The empirics of currency and banking crises.
Eichengreen, Barry ; Rose, Andrew K.
Currency and banking crises are potholes on the road to financial
liberalization. It is relatively rare for them to cause a vehicle to
break an axle - to bring the process of growth and liberalization to an
utter and extended halt - but the flats they cause can result in
significant losses of time and output and set back the process of policy
reform. The output costs of both currency and banking crises can be a
year or more of economic growth and the resolution costs of banking
crises have often been the equivalent of two or more years of GNP growth. As capital becomes increasingly mobile, the severity and
prevalence of these problems has grown, as amply demonstrated by recent
experience in Asia, Latin America, and Europe.
There is no shortage of theoretical models of the causes and
consequences of banking and financial crises.(1) But in comparison,
systematic empirical work has been scarce. For the last several years,
therefore, together and with a number of collaborators, we have
attempted to reorient work on this subject in empirical directions.
In this article, we review this empirical research on currency and
banking crises and provide a critical review of related literature. In
addition, we offer some suggestions - and cautions - for future
research.
Currency Crises
Contrary to the assumption of convenience made in some other recent
writings, currency crises cannot be identified with changes in the
exchange rate regime. Not all decisions to devalue or float the exchange
rate are preceded by speculative attacks.(2) More importantly, a central
bank may successfully defend its currency against attack by using its
international reserves to intervene in the foreign exchange market.
Alternatively, it may discourage speculation against the currency by
raising interest rates or forcing the government to adopt other
austerity policies.
An innovation of our work therefore has been to construct empirical
measures of speculative attacks. We measure speculative pressure as a
weighted average of changes in exchange rates, interest rates, and
reserves, where all variables are measured relative to those of a center
country.(3) Intuitively, speculative pressure can lead to a loss of
reserves, be rebuffed by a rise in domestic interest rates, or be
conceded by a depreciation or devaluation of the exchange rate.(4)
Speculative attacks or currency crises (we use the terms
interchangeably) are then defined as periods when this speculative
pressure index reaches extreme values.
With this distinction in mind, we have analyzed of the experience
of more than 20 OECD countries, using data that stretch back to the late
1950s.(5) We find that devaluations - as distinct from currency crises -
generally have occurred after periods of overly expansionary monetary
and fiscal policies. These expansionary policies lead to price and wage
inflation, deteriorating international competitiveness, and weak
external accounts. They occur when unemployment is high. as if
governments are attempting to stimulate an economy in which unemployment
has political and economic costs. But that stimulus leads to a loss of
reserves, which jeopardizes exchange rate stability. There are some
signs that governments react by adjusting policy in more restrictive
directions in an effort to stem the loss of reserves. In episodes that
culminate in devaluation, however, these adjustments prove inadequate.
Reserves continue to decline, eventually forcing the government to
devalue the exchange rate. When devaluation finally occurs, it is
accompanied by some monetary and fiscal retrenchment to reassure
investors and render the new level of the exchange rate sustainable. As
inflationary pressures fall, there is a sustained boost to
competitiveness that helps to restore balance to the external accounts.
This comes at the expense of sustained unemployment and falling
employment and output growth.
It is more difficult to generalize about currency crises. Put
another way, devaluations are more predictable than speculative
attacks.(6) Although there are signs that crises, like devaluations, are
preceded by loose monetary policies and inflation, there is less sign of
governments attempting to rein in their expansionary policies as the
threat to the exchange rate develops. The foreign exchange market
intervention that occurs is sterilized (its potential effects on the
domestic money supply are neutralized, and its effectiveness is
therefore reduced). There are fewer signs of monetary and fiscal
retrenchment in the wake of the event. The exchange rate changes that
take place in response tend to be disorderly. They do not lead to the
establishment of parities that are clearly sustainable. Indeed, the
exchange rate is frequently floated rather than merely being devalued.
Thus, the failure of governments to adapt policy in a manner
consistent with their exchange rate targets is at the heart of many
currency crises. This points to the need for studying political
incentives and constraints on economic policy formulation. One approach
is to build on the theory of optimum currency areas and ask whether
economic characteristics of countries that make exchange rate stability
advantageous are associated with extensive and concerted foreign
exchange market intervention.(7) Another approach is to assess political
considerations directly. We have tested whether speculative attacks are
more likely to occur before or after elections and whether left- or
right-wing governments are more susceptible to their effects. We also
ask whether changes in government and changes in finance minister help
to explain speculative attacks. We find that these standard measures of
political conditions are in fact only loosely linked to speculative
attacks and devaluations, although there is some evidence that when a
new government assumes office because of the electoral defeat of its
predecessor, it feels relatively free to devalue the currency. On other
occasions the finance minister is used as the sacrificial lamb and takes
the blame for the unsuccessful defense. It is perhaps not surprising
that the evidence on political determinants of currency crises is less
than definitive, as identifying them requires pinning down a number of
separate effects - the effect of politics on economic policies, the
effect of economic policies on expectations, and the effect of
expectations on financial market outcomes - each of which is elusive.
Clearly, this is an important area for further work.
Theoretical models suggest that speculative attacks unfold
differently in situations of high and low capital mobility.(8) Our
empirical work confirms this supposition. The presence of capital
controls makes devaluations less likely and increases the likelihood
that a government will be able to rebuff a speculative attack. In our
empirical analysis, we have taken pains to allow for the fact that
capital controls are endogenous. Indeed, we find that controls are more
likely to appear after the exchange rate has been devalued and to
disappear after a failed attack.
Contagion
The Asian crisis has focused attention not just on the determinants
of speculative attacks but also on contagion. We think of contagion as a
tendency for a currency crisis somewhere in the world to increase the
probability of a crisis in another country after controlling for the
latter's fundamentals. Some continue to question whether contagion
exists, arguing that when several countries are attacked simultaneously
this reflects not contagion but the fact that they all exhibit a weak
underlying economic and financial position. Using our measure of
currency crises, we have considered this question in a series of recent
papers.(9) We do so by adding the incidence of crises elsewhere in the
world to the standard domestic determinants of currency crises. The
results strongly suggest that the existence of a currency crisis
elsewhere in the world (whether it leads to a devaluation or not) raises
the probability of an attack on the domestic currency by about 8
percent, even after taking into account a variety of domestic political
and economic factors. This evidence is strikingly robust: A variety of
tests and a battery of sensitivity analyses confirm that a crisis abroad
increases the probability of a speculative attack by an economically and
statistically significant amount, even after controlling for economic
and political fundamentals in the country concerned. This would appear
to be the first systematic evidence of the existence of contagious
currency crises.
How does the infection spread? One possibility is that attacks
spread contagiously to other countries with which the subject country
trades. In the presence of nominal rigidities, countries that devalue
gain competitiveness at the expense of their trading partners. These
competitors are therefore less likely to resist attacks and thus more
likely to be attacked themselves. A second possibility is that attacks
spread to other countries where macroeconomic and financial conditions
are broadly similar, so that there is reason to suspect that the same
underlying problems exist. We test these hypotheses by weighting our
measure of contagion (that is, currency crises in other countries) by
the importance of trade linkages, and, alternatively, by the similarity
of macroeconomic policies and conditions. For our panel of 20 OECD
countries, it turns out that contagion operating through trade is
stronger than contagion as a result of macroeconomic similarities. When
measures of both are included in the specification, trade-related
contagion dominates. Moreover, our proxies for both trade-related
contagion and macro-weighted contagion outperform a naive contagion
measure (the simple existence of speculative attacks in other
countries). We take this as confirmation that our results are picking up
contagion per se and not just the effects of omitted environment factors
common to the countries in question, although the latter might still be
present. Admittedly, similarities in macroeconomic policies and
performance across countries are more difficult to capture than the
intensity of trade linkages; the stronger showing of trade-related
contagion may simply reflect our greater success in proxying this
effect. But, reassuringly, our OECD panel evidence has been confirmed by
other investigators using cross-sectional evidence for OECD and
developing countries.(10)
Future work needs to pay more attention to currency crises in
emerging markets. Unfortunately, attempts to construct proper measures
of exchange market pressure tend to be stymied by the absence of
comparable interest rate data for a large cross-section of developing
countries. It may be argued that the absence of relevant interest rate
data reflects the underdevelopment of the relevant financial markets,
implying in turn that the authorities are not able to use the interest
rate as an instrument for defending the currency. With this
justification it is possible to construct a measure of currency crashes,
either as a weighted average of exchange rate changes and reserve
losses, or simply as large changes in the exchange rate. Analyzing the
correlates of the latter measure suggests that currency crashes in
developing countries are subject to many of the same determinants as
those in advanced industrial countries.(11) Crashes tend to occur when
the rate of growth of domestic credit is high and when output growth is
slow, consistent with the behavior of industrial countries. In addition,
emerging market crashes are most likely when global interest rates are
high and rising and when the share of foreign direct investment (FDI) in
total external debt is relatively low. A fall in FDI inflows by 10
percent of total debt is associated with an increase in the probability
of a crash by 3 percent. Still, there is much work to be done. For
example, developing countries are much more likely to threaten or impose
capital controls in the face of speculative attacks; they are also much
more likely to receive bailout packages led by the International
Monetary Fund. Incorporating the effects of these factors remains an
important topic in the research agenda.
Banking Crises
Compared to currency crises, far less empirical work of a systemic,
cross-country, comparative nature has been done on the causes and
consequences of banking crises, especially in emerging markets.(12) Our
own work does, however, point to a number of regularities.(13) We find
that the stage is set for banking crises by the interaction of
fragilities in domestic financial structure and unpropitious global
economic conditions. Our central finding is of a large, highly
significant correlation between changes in industrial country interest
rates and banking crises in emerging markets. We show that interest
rates in the United States, Europe, and Japan tend to rise sharply and
significantly in the year preceding the onset of banking crises. This
result comes through strongly in univariate and multivariate analyses
alike and is robust to changes in specification. There is also some
evidence that the global business cycles and OECD growth in particular
play important roles in the incidence of banking crises, with slowing
growth in the advanced industrial countries associated with the onset of
crises. These results point to the role of external conditions in
heightening the vulnerability of emerging markets to banking problems.
There are also signs that real overvaluation and slow growth at home
help to set the stage for bank crises, but the evidence is inconsistent
with the notion that domestic macroeconomic problems provide the entire
explanation for emerging market banking crises. This is precisely the
same result found, of course, for emerging market currency crashes.
In addition, our analysis confirms that banking crises can have
quite severe, if short-lived, macroeconomic effects. The disruptions
associated with a banking crisis cause output growth to decline by 2 to
3 percent relative to the control group of non-crisis countries. That
effect lasts only for a year, however; by the second year after a
crisis, growth has recovered nearly to the levels typical of developing
countries that are not in crisis.
Back to Theory
These results provide some guidance as to what kind of theoretical
models are likely to reward further study. The results for OECD
countries suggest that models in which governments are reluctant to
raise interest rates to defend the currency for fear of aggravating an
already serious domestic unemployment problem are likely to have
considerable relevance.(14) The results for emerging markets - for
example, that the share of FDI in foreign debt is associated with
currency and financial stability - are consistent with the many models
in which the maturity structure of the debt is an important determinant
of vulnerability to currency and financial crises. In turn, these
conclusions point to the relevance of so-called second-generation models
of currency and financial crises, in which crises cannot simply be
predicted on the basis of macroeconomic fundamentals like the stance of
monetary and fiscal policy. Instead, crises are possible - but not
necessary - when the economy enters a zone of vulnerability in which
authorities will be reluctant to use restrictive policies to defend the
currency for fear of aggravating already-existing economic and financial
fragilities.(15) In such circumstances, attacks may occur if a
sufficient number of currency traders coordinate on short sales of a
currency. We expect future theoretical work to continue this line of
argument.
Misleading Indicators
Concern over the disruptive effects of currency and banking crises
has led to the development of a considerable industry in which
econometric models like these are used in a mechanistic attempt to
predict currency and banking crises.(16) Our work suggests that these
exercises are subject to important criticisms. Devaluations and
floatations are intrinsically heterogeneous from a theoretical
perspective; they may be caused by the slow deterioration of
macroeconomic fundamentals (as in "first-generation" models),
or they may result from self-fulfilling attacks. As a result, they defy
generalization empirically, complicating efforts at prediction
Theoretical models have identified the kind of variables that can sap a
government's ability to defend itself, thereby rendering it
vulnerable to attack; but the domestic considerations that governments
weigh when contemplating a costly defense of the currency vary across
time and country. High unemployment, weak economic growth, a fragile
banking system, and large amounts of short-term debt may have rendered
governments reluctant to hike interest rates in the past, but one could
imagine in the future that a government will be concerned instead with
the level of property prices, the solvency of a heavily indebted
nonfinancial corporation, or some very different consideration.
These variables do not provide much guidance on when the attack
will come. Whether speculators attack will depend not just on the
weakness of the banking system or the level of unemployment, but on how
much governments care about further aggravating these problems when
deciding whether to defend the currency. The only thing more difficult
to measure than governments' resolve is investors' assessment
of it. Even if observers conclude that the currency peg is vulnerable,
no one market participant is likely to be large enough to build up the
short position needed to exhaust the authorities' reserves. For
that to occur, multiple investors would have to coordinate their
actions. Coordinating devices vary from case to case and generally elude prediction; both the French Referendum on the Maastricht Treaty and the
Chiapas uprising were exceptional noneconomic events. All in all, it is
easy to understand why so many speculative attacks have come as
surprises, even to the speculators themselves.(17)
A close look at existing attempts to build early warning systems
underscores these points.(18) These studies show that the estimated
relationship between observable macroeconomic and financial indicators
and the probability of large changes in exchange rates and reserves
tends to be very sensitive to the sample of countries and the period for
which the exercise is carried out. This belies the notion that there
exist a single set of variables and a stable set of relationships on
which crisis forecasting can be based. As most attacks come as
surprises, models that rely on time-series data tend always to predict
"no crisis."(19) The models that perform best, in statistical
terms, tend to be cross-sectional. They ask which countries were
affected most severely during episodes of speculative pressure, and they
rely on variables like reversals in the direction of capital flows and
sudden reserve losses. Such variables are properly regarded as
concurrent rather than leading indicators of currency crises; once this
information is available, the horse has left the barn. The same
criticisms apply to models that rely for their predictive power on the
number of crises erupting in other countries in the current or
immediately preceding months.
None of this is to deny the value of statistical studies seeking to
deepen our understanding of past crises. However, the success of future
papers in explaining past crises does not mean that they will
necessarily succeed in predicting future crises. This creates a real
danger that the policy community, if led to think otherwise, will be
lulled into a false sense of complacency.
1 One seminal contribution is P. Krugman, "A Model of
Balance-of-Payments Crises," Journal of Money, Credit and Banking,
11 (1979), pp. 311-25. A good recent review is R. Flood and N. Marion,
"Perspectives on the Recent Currency Crisis Literature." NBER Working Paper No. 6380, January 1998. On the causes and consequences of
banking crises, see D. Diamond, "Bank Runs, Deposit Insurance and
Liquidity."Journal of Political Economy, 91 (1983), pp. 401-19; and
B. Bernanke, "Nonmonetary Effects of the Banking Crisis in the
Propagation of the Great Depression," American Economic Review, 73
(1983), pp. 57-276.
2 Recall, for example, the decision of the Taiwanese authorities in
October 1997 to devalue their currency despite the absence of
significant speculative pressure in the foreign exchange market, or the
numerous EMS realignments undertaken in periods of tranquility before
1987.
3 We typically choose Germany, as it is both a strong-currency
country and has been at the core of all OECD fixed exchange rate
regimes. See B. Eichengreen, A. Rose, and C. Wyplosz, "Speculative
Attacks on Pegged Exchange Rates: An Empirical Exploration With Special
Reference to the European Monetary System," in The New
Transatlantic Economy, M. Canzoneri, W. Ethier, and V. Grilli, eds. New
York: Cambridge University Press, 1996.
4 Other empirical studies, which have failed to distinguish actual
changes in exchange rates from speculative attacks, can therefore be
subject to serious bias. Models like those of L. Girton and D. Roper,
"A Monetary Model of Exchange Market Pressure Applied to Postwar
Canadian Experience," American Economic Review, 67 (1977), pp.
537-48, can be used to derive the weights on the three elements of our
speculative pressure index. Given the limitations of the empirical
literature on exchange rate determination, we instead choose weights on
the basis of data characteristics and undertake extensive sensitivity
analysis.
5 See also B. Eichengreen, A. Rose, and C. Wyplosz, "Is There
a Safe Passage to EMU? Evidence on Capital Controls and a
Proposal," in The Microstructure of Foreign Exchange Markets, J. A.
Frankel, G. Galli, and A. Giovannini, eds. Chicago: University of
Chicago Press, 1996; and "Exchange Market Mayhem: The Antecedents
and Aftermath of Speculative Attacks," Economic Policy, 21 (1995),
pp. 249-312.
6 That currently crises are more heterogeneous than devaluations
and that their timing is difficult to predict is consistent with the
conclusions of Rose and Svensson, who found that macroeconomic
fundamentals are of relatively little use for explaining the credibility
of exchange rate parities. Eichengreen and Wyplosz also found that
fundamentals did not obviously predict the timing of the 1992 attack on
the EMS. A. Rose and L. Svensson, "European Exchange Rate
Credibility Before the Fall." in European Economic Review, 38
(1994). pp. 1185-1216; B. Eichengreen and C. Wyplosz, "The Unstable
EMS." Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, 1 (1993), pp. 51-144.
7 One of us has recently reported evidence to this effect: B.
Eichengreen and T. Bayoumi, "Exchange Rate Volatility and
Intervention: Implications of the Theory of Optimum Currency
Areas." Journal of international Economics, 45 (1998), pp. 191-209.
8 C. Wyplosz, "Capital Controls and Balance of Payments
Crises," Journal of International Money and Finance, 5 (1986), pp.
167-79.
9 B. Eichengreen, A. Rose, and C. Wyplosz, "Contagious
Currency Crises: First Tests," Scandinavian Journal of Economics,
98 (1996), pp. 463-84; B. Eichengreen and A. Rose, "Contagious
Currency Crises: Channels of Conveyance," in Changes in Exchange
Rates in Rapidly Developing Countries, T. Ito and A. Krueger, eds.
Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1998: B. Eichengreen, A. Rose, and
C. Wyplosz. "Contagious Currency Crises," NBER Working Paper
No. 5681, August 1996.
10 R. Glick and A. Rose, "Contagion and Trade: Why Are
Currency Crises Regional?" Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco Working Paper.
11 J. Frankel and A. Rose, "Currency Crashes in Emerging
Markets: An Empirical Treatment," Journal of International
Economics, 41 (November 1996), pp. 351-66.
12 An important exception is A. Demirguc-Kunt and E. Detragiache,
"The Determinants of Banking Crises: Evidence From Developing and
Developed Countries," IMF Working Paper No. 97/107, September 1997.
13 B. Eichengreen and A. Rose, "Staying Afloat When the Wind
Shifts: External Factors and Emerging-Market Banking Crises," NBER
Working Paper No. 6370, January 1998.
14 B. Eichengreen and O. Jeanne, "Currency Crises and
Unemployment: Sterling in 1931," NBER Working Paper No. 6563, May
1998.
15 M. Obstfeld, "Models of Currency Crises With
Self-Fulfilling Features," NBER Working Paper No. 5285, February
1997; also published in European Economic Review, 40 (1996), pp.
1037-47. We claim patrimony (in 1994) of the first- and
second-generation terminology used to distinguish alternative approaches
to modeling currency crises. See B. Eichengreen, A. Rose, and C.
Wyplosz, "Speculative Attacks on Pegged Exchange Rates: An
Empirical Exploration With Special Reference to the European Monetary
System."
16 International Monetary Fund, "Financial Crises:
Characteristics and Indicators of Vulnerability," in World Economic
Outlook, International Monetary Fund, May 1998; G. Kaminsky, S. Lizondo,
and C. Reinhart, "Leading Indicators of Currency Crises,"
Policy Research Working Paper No. 1852, The World Bank, November 1997;
D. Hardy and C. Pazarbasioglu, "Leading Indicators of Banking
Crises: Was Asia Different?" IMF Working Paper No. 98/91, June
1998.
17 A. Rose and L. Svensson, "European Exchange Rate
Credibility Before the Fall."
18 Another study that makes these points is A. Berg and C.
Pattillo, "Are Currency Crises Predictable? A Test,"
unpublished manuscript, International Monetary Fund, July 1998.
19 Indeed, suppose that forecasts of a country's vulnerability
trigger corrective policy actions that then prevent a crisis. In this
case, the model would appear to forecast poorly, as the potential for a
crisis would never be followed by an actual crisis.
Barry Eichengreen is a Research Associate in the NBER's
International Finance and Macroeconomics, International Trade and
Investment, Development of the American Economy, and Monetary Economics
Programs and the John L. Simpson Professor of Economics and Political
Science at the University of California, Berkeley. Andrew K. Rose is the
Acting Director of the NBER's International Finance and
Macroeconomics Program and the B. T. Rocca Professor of Economic
Analysis and Policy at the Haas School of Business at the University of
California, Berkeley. A version of this article is available at
http://haas.berkely.edu/~arose.