Asset pricing.
Campbell, John Y.
Asset pricing - the study of markets for financial assets including
stocks, bonds, foreign currencies, and derivatives - is a field in which
there is an intense and fruitful interaction between empirical and
theoretical research. The work of economists associated with the NBER Asset Pricing Program illustrates this interaction particularly well.
NBER economists have been studying many different phenomena, including
the high rewards that investors have received for holding stocks in
general and "value stocks" in particular, the apparent
predictability of stock and bond returns at long horizons, and unusual
patterns in option prices. In each area, empirical puzzles have
stimulated new thinking about investor behavior and the functioning of
capital markets.
Financial markets are, of course, changing rapidly. NBER economists
have been following these developments, and in some cases have tried to
anticipate or influence them. There has been much research on
international capital markets and the opportunities they present for
risksharing across countries; other work has discussed new types of
securities, including inflation-indexed bonds, which were issued for the
first time by the U.S. Treasury in January 1997.
Cross-Sectional Patterns in Stock Returns
Historically, investors have received handsome rewards for bearing
the risk of investments in equity markets. Economists have found it
difficult to rationalize the size of this "equity premium".(1)
Recent research on individual U.S. stocks has uncovered facts that
make this puzzle even more challenging. First, the average excess
returns on value stocks - stocks whose prices are low relative to their
book values, earnings, or dividends - are even higher than the average
excess returns on stocks in general. Second, there seems to be a
"momentum effect": stocks that have outperformed the market
during the last few months tend to outperform the market during
subsequent months.
There is an active debate about how to interpret these phenomena.
Eugene Fama and Kenneth French have proposed that value stocks deliver
higher average returns because they are riskier.(2) Other NBER
economists have challenged this view. Craig MacKinlay argues that it
requires an implausibly high reward for bearing risk,(3) while Rafael La
Porta, Josef Lakonishok, Andrei Shleifer, and Robert Vishny suggest that
investors underprice value stocks because they are too pessimistic about
the earnings of these companies. They show that as much as one third of
the excess return on value stocks occurs in the few days around earnings
announcements, suggesting that investors are on average favorably
surprised by the earnings of value stocks.(4) Louis Chan, Narasimhan
Jegadeesh, and Lakonishok document a similar tendency for the excess
return on momentum stocks to occur near earnings announcements,
suggesting that for these stocks also investors tend to have incorrect
earnings expectations.(5)
Nicholas Barberis, Shleifer, and Vishny have built an explicit
model of investors' irrational expectations that can generate
excess returns on both momentum stocks and value stocks. In their model,
earnings growth cannot be forecast, so the best forecast of future
earnings is just the current level of earnings. Investors normally
expect earnings to revert to some long-run average level, which leads
them to underprice stocks that have experienced recent earnings growth
(momentum stocks). A series of positive or negative earnings surprises,
however, can lead investors to expect continued positive or negative
earnings growth; this leads them to underprice stocks that have
performed extremely badly (value stocks).(6)
Time-Variation in the Reward for Risk
Financial ratios of stock prices to book values, earnings, or
dividends also are used in time-series studies of the stock market as a
whole. These ratios, along with other variables including yield spreads
between long- and short-term or between low- and high-quality bonds,
have some ability to forecast aggregate stock and bond returns.(7)
Shmuel Kandel and Robert Stambaugh have explored the implications
of this evidence for optimal portfolio choice. Using a Bayesian
framework to allow for uncertainty about the degree of predictability in
returns, they show that an investor with constant risk aversion and a
short investment horizon should try to "time the market,"
adjusting the portfolio share in stocks in response to changes in the
financial ratios that predict returns. In a similar spirit, Luis Viceira
and I have derived the optimal market-timing portfolio strategy for an
investor with constant risk aversion and a long horizon.(8)
This work takes predictable variation in returns as given. Other
NBER research asks where that variation comes from, and whether it can
persist in the face of market-timing responses by investors. John
Cochrane and I, building on the work of George Constantinides, have
argued that typical investors do not have a constant aversion to risk;
instead their risk aversion tends to fall when the economy is strong,
because they judge their well-being by reference to recent standards of
living and feel more comfortable taking risks when their consumption is
well above recent average levels. This "habit-formation" model
implies that investors do not try to profit from predictable variation
in returns because it is during periods of unusually low stock returns
that investors are unusually willing to take on risk.(9) Jiang Wang has
explored the possibility that different investors have different levels
of risk aversion; when they trade with one another, the equilibrium
reward for bearing risk can vary over time.(10)
Shleifer and Vishny have pointed out that even when there is no
equilibrium justification for time-variation in stock returns, so that
the time-variation represents mispricing of stocks, it may be difficult
for rational speculators to trade aggressively enough to eliminate the
mispricing. This is particularly true when an initial pricing error
increases; then rational speculators who have bet on a correction of the
error lose money and are forced to the sidelines. Thus stabilizing
speculation tends to be weakest precisely when mispricing is most
severe.(11)
In a study of the foreign exchange market, Blake LeBaron has shown
that intervention by monetary authorities is one possible source of
mispricing. He finds that technical trading rules produce profits only
in periods of intervention, when monetary authorities are trading to
influence exchange rates and are willing to lose money in pursuit of
their objectives.(12)
Option Prices, Changing Volatility, and Market Microstructure
Option markets offer economists a fascinating look at
investors' expectations. By combining different options on a given
underlying security, it is possible to construct a derivative security that pays off only if the underlying price is in a particular narrow
range: for example, only if the S&P 500 index is between 800 and 801
on a particular date in the future. Thus option prices can reveal the
probabilities (adjusted for risk) that investors place on each possible
level of the S&P 500 index.
Yacine Ait-Sahalia and Andrew Lo have developed a nonparametric
econometric method for estimating risk-adjusted probabilities. They show
that recent prices for S&P 500 index options imply high
risk-adjusted probabilities of a large decline in the S&P 500
index.(13) David Bates has compared two possible explanations for this
finding. Investors could anticipate that a decline in stock prices would
increase volatility, so that over several months a large decline in the
market is more likely than an equally large increase; or they could fear
a "crash," an instantaneous large drop in the market. Because
the risk-adjusted probabilities of a large decline in the index are high
even for very short-term options, Bates concludes that investors do
indeed fear a stock market crash.(14)
Other researchers have studied changing volatility, a pervasive
phenomenon in stock and bond markets that shifts the risk-adjusted
probability distributions implied by option prices. Torben Andersen and
Tim Bollerslev have argued that volatility follows a complex time-series
process; there are short-lived bursts of volatility within the trading
day, but there are also highly persistent movements in volatility that
affect asset markets for several months.(15) Robert Engle and Joshua
Rosenberg, and Bernard Dumas, Jeff Fleming, and Robert Whaley, have
shown how models of changing volatility can be used to explain the
behavior of option prices.(16)
Studies of volatility within the trading day lead naturally to a
new frontier in financial economics, the study of transaction-level
data. In recent years, data have become available on all trades and
quotes for listed and some over-the-counter U.S. stocks. These data are
stimulating the development of new econometric methods,(17) and they
make it possible to study the properties of alternative systems for
trading stocks and other assets.(18) A new "Market Microstructure
Research Group" will meet for the first time at the 1997 NBER
Summer Institute to provide a forum for empirical research in this area.
Diversification, Risk-Sharing, and New Financial Markets
A striking fact about international financial markets is that
investors tend to concentrate heavily in the stocks and bonds of their
own country. This "home bias" is diminishing only slowly, and
it is costly because investors give up the opportunity to diversify
internationally.(19)
One factor that may contribute to home bias is that investors are
better informed about assets in their own country than about foreign
assets. Consistent with this explanation, Jun-Koo Kang and Rene Stulz
have shown that foreign investors in Japan tend to concentrate in large
stocks, which presumably are better-known overseas; while Jeffrey
Frankel and Sergio Schmukler have shown that Mexican stock prices
declined more rapidly in the peso crisis of December 1994 than did
prices of Mexican closed-end funds traded in the United States,
suggesting that Mexican investors were better-informed than U.S.
investors.(20)
In a series of papers, Robert Shiller has argued that unexploited
opportunities for diversification justify the establishment of new
financial markets. Shiller and Stefano Athanasoulis, Shiller and Ryan
Schneider, and Shiller and Allan Weiss have proposed securities that
could be used to trade international income risk, occupational income
risk, and real estate price risk, respectively.(21)
While these markets do not yet exist, the U.S. Treasury has
recently created a potentially important new market by issuing
inflation-indexed bonds. Shiller and I have summarized the arguments
that many economists have made in favor of indexing bonds and other
contracts to inflation, while David Barr and I have studied the U.K.
experience with inflation-indexed bonds.(22) Niko Canner, N. Gregory
Mankiw, and David Weil have criticized the conventional wisdom that
conservative investors should hold bonds rather than stocks; they point
out that nominal bonds are risky in real terms. Inflation-indexed bonds
offer stable real returns and thus should appeal to conservative
investors with long horizons.(23)
1 See J. Y. Campbell, "Consumption and the Stock Market:
Interpreting International Evidence," NBER Working Paper No. 5610,
June 1996, for a survey. WN. Goetzmann and P. Jorion, "A Century of
Global Stock Markets," NBER Working Paper No. 5901, January 1997,
cautions that equity returns may be overstated by looking only at
successful stock markets.
2 E.F. Fama and K.R. French, "Common Risk Factors in the
Returns on Stocks and Bonds," Journal of Financial Economics 33,
3-56.
3 A. C. MacKinlay, "Multifactor Models do not Explain
Deviations from the CAPM," Journal of Financial Economics 38, 3-28,
1995.
4 R. La Porta, J. Lakonishok, A. Shleifer, and R.W. Vishny,
"Good News for Value Stocks: Further Evidence on Market
Efficiency," NBER Working Paper No. 5311, October 1995.
5 L.K.C. Chan, N. Jegadeesh, and J. Lakonishok, "Momentum
Strategies," NBER Working Paper No. 5375, December 1995.
6 N. Barberis, A. Shleifer, and R. W. Vishny, "A Model of
Investor Sentiment," NBER Working Paper No. 5926, February 1997.
7 A. W. Lo and A.C. MacKinlay, "Maximizing Predictability in
the Stock and Bond Markets," NBER Working Paper No. 5027, February
1995, documents predictability for the aggregate U.S. market and for
selected portfolios of U.S. stocks. W.E. Ferson and C.R. Harvey,
"Fundamental Determinants of National Equity Market Returns: A
Perspective on Conditional Asset Pricing," NBER Working Paper No.
5860, December 1996, presents similar evidence for stock portfolios from
different countries. C. Engel, "The Forward Discount Anomaly and
the Risk Premium: A Survey of Recent Evidence," NBER Reprint No.
1089, November 1996, and Journal of Empirical Finance 3, 123-192, 1996,
reviews evidence for predictability in international bond markets.
8 S. Kandel and R.E Stambaugh, "On the Predictability of Stock
Returns: An Asset-Allocation Perspective," NBER Working Paper No.
4997, January 1995, and J. Y. Campbell and L. Viceira, "Consumption
and Portfolio Decisions when Expected Returns are Time Varying,"
NBER Working Paper No. 5857, December 1996.
9 G. Constantinides, "Habit Formation: A Resolution of the
Equity Premium Puzzle,"Journal of Political Economy 98, 519-543,
1990, and J. Y. Campbell and J.H. Cochrane, "By Force of Habit: A
Consumption-based Explanation of Aggregate Stock Market Behavior,"
NBER Working Paper No. 4995, January 1995. See also M. Boldrin, L.J.
Christiano, and J.D.M. Fisher, "Asset Pricing Lessons for Modeling
Business Cycles," NBER Working Paper No. 5262, September 1995.
10 J. Wang, "The Term Structure of Interest Rates in a Pure
Exchange Economy with Heterogeneous Investors," NBER Working Paper
No. 5172, July 1995.
11 A. Shleifer and R.W. Vishny, "The Limits of
Arbitrage," NBER Working Paper No. 5167, July 1995.
12 B. LeBaron, "Technical Trading Rule Profitability and
Foreign Exchange Intervention," NBER Working Paper No. 5505, March
1996.
13 Y. Ait-Sahalia and A. W. Lo, "Nonparametric Estimation of
State-Price Densities Implicit in Financial Asset Prices," NBER
Working Paper No. 5351, November 1995. Ait-Sahalia has taken a similar
nonparametric approach to interest-rate derivatives in
"Nonparametric Pricing of Interest Rate Derivative Securities," NBER Working Paper No. 5345, November 1995.
14 D.S. Bates, "Testing Option Pricing Models," NBER
Working Paper No. 5129, May 1995, and "Post-'87 Crash Fears in
S&P 500 Futures Options," NBER Working Paper No. 5894, January
1997.
15 T.G. Andersen and T. Bollerslev, "Heterogeneous Information
Arrivals and Return Volatility Dynamics: Uncovering the Long Run in High
Frequency Returns," NBER Working Paper No. 5752, September 1996,
and "DM-Dollar Volatility: Intraday Activity Patterns,
Macroeconomic Announcements, and Longer Run Dependencies," NBER
Working Paper No. 5783, October 1996.
16 R.F. Engle and J. V. Rosenberg, "Hedging Options in a GARCH Environment: Testing the Term Structure of Stochastic Volatility
Models," NBER Working Paper No. 4958, December 1994, and
"GARCH Gamma," NBER Working Paper No. 5128, May 1995, and B.
Dumas, J. Fleming, and R.E. Whaley, "Implied Volatility Functions:
Empirical Tests," NBER Working Paper No. 5500, March 1996.
17 R.F. Engle and J. R. Russell, "Forecasting Transaction
Rates: The Autoregressive Conditional Duration Model," NBER Working
Paper No. 4966, December 1994, and R.F. Engle, "The Econometrics of
Ultra-High Frequency Data," NBER Working Paper No. 5816, November
1996.
18 The Industrial Organization and Regulation of the Securities
Industry, A.W. Lo ed., Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1996,
contains several papers on this topic.
19 K.K. Lewis, "What Can Explain the Apparent Lack of
International Consumption Risk Sharing?", NBER Working Paper No.
5203, August 1995, and "Consumption, Stock Returns, and the Gains
from International Risk Sharing," NBER Working Paper No. 5410,
January 1996, explore some possible explanations for the home bias
puzzle and compare alternative measures of the welfare cost of home
bias. G. Bekaert and M. S. Urias, "Diversification, Integration,
and Emerging Market Closed-End Funds," NBER Reprint No. 2066,
September 1996, and Journal of Finance 51, 835-869, July 1996, shows how
closed-end funds that hold shares in emerging markets can be used for
international diversification.
20 J.-K. Kang and R.M. Stulz, "Why Is There a Home Bias? An
Analysis of Foreign Portfolio Equity Ownership in Japan," NBER
Working Paper No. 5166, July 1995, and J. A. Frankel and S.L. Schmukler,
"Country Fund Discounts, Asymmetric Information, and the Mexican
Crisis of 1994: Did Local Residents Turn Pessimistic Before
International Investors?", NBER Working Paper No. 5714, August
1996.
21 R.J. Shiller and S. Athanasoulis, "World Income Components:
Measuring and Exploiting International Risk Sharing Opportunities,"
NBER Working Paper No. 5095, April 1995; R.J. Shiller and R. Schneider,
"Labor Market Indices Designed for Use in Contracts Promoting
Income Risk Management," NBER Working Paper No. 5254, September
1995; and R.J. Shiller and A.N. Weiss, "Home Equity
Insurance," NBER Working Paper No. 4830, August 1994.
22 J. Y. Campbell and R.J. Shiller, "A Scorecard for Indexed
Government Debt," NBER Macroeconomics Annual 11, 155-197, 1996, and
D.G. Barr and J. Y. Campbell, "Inflation, Real Interest Rates, and
the Bond Market: A Study of UK Nominal and Index-Linked Government Bond
Prices," NBER Working Paper No 5821, November 1996.
23 N. Canner, N.G. Mankiw, and D.N. Weil "An Asset Allocation Puzzle," NBER Working Paper No. 4857, September 1994.
John Y. Campbell is director of the NBER's Program on Asset
Pricing and a professor of economics at Harvard University.