51-72. See also E. Hanushek and S. Rivkin,
"Understanding the 20th Century Explosion in U.S. School
Costs," mimeo, University of Rochester and Amherst College, 1994.
4 C.M. Hoxby, "Not All School Finance Equalizations Are Created
Equal," mimeo, Harvard University, 1995. See also W. Evans, S.
Murray, and R. Schwab, "Schoolhouses, Courthouses, and Statehouses
After Serrano," Journal of Policy Analysis and Management, (January
1997), 16(1), pp. 10-37.
5 I certainly argue that there should be a consensus in C.M. Hoxby
(Journal of Economic Perspectives, 1996 - see n. 3). This is also the
standard suggested by R. Benabou and by Raquel Fernandez and Richard D.
Rogerson. See R. Benabou, "Heterogeneity, Stratification, and
Growth: Macroeconomic Implications of Community Structure and School
Finance," American Economic Review, (June 1996), 86(3), pp.
584-609.
6 See, for instance, J. Greene, W. Howell, and P. Peterson, "An
Evaluation of the Cleveland Scholarship Program," Harvard
University Program in Education Policy and Governance Occasional Paper,
199
7. 7 C.M. Hoxby, "Does Competition Among Public Schools Benefit
Students and Taxpayers," NBER Working Paper No. 4979, December
1994.
8 In practice, the most reliable measure of the ease of choice is a
Herfindahl index based on districts' enrollment shares. The
Herfindahl index incorporates both the number of districts and the
evenness of districts' enrollment shares. A Herfindahl index based
on enrollment shares is computed as follows. Suppose a metropolitan area
has J school districts, which we index by j = 1, ..., J. Suppose each
school district has a share, [s.sub.j], of total metropolitan area
enrollment. Then, the index is:
[Mathematical Expression Omitted]
When there is no choice in a metropolitan area because there is only
one public school district, the index is equal to 1. As more districts
are added, and as enrollment is spread more evenly over those districts,
the index gets closer to 0.
9 C.M. Hoxby, "When Parents Can Choose, What Do They Choose? The
Effects of School Choice on Curriculum and Atmosphere," in When
Schools Make a Difference, S. Mayer and P. Peterson, eds., Washington,
DC: The Brookings Institution Press, 1998.
10 C.M. Hoxby, "Do Private Schools Provide Competition for
Public Schools?" NBER Working Paper No. 4978, December 1994. See
also C. M. Hoxby, "The Effects of Private School Vouchers on
Schools and Students," in Holding Schools Accountable, H. Ladd,
ed., Washington, DC: The Brooking Institution Press, 1996.
11 C.M. Hoxby, "Do Private Schools Provide Competition for
Public Schools?"
12 D. Epple and R. Romano, "Public School Choice and Finance
Policies, Neighborhood Formation, and the Distribution of Educational
Benefits," mimeo, Carnegie-Mellon University and University of
Florida, 1995. See also T.J. Nechyba, "Public School Finance in a
General Equilibrium Tiebout World: Equalization Programs, Peer Effects,
and Vouchers," NBER Working Paper No. 5642, June 1996.
13 C.M. Hoxby, "Tiebout and a Theory of the Local Public Goods
Producer," NBER Working Paper No. 5265, September 1995 (revised
1997).
14 See the reference to R. Benabou, American Economic Review, 1996,
in n. 5. See also M. Boldrin, "Public Education and Capital
Accumulation," Economic Theory Workshop Discussion Paper No. 1017,
1993.
15 C.M. Hoxby, "How Much Does School Spending Depend on Family
Income? The Historical Origins of the Current School Finance
Dilemma," American Economic Review, Papers and Proceedings, 88(2),
May 1998.
16 See C.M. Hoxby, Journal of Economic Perspectives, 1996, and,
"Not All School Finance Equalizations Are Created Equal,"
1995.
17 C.M. Hoxby, "Does Competition Among Public Schools Benefit
Students and Taxpayers?"
18 C.M. Hoxby, "How Teachers' Unions Affect Education
Production," Quarterly Journal of Economics, (August 1996), 111(3),
pp. 671- 718.
19 C.M. Hoxby, "Where Should Federal Education Initiatives Be
Directed? K-12 Education versus Higher Education," in Financing
College Tuition: Government Priorities and Social Priorities, M.
Kosters, ed., Washington, DC: American Enterprise Institute Press, 1998.
20 D. Breneman, "The Extent and Cost of Remediation in Higher
Education," in Brookings Papers in Education Policy, D. Ravitch
ed., Washington, DC: The Brookings Institution Press, 1997.
Caroline M. Hoxby is an NBER Research Associate in the Programs on
Public Economics, Labor Studies, and Children, and the Morris Kahn
Associate Professor of Economics at Harvard University.