Do we still need commercial banks?
Rajan, Raghuram G.
According to many observers, the commercial bank - the institution
that accepts deposits payable on demand and originates loans - has
outlived its usefulness and is in a state of terminal decline.
Commercial banks' share of total financial institution assets in
the United States has fallen dramatically, from more than 70 percent
around the turn of the century to just around 30 percent today.(1) Bank
share of corporate debt in the United States has declined from 19.6
percent in 1979 to 14.5 percent in 1994.(2) Competition on both sides of
the banks' balance sheet has increased. On the banks' asset
side, the growth of the commercial paper and junk bond markets has given
large firms an alternative to borrowing from the bank. On the liability
side, new technologies and deregulation have given customers choices.
Instead of being forced to deposit at the local bank branch or make
payments through a bank checking account, customers are able to use
mutual funds that offer much the same services.
At the same time that banks appear to be losing business to
financial markets and other institutions, they are also imposing huge
costs on society. The savings and loan crisis in the United States cost
taxpayers several hundred billion dollars by even the most conservative
estimate. Estimates of the cost of cleaning up the Japanese banking
crisis now exceed $500 billion, and few will hazard a guess as to the
costs of the East Asian banking crisis. In the face of the apparent
decline in the role of banks and the large costs they can still impose
on taxpayers, it is legitimate to ask whether we still need commercial
banks.
Further Questions
In order to answer this, we have to ask two further questions.
First, what functions do banks perform? Second, is the institutional
form that carried out these functions no longer useful?
Before I go further, let me be more specific about the
institutional form under investigation. The U.S. Banking Act of 1971
defines the "commercial bank" as an institution that offers
demand deposits and originates loans. Therefore, a money market mutual
fund is not a bank (it does not originate loans) and a finance company
is also not a bank (it does not offer demandable deposits). To start
with, I adopt this product-based description as my working definition of
a commercial bank.
What Banks Do: Liquidity Provision
Banks essentially perform two functions. First, they provide
liquidity. Every time customers withdraw money from an automated teller
machine or write a check, they rely on the bank's liquidity
provision function. Because this is the immediate point of contact most
of us have with banks, early influential papers in banking quite
naturally focused on the role of banks in meeting the liquidity needs of
depositors.(3) Still, there is very little difference between a demand
deposit that an investor holds and a line of credit extended to a firm.
Both products require the bank to pay the client money on demand.
Therefore it seems natural to conclude that the bank provides liquidity
on both sides of the balance sheet - to both depositors and borrowers.
Why might a bank want to do this? A bank can achieve scale
economies by using the same underlying reserve of liquid assets and the
same institutional arrangements (access to the central bank's
discount window and to other banks) to meet the unexpected demands of
both borrowers and depositors. Also, the demands may offset each other
(borrowers draw down lines of credit at different times from
depositors), economizing on the need to hold low-return reserves.(4)
Anil Kashyap, Jeremy Stein, and I find evidence suggesting
complementarities between demand deposits and lines of credit for banks
in the United States - the more a bank does of one, the more it does of
the other. Moreover, our work suggests that synergies between the
products arise because a bank can economize on holdings of liquid assets
when the two products are jointly offered.
In summary, banks appear to provide liquidity in many ways, not
just through demand deposits, and the banks' ability to take
advantage of diversification is what gives them an advantage in
servicing these various demands.
What Banks Do: Fund Complex Positions
The second major function banks perform is to fund complex,
illiquid positions.(5) Historically, this has taken the form of making
term loans to borrowers who are "difficult" credits. By virtue
of their past relationships with client firms, banks know more about
their future prospects, as well as about alternative uses for the
firms' assets.(6) Consequently, they can lend more than other
less-knowledgeable lenders.(7) Consistent with these theories, Mitchell
Petersen and I find that, correcting for other effects, the availability
of credit to small firms increases with the length of their banking
relationship and the number of dimensions across which they interact
with their bank.(8)
Also, the bank's specific lending skills and knowledge have to
be brought into play when the bank wants to coax repayment. As a result,
the loans are hard to sell to other potential lenders without similar
skills or knowledge. Thus the bank's positions have historically
been illiquid.(9)
The positions that banks enter are complex and illiquid for a
variety of other reasons. In particular, many of the transactions
between the bank and its borrower may be governed by an implicit
understanding rather than by explicit contracts. If explicit contracts
are incomplete, then implicit arrangements can be more flexible and
allow for superior transactions.
Petersen and I consider the following natural experiment to test
this premise(10): The theory suggests that implicit arrangements between
two parties typically are harder to sustain when competitive
alternatives are open to the partners. Some areas of the United States
have relatively concentrated banking markets. In these areas, implicit
arrangements should be easier to sustain. Specifically, a bank can give
a borrower subsidized credit when the borrower most needs it - when it
is young or distressed - with the intent of recouping the subsidy when
the firm is more mature or healthy. Unlike in a more competitive market,
the bank can make the intertemporal cross-subsidy, confident that the
firm has no alternative but to stick with the bank when mature or
healthy.(11) Petersen and I find evidence consistent with this argument.
Small young firms in areas in the United States where there are few
banks get more credit than similar firms in areas where banking is more
competitive. Moreover, firms in concentrated areas pay less than similar
firms in competitive areas for their credit when young (they receive
subsidized financing when most needed), and pay more when old (they
repay earlier subsidies). More generally, our evidence suggests that
more complicated intertemporal transactions are possible within
bank-firm relationships than are possible through explicit contracting.
Because of their nature, however, these implicit relationships are
hard for outsiders to track or take over. Thus banking relationships add
to the complexity and illiquidity of bank positions.
Finally, banks' comparative advantage in financial innovation
make their positions novel and therefore illiquid in the face of a less
advanced market. There are several possible reasons that banks have an
advantage in innovation. New financial instruments and contracts
typically are incomplete in many ways when they are first introduced.
Payments or responsibilities have not been spelled out fully for many
possible situations, partly because those situations have not been
anticipated. There needs to be a trial period during which the contract
may be tried out in real-world situations and the appropriate
contractual features for dealing with initially unforeseen contingencies
developed. The firms with which a bank has relationships form an ideal
testing ground because the relationships allow the contract to be
perfected in a nonadversarial environment. However, this ability to
enter into innovative contracts that the market does not fully
understand adds to the complexity of the banks' positions and their
illiquidity.(12)
Why Both Functions?
These two functions, liquidity provision and funding complex
positions, seem incompatible. In the first, the bank must come up with
money on demand, while in the second, the bank holds investments that,
because of their novelty or dependence on the bank's specific
knowledge, are hard to undo or liquidate. Excessive investment in
illiquid positions make the illiquid bank susceptible to inefficient
runs.(13) It seems silly to tie the two functions together; hence there
are increasingly strident calls from politicians and some academics to
break up the bank and distance the two functions.
Yet, the widespread coexistence of these functions in the bank,
both historically and across countries, should give us pause. Could
there be synergies between the two functions? Douglas Diamond and I
argue that, because bankers' specialized skills enable them to
manage complicated positions, they have the ability to extract high
rents from their investors. Bankers can commit to extracting lower rents
in the future by issuing demand deposits that are a "hard"
claim. More generally, by providing liquidity, a bank also can commit
itself to lower compensation for managing complex positions. This
reduces the bank's cost of financing those positions. Diamond and I
also explain why we would not see industrial firms financing themselves
with demandable deposits.(14)
Stewart Myers and I point to another source of synergy.(15) Banks
have to maintain a store of very liquid assets in order to meet
unexpected demand for liquidity. However, these liquid assets can be
invested at short notice against the interests of financiers. The
potential for opportunistic risky investment by the banker can raise the
bank's cost of financing. One way for the bank to avoid
opportunistic risks is for it to embed part of its value in complex
illiquid positions. Because these positions are hard to unwind, they
give financiers time to react to changes in the bankers' strategy.
The positions are also a (limited) source of rents for bankers
(discussed earlier), and they may be unwilling to jeopardize these in
order to undertake short-term opportunistic investments.
In summary, the function of liquidity provision requires issuing
demandable claims that have the ancillary effect of keeping in check the
bank's rents from managing illiquid positions. Moreover, the
bank's remaining rents and the illiquidity of its positions
increase its stake in the future. As a result, the bank can commit to
holding liquid assets safely without the straitjackets of rules and
regulations that other institutions, such as money market mutual funds,
require. Thus there are synergies flowing both ways that reduce the
bank's cost of financing when it undertakes both functions
together.
Is the Institutional Form Dead?
Equipped with some theory, we can ask whether the bank is dead. If
the institutional form is defined in terms of its products - demand
deposits and industrial loans - then the data suggest a definite decline
in its importance in industrial countries. Depositors are moving away
from banks to money market mutual funds and large firms are issuing
public debt to meet their financing needs rather than borrowing from
banks.
On the face of it, therefore, disintermediation appears rampant.
However, if one looks closer, it appears that banks continue to provide
their traditional functions, albeit through nontraditional products. For
example, one could observe the dramatic increase in volume of commercial
paper issuances relative to bank commercial loans and conclude,
incorrectly, that the role of banks in providing liquidity to borrowers
is declining. In fact, instead of providing liquidity directly to a
large firm, a bank provides a backup line of credit that can be drawn
down in case the firm's commercial paper cannot be refinanced. It
is much more effective for the bank to provide such contingent
guarantees than to directly fund the firm's liquidity needs: With
contingent guarantees, the same unit of liquid reserves can back the
needs of multiple firms. By contrast, with direct funding, a unit of
liquid reserve is fully locked up in meeting the liquidity needs of a
single firm.
Since banks have begun to use their balance sheets more cleverly,
old measures - such as the relative size of bank assets - are no longer
useful in describing the importance of the role of banks. A more useful
indicator is one that adds capitalized fee income to bank assets. By
this measure, banks continue to maintain their importance.(16)
While banks are not dying out, they may be changing. With the
widespread availability of information and increases in both processing
capability and regulatory infrastructure, many more transactions can be
handled directly in the market or by specialized institutions. This has
forced banks to give up products that have become commodity-like and to
refocus on products where bank value-added is still substantial.
Typically, we see a cycle of innovation. Banks develop a complex new
product, extract some rents for a while, and, eventually, the product
becomes well understood and is offered by the market.(17) Banks then
move on to new products.
This means that it is not very useful to continue associating a
bank with specific products such as demand deposits and commercial
loans. Such terms describe small community banks and little else today.
However, if we define banks as institutions that jointly provide
liquidity and complicated funding, we capture much more of the essence
of what banks really do and vastly expand the set of banks for which the
definition has relevance.
Do We Really Need Banks?
With this broader definition, and the evidence that, according to
reasonable measures, the relative importance of banks in the financial
sector has not declined, we have to conclude that it is too early to
write off banks. Given the market value that most banks command today,
and the University of Chicago's traditional belief in efficient
markets, I could not have reached a different conclusion. However, the
private valuations may be at the public expense: Banks may be so
valuable partly because they can dip periodically into the public till.
Unfortunately, absent much better financial markets than those that
currently exist, the theory suggests we cannot get many of the good
things banks do, such as liquidity creation, credit origination, and
financial innovation, without banks issuing claims susceptible to runs
and thus being financially fragile. In breaking up banks into finance
companies and money market funds (the so-called "narrow" bank
proposals), we risk throwing the baby out with the bath water. Thus part
of the Faustian bargain that we have to live with is that periodic
banking disasters will occur and public money will be used.(18)
Innovations in regulation and supervision can attempt to reduce the
magnitude of the problem, but we should recognize that the alternative
of doing away with the banks, at least in the foreseeable future, could
be much worse.
1. See C. James and J. Houston, "Evolution or Extinction:
Where Are Banks Headed?," Bank of America Journal of Applied
Corporate Finance, 9, (1996), pp. 8-23.
2. See A. Berger, A.K Kashyap, and J. Scalise, "The
Transformation of the U.S. Banking Industry: What a Long Strange Trip
It's Been," Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, 2, (1995),
pp. 55-217.
3. Liquidity provision can take place in many ways. The bank can
directly pay cash on demand to depositors (see J. Bryant, "A Model
of Reserves, Bank Runs, and Deposit Insurance," Journal of Banking
and Finance, 4. [1980], pp. 335-44); D. Diamond and P. Dybvig,
"Bank Runs, Deposit Insurance, and Liquidity," Journal of
Political Economy, 91, [1983], pp. 401-19). Alternatively, it can
provide a liquid medium of exchange to depositors through bank notes or
checkwriting facilities (see G.B. Gorton and G. Pennachi,
"Financial Intermediaries and Liquidity Creation," Journal of
Finance, 45, [1990], pp. 49- 72).
4. See A.K Kashyap, R.G. Rajan, and J. C. Stein, "Banks as
Liquidity Providers: An Explanation for the Co-Existence of Lending and
Deposit Taking," mimeo, University of Chicago, 1998. Also, there
could be a rationale for offering lines of credit and demand deposits
even if lines of credit are normally not taken down at substantially
different times than deposits. It is sufficient that liquid assets be
held by the firm against the possibility of a "sunspot" run by
depositors. As there is no special reason for those who have lines to
panic at the same time as the depositors, the possibility of more fully
utilizing liquid assets that are held to protect against depositor runs
may be reason enough to offer lines of credit. I should stress that the
novel point in work that Kashyap, Rajan, and Stein (1998) have completed
is the diversification across different categories of liquidity demands.
Diamond and Dybvig (1983) stress that banks diversify across the
liquidity demands of depositors and the fact that banks diversify across
the liquidity needs of borrowing firms has been emphasized by B.R.
Holmstrom and J. Tirole, "Private and Public Supply of
Liquidity," Journal of Political Economy, 106, (1998), pp. 1-40.
5. Banks perform myriad functions. I focus only on the ones that
are both important and serve to distinguish commercial banks from other
financial institutions.
6. See B. Bernanke, "Non-Monetary Effects of the Financial
Crisis in the Propagation of the Great Depression," American
Economic Review, 73, (1983), pp. 257-76; S.A. Sharpe, "Asymmetric
Information, Bank Lending and Implicit Contracts: A Stylized Model of
Customer Relationships," Journal of Finance, 45, (1990), pp.
1069-88; R.G. Rajah, "Insiders and Outsiders: The Choice Between
Informed and Arm's Length Debt,"Journal of Finance, 47,
(1992), pp. 1367-400; D. Diamond and R.G. Rajah, "Liquidity Risk,
Liquidity Creation and Financial Fragility: A Theory of Banking,"
mimeo, University of Chicago, 1998.
7. For evidence, see C. James, "Some Evidence on the
Uniqueness of Bank Loans," Journal of Financial Economics, 19,
(1987), pp. 217-35; T. Hoshi, A.K Kashyap, and D.S. Scharfstein,
"Bank Monitoring and Investment: Evidence from the Changing
Structure of Japanese Corporate Banking Relationships," in
Asymmetric Information, Corporate Finance and Investment, R.G. Hubbard,
ed., Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1990.
8. See M. Petersen and R.G. Rajan, "The Benefits of Lending
Relationships: Evidence from Small Business Data," Journal of
Finance, 49, (1994), pp. 3-37.
9. See Diamond and Rajan (1998).
10. See M. Petersen and R.G. Rajan, "The Effect of Credit
Market Competition on Lending Relationships," Quarterly Journal of
Economics, 110, (1995), pp. 407-43.
11. This idea was initially proposed by C.J. Mayer, "New
Issues in Corporate Finance," European Economic Review, 32, (1988),
pp. 1167-89.
12. See R.G. Rajah, "The Past and Future of Commercial Banking
as Viewed Through an Incomplete Contract Lens," Journal of Money,
Credit and Banking, (1998), forthcoming.
13. See Diamond and Dybvig (1983).
14. Once the bank has offered credit, its specific skills are used
largely in effecting transfers (from borrower to depositor) rather than
in creating value. As a result, demand deposits can play some
disciplinary role because a bank run will render the bank ineffectual
and extinguish its rents. However, in an industrial firm, the
entrepreneur's (or manager's) rents accrue largely from his or
her specific skills in creating value. A run will be highly inefficient,
and its effects will be mitigated by renegotiation. Earlier work by
Calomiris and Kahn (1991) emphasizes the monitoring role of demandable
debt but does not explain why its beneficial effects would be any
different for industrial firms. Hence, the fact that industrial firms
rarely use demand deposits to finance is not explained by their work.
15. S.C. Myers and R.G. Rajan, "The Paradox of
Liquidity," Quarterly Journal of Economics, (1998), forthcoming.
16. J. Boyd and M. Gertler, "Are Banks Dead? Or Are the
Reports Greatly Exaggerated," Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis working paper, 1994.
17. See R.C. Merton, "Financial Innovation and the Management
and Regulation of Financial Institutions,"Journal of Banking and
Finance, 19, (1995), pp. 461-82. 18. The theories described thus far do
not explain why banks have the periodic collective urge to commit
suicide by making bad loans. For one attempt at an explanation, see R.G.
Rajah, "Why Bank Credit Policies Fluctuate: A Theory and Some
Evidence," Quarterly Journal of Economics, 109, (1994), pp.
399-442.
Rajan is Director of the NBER's Program on Corporate Finance
and the Joseph L. Gidwitz Professor at the University of Chicago's
Graduate School of Business. His "Profile" appears later in
this issue.