Patents, patent citations, and the dynamics of technological change.
Jaffe, Adam B.
Economists accept that technological change contributes powerfully to
long-run improvements in living standards. Yet, we know surprisingly
little about the determinants of technological change, including the
relative contributions of different economic agents to the change
process, the empirical sensitivity of the process to economic
incentives, and the extent of market failure surrounding decisions
affecting investments in new knowledge and technology. In part, this
lack of knowledge is attributable to the fact that, until recently, some
economists have tended to view technology as a "black box"
that affected the economic system but that was itself driven largely by
exogenous noneconomic forces, such as the advance of science. Pioneering
work by Schmookler, Griliches, and others showed that this was not true;
more recently the so-called New Growth Theory of Romer, Lucas, Grossman
and Helpman, and others, has placed technology squarely within the
economic system. However, grappling with these ideas empirically
requires confronting the reality that many of the relevant activities,
although endogenous to the political-economic system, are carried out in
institutions such as universities and government laboratories, and may
not be amenable to analysis with the standard tools of the theory of the
firm.
More fundamentally, microeconomic analysis of the process of
technological change must confront severe measurement problems.
Fundamentally, technological change is driven by an investment process
that produces a form of capital that is hard to see or measure.
Moreover, technological change is inherently an interrelated and
cumulative process: an important part of the economic consequence of
investments made by one agent is the effect that such investments have
on the marginal product of other (either subsequent or made by others)
investments. Thus, empirical implementation of New Growth Theory, and
the broader agenda of quantifying the determinants of technological
change, requires the development of methods 1) to measure the output of
investments in new knowledge and new technology, including investments
made in the university and government sectors, and 2) to quantify the
linkages across time and institutional boundaries by which the
"spillovers" and cumulative impact of new knowledge are
manifested. Along with various coauthors, I have explored the use of
data on patents and patent citations for these purposes.
Patents are an interesting "economic institution." In
return for a government-enforced monopoly franchise on the commercial
exploitation of an invention, the patentee must disclose and explain the
invention, in principal with sufficient detail that a knowledgeable
practitioner of the relevant technology could reproduce the invention
using the patent document. When a patent is issued, a large amount of
information is publicly recorded, and most of this information is now
available in computerized form. The information that is available
includes the following: 1) the names and postal addresses of the
inventor(s); 2) the organization, if any, to which the patent property
right was assigned or transferred when the patent was issued, and its
legal address; 3) a detailed technological classification of the
invention; 4) the patentee's specific claims regarding what the
invention can do that could not be done before; and 5) citations that
indicate previously existing knowledge, embodied in prior patents or
other publications, upon which the patent builds.
Constructing a Database of Patents
Michael Fogarty, Manuel Trajtenberg, Bronwyn H. Hall, and I are
engaged in an NBER project, funded by the National Science Foundation,
to assemble patent information into a dataset for economic research. The
data file, which eventually will reside on an Internet site accessible
to all qualified researchers, contains most of the foregoing information
for about 3 million U.S. patents granted since 1963. The dataset tracks
the citations in all patents since 1977 and permits convenient merging
of data relating to citing and cited patents. For example, one can look
specifically at patents granted to inventors residing in the United
States and ask what fraction of the subsequent patents citing them are
also from the United States. Because of the detail in the patent data,
one can ask about specific time periods or specific technological fields
separately, and can look at finer geographic breakdowns, such as states
or metropolitan areas.
Using these data, my coauthors and I have begun to explore two broad
categories of questions about the dynamics of technological change.
First, we examine the number and composition of citations that a patent
receives from subsequent patents as an indicator of an invention's
technological and economic impact. We also explore the use of these
citation-based measures of impact to quantify the effects of changes in
incentives for research organizations. Second, we consider patent
citations as proxies for the flow of "knowledge spillovers"
from the inventors whose patents are cited to the inventors making the
citations. In this context, we examine the effects of geographic
proximity, technological relatedness, organizational boundaries, and
passage of time on these spillover flows.
Citation-based Measures of "Basicness" of Inventions
My research in this area began with a paper written in 1990 with
Manuel Trajtenberg and Rebecca Henderson and published recently.(1) We
tested whether patent citations could be used to identify
"basic" inventions, using the hypothesis that inventions
coming out of universities were, on average, more basic than those
coming from private firms. We proposed several measures of the basicness
of inventions, based on patent citations. These include both
"backward" measures (derived from the citations made by a
patent) and "forward" measures (derived from the citations
that a patent subsequently receives from other patents). For both
forward and backward citations, the measures fall into three categories:
importance measures are based on the number of citations made or
received; distance measures relate to the proximity or remoteness of the
cited or citing patents, across both time and technology space; and
originality or generality measures relate to the dispersion of citations
made or received across different areas of technology space. We also
examined the extent to which the citations made by patents were to
scientific articles rather than to other patents as an indicator of the
closeness of the invention to basic science.(2) We found that the
forward measures of basicness based on citations generally were
significantly higher for university patents, but the differences in the
backward measures were typically not significant, except for the
citations to scientific papers, which were significantly higher for
university patents.
We also proposed that the fraction of "self-citations" -
citations that come from patents assigned to the same organization - was
an indicator of the originating organization's successful
appropriation of the subsequent fruits of that research. The data
confirm that this fraction was much higher for firms than for
universities, and it was higher for large firms than for small firms (as
high as 25 percent for the largest firms).
That first paper was based on patents from the 1970s and early 1980s.
In 1980, Congress changed U.S. law, making it much easier for
universities to get patents and license them to commercial firms.
Following this change, the number of patents taken out by universities
has exploded, from about 500 per year in 1980 to about 2,000 per year
today. The motivation for the policy change was to increase the rate of
technology transfer from universities to the private sector. The
increase in the number of patents suggests that the policy was
enormously successful. However, because patenting is now so much easier
for universities, one wonders whether inventions in the current flood of
patents are comparable in technological significance to those patented
when doing so was more difficult. In another paper, Henderson,
Trajtenberg, and I show that, according to citation-based measures, the
technological impact of university patents declined dramatically during
the 1980s, suggesting that the effective increase in technology transfer
has been significantly less than the raw patent numbers suggest.(3)
In recent work with Michael Fogarty and Bruce Banks, I applied a
similar analysis to patents assigned to U.S. government research
labs.(4) We found that, unlike university patents, federal labs'
patents historically were less frequently cited than corporate patents,
except for National Aeronautics and Space Administration (NASA) patents
approved during the 1970s. The federal patents, particularly NASA
patents, were somewhat more basic than corporate patents, as indicated
by their "generality" or the dispersion of their citation
effects across many areas of technology. This paper also includes
qualitative analysis based on interviews with inventors in both the
government labs and in firms. These discussions show that, although
there is a lot of "noise" in citations data, there is a
systematic relationship between citations and technological impact.
A related paper written with Ricardo J. Caballero integrates
citations as evidence of research spillovers into the theoretical
framework of New Growth Theory.(5) In the context of a general
equilibrium dynamic growth model, we use citations to measure the
cumulative impact of research on research productivity in subsequent
periods. Our estimation of the model based on aggregate annual data
suggests that a decline in the aggregate "fertility" of
invention in the United States in the second half of this century was a
factor in the productivity slowdown experienced in the 1970s.
Work in progress with Hall and Trajtenberg examines the relationship
between the stock market's valuation of firms and the number of
citations the firms' patents receive.(6) Preliminary results
suggest that firms' possession of frequently cited patents is
correlated with market participants' perceptions of the value of
firms' knowledge stocks. Further analysis will explore the timing
of these relationships, possible connections among citations, private
returns to inventions, and obsolescence of technology as other firms
develop competing technologies.
Patterns of Citations as Evidence of Paths of Knowledge Flows
Turning to the use of citations to trace the flows of knowledge
spill-overs, my 1993 paper with Henderson and Trajtenberg examines
whether patent citations come from geographically proximate inventors.
Because citations tend to come from inventors pursuing technologically
related research, and inventors working in particular areas tend to be
concentrated in certain locations, our analysis controls for the
nonrandom geographic distribution of researchers working in particular
fields. We also exclude self-citations, to limit the analysis to
citations that might indicate spillovers. We find that at the levels of
metropolitan areas, states, and the United States as a whole, citations
are concentrated locally to a statistically significant extent, although
the actual magnitude of the effects is rather modest.(7)
Trajtenberg and I have extended this analysis in two more recent
papers.(8) Adapting the "citation function" formulation
developed by Caballero and Jaffe, we examine the flows of citations
across countries and time. We find strong evidence that citation flows
are geographically localized, not only within the United States but also
within the United Kingdom,' France, Germany, and Japan. For
example, even though we examined patents taken out in the U.S. patent
system, patents from Japanese inventors are more likely to cite Japanese
patents than German, French, or British patents; we find similar
localization for all countries. We also find important time effects:
citation localization is strongest in the first few years after a patent
issues, and fades significantly over time. The results suggest strongly
that, although knowledge eventually diffuses fully around the globe,
inventors that work near important sources of new ideas benefit
significantly sooner from their spillovers than do inventors that are
farther away. We also find that self-citations arrive much more quickly
than non-self-citations. Overall, geographic localization is partly a
result of self-citation at the level of individual firms, but it is
still significant even after self-citations are eliminated.
Ongoing work will extend this research in several directions. We are
preparing a survey of inventors to explore in more detail the
relationships among patent citations, communication among inventors,
research spillovers, and cumulative technological impact. We are also
continuing to explore the finer detail of the geographic, institutional,
and technological dimensions of the citation patterns. Because of the
richness of the data, the potential range of research questions is
large, including the following: What role do factors other than
geographic distance (for example, language, culture, and economic ties)
play in flows of knowledge around the globe? Do particular firms or
kinds of firms play central roles in the flows of knowledge? Do
particular kinds of research or technological fields generate measurably
large spillovers? We are also pursuing further work linking patent
citations to other economic observables, such as market value and
productivity at the levels of firms, industries, and countries.
While I doubt that we will ever be able to measure
"invention" or "knowledge" as well as we measure
labor or even capital, I do believe that this line of research is
gradually increasing our ability to give empirical content to economic
constructs that play crucial roles in economic theory and economic life.
1 M. Trajtenberg, R. Henderson, and A.B. Jaffe, "University
versus Corporate Patents: A Window on the Basicness of Invention,"
Economics of Innovation and New Technology, 5, (1997), pp. 19-50. Also
presented as "Telling Trails Out of School: University versus
Corporate Patents and the Basicness of Invention," at the 1991 AEA Annual Meeting.
2 This last idea has been carried further by Francis Narin, who has
looked in detail at the citations to scientific literature in
biotechnology patents and bas shown close links to research funded by
the U.S. National Institutes of Health and other basic research
agencies. See F Narin, Linkage Between U.S. Patents and Public Science,
CHI Research, Inc., 1997.
3 R. Henderson, A.B. Jaffe, and M. Trajtenberg, "Universities as
a Source of Commercial Technology: A Detailed Analysis of University
Patenting, 1965-1988," Review of Economics and Statistics, LXXX, 1,
(February 1998), pp. 119-27.
4 A.B. Jaffe, M. Fogarty, and B. Banks, "Evidence from Patents
and Patent Citations on the Impact of NASA and Other Federal Labs on
Commercial Innovation," NBER Working Paper No. 6044, May 1997.
Forthcoming in the Journal of Industrial Economics.
5 R.J. Caballero and A.B. Jaffe, "How High are the Giants'
Shoulders: An Empirical Assessment of Knowledge Spillovers and Creative
Destruction in a Model of Economic Growth" in NBER Macroeconomics Annual, Vol. 8, O. Blanchard and S. Fischer, eds. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press, 1993.
6 B.H. Hall, A.B. Jaffe, and M. Trajtenberg, "Patent Citations
and Market Value A First Look,"paper presented at the NBER Program
Meeting on Productivity, March 6, 1998.
7 For example, we found that about 6 percent of citations come from
the same metropolitan area, compared to an expectation of about 1
percent based solely on the geographic concentration of inventors. A.B.
Jaffe, R, Henderson, and M. Trajtenberg, "Geographic Localization
of Knowledge Spillovers as Evidenced by Patent Citations" Quarterly
Journal of Economics, Vol. CViii, (August 1993), issue 3, p. 577.
8 A.B. Jaffe and M. Trajtenberg, "Flows of Knowledge from
Universities and Federal Labs: Modeling the Flow of Patent Citations
over Time and Across Institutional and Geographic Boundaries,"
Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences, 93, (November 1996),
pp. 12671-7; A.B. Jaffe and M. Trajtenberg, "International
Knowledge Flows: Evidence from Patent Citations" NBER Working Paper
No. 6507, April 1998.
Jaffe is an Associate Professor of Economics at Brandeis University,
an NBER Research Associate, and Coordinator of the NBER's Project
on Industrial Technology and Productivity. His report on that Project
and his Profile appeared in the Spring 1996 NBER Reporter. The research
described in this article was supported by National Science Foundation
Grants SBR-9320973 and SBR-9413099 to the NBER.