Economic analysis of law.
Bebchuk, Lucian A.
My general interest is in using economics to analyze the effects of
legal rules and institutions. In this article, I describe my current and
recent work in the economics of four areas in which legal rules and
institutions play a major role: corporate control and structure,
bankruptcy, contracts, and litigation and settlement.
Corporate Control and Structure
While much of my earlier work in corporate control focused on
takeover bids for companies with dispersed shareholders, my more recent
research has focused on companies in which there is a controlling
shareholder. In many public companies - both in the United States and
(even more so) in other countries - a significant number of shares are
concentrated in the hands of a controlling shareholder.(1)
One part of my research has focused on the decisions of controllers
about selling their control blocks. In a recent article, I have shown
that such decisions often might be distorted.(2) The efficiency costs
produced by these distortions should be regarded as arising from having
a controlling shareholder structure.
A central feature of the model of control transfers that I have
developed is that controllers may differ from each other in two
respects: their ability to manage and produce value; and their ability
to capture private benefits of control. My analysis shows that, under
the existing regime in the United States, inefficient transfers may take
place; this will happen when the potential new controller has less
managerial ability but a sufficiently greater ability to capture private
benefits than the previous controller. Also under the existing regime,
some efficient transfers may not take place; this will happen if the
potential new controller, although better able to manage the company,
has a sufficiently lower ability to capture private benefits.
My analysis also examined control transfers under the equal
opportunity rule that prevails in many other countries. Under this rule,
minority shareholders are entitled to participate in the transaction on
the same terms as the control seller. My analysis shows that adopting
the equal opportunity rule would prevent all inefficient transfers, but
also would prevent a wider range of efficient transfers. Finally, the
analysis has identified conditions under which adding the equal
opportunity rule would and would not be efficient overall; for example,
adopting the equal opportunity rule would produce an efficiency loss
overall if existing and new controllers draw their characteristics from
the same distributions.
In a related paper, Jesse Fried and I study the decisions of
controllers on whether to effect a freezeout.(3) In a corporate
freezeout, which is allowed under U.S. rules, a controller can take the
shares of the minority shareholders and provide them instead with
consideration exceeding the value of those shares as appraised by the
court. Our model shows that decisions on whether to effect a freezeout
may be distorted, thus producing another efficiency cost arising from
having a controlling shareholder structure. The analysis identifies
conditions under which efficient freezeouts might not take place or
inefficient freezeouts might take place. We use this model to analyze
how alternative legal rules perform with respect to the objectives of
facilitating efficient freezeouts and discouraging inefficient ones.
These two projects take as given the existence of control blocks.
Another part of my research examines the factors that determine the
initial ownership structure. In joint work, Luigi Zingales and I(4)
analyze the choice that initial owners make between retaining a complete
ownership structure and creating a controlling shareholder structure by
selling some shares to the public. We show that, in this choice, private
and social optimality might diverge.
The source of this potential divergence is an externality. The
initial choice of ownership structure will have important effects on
both the initial shareholders and the potential future buyers of
control. Since the IPO price will reflect the effects of the choice on
the initial shareholders, the initial owner will internalize these
effects fully. Since potential future buyers are not "at the
table" at the time of the IPO, however, the initial owner will not
take into account the effect of the ownership structure on them. Our
analysis identifies three ways in which the initial choice of ownership
structure can affect these future buyers.
Having identified a possible distortion, we turn to identifying
conditions under which the distortion leads to excessive or suboptimal incidence of controlling shareholder structures. Our analysis has
normative implications for the regulation of sale of control
transactions and of public offerings of minority shares. Among its
positive implications, our analysis suggests reasons for the substantial
differences in the incidence of control blocks across different
countries.
Bankruptcy
Much of my initial work on bankruptcy concerns the ex post
distribution of value in corporate bankruptcy. In a joint article,
Howard Chang and I develop a bargaining model that explains why, under
the existing corporate reorganization regime, equityholders are able to
obtain value even when the creditors are not paid in full.(5) This model
can help to explain the empirical evidence about the commonality of such
deviations from the absolute priority of debt over equity.
In another article, I put forward a proposal for dividing the
reorganization pie in a way that would eliminate deviations from
absolute priority.(6) Unlike the existing bargaining-based method for
reorganizations, the method that I propose involves no bargaining, nor
does it require that the value of the reorganized company be identified.
Under this method, the participants in a reorganization would receive a
set of options with respect to the securities of the reorganized
company. These options can be designed so that, whatever the
reorganization value, the participants ultimately will all receive the
value to which they are entitled according to the absolute priority
standard.
My proposed "options" method of corporate reorganization
has received many and varied reactions. Some have endorsed it (Aghion,
Hart, and Moore, for example, have used it as the basis for the
distribution of the reorganization value in their proposal on corporate
reorganizations(7)), while others have expressed various criticisms and
concerns. To address the issues raised, I have been working on a
follow-up project that will explore how the options approach can and
should deal with the various problems that commentators have raised with
respect to it.
In developing the options method, my premise has been, as that of
much of the literature on bankruptcy reform, that it is desirable to
distribute the bankruptcy value in accordance with the absolute priority
principle. The problem that I sought to solve was just how to produce
such a distribution, given that the bankruptcy value is not verifiable
by courts. But an important question that might be raised is what the
desirable distribution is. Of course, in choosing the bankruptcy
distribution, it is important to consider the ex ante effects of
alternative distributions. Some of my recent work seeks to contribute to
the understanding of these ex ante effects.
In a recent article, Jesse Fried and I(8) analyze the ex ante
effects of providing secured claims with full bankruptcy priority over
unsecured claims. We show that, contrary to the conventional wisdom,
providing such full priority has certain undesirable ex ante effects. In
particular, full priority of secured claims leads to excessive use of
security interests, distorts the choice between security interests and
covenants, and produces suboptimal precautions against tort liability,
use of covenants, and monitoring by secured creditors. Accordingly, we
have put forward alternative rules for partial priority of secured
claims, and we have analyzed the efficiency costs and benefits involved
in the adoption of a partial priority regime.
In two other working papers, I analyze some of the ex ante effects
of providing debtholders with absolute priority over equityholders. In
one, I show that deviations from such absolute priority of debt over
equity might have an adverse effect on the moral hazard problem between
debt and equity.(9) In particular, such deviations might increase the
excessive incentive that equityholders have to prefer risky projects
over safe ones, to make dividend distributions, and to engage in claim
dilution by issuing extra debt.
In the second paper, Randy Picker and I analyze certain positive ex
ante effects of deviations from the absolute priority of debt over
equity.(10) Such deviations might have a positive effect on those
decisions by managers-owners that determine the extent to which a
firm's managers have an advantage over others in operating the
firm's assets. Without any such deviations, managers will entrench themselves by over-investment in assets that require their unique
skills, and they also will under-invest in firm-specific human capital.
Allowing ex post deviations from absolute priority decreases the
severity of these two problems.
Contracts
In contract law, my interest is in understanding how the rules can
affect the various aspects of the contracting parties' behavior. In
an article published several years ago, Steven Shavell and I showed that
contractual rules might have an effect on informational transfer between
the contracting parties.(11) In analyzing the optimal default rule in a
contractual setting, models generally had taken the information held by
the contracting parties to be given. However, as our model suggested
(and as was suggested by Ayres and Gertner in an article published at
the same time(12)), the choice of an appropriate default rule might lead
to transfers of information between the contracting parties and thus
might reduce informational asymmetries between them. Our model also has
analyzed when inducing such informational transfers would and would not
be socially optimal.
In a recent paper Omri Ben-Shahar and I(13) examine the effects of
legal rules on pre-contractual reliance. During contractual
negotiations, but before entering a contract, parties might make
reliance expenditures - expenditures that would increase the surplus
should a contract be made but would be wasted otherwise. In the absence
of any pre-contractual liability, parties' reliance will be
socially suboptimal. The focus of our model is on analyzing whether and
how rules could be designed to induce optimal reliance decisions. We
also study the effects of the rules governing pre-contractual liability
on parties' decisions whether to enter into contractual
negotiations.
In another recent working paper Ivan P'ng and I(14) analyze
the effect of remedies for breach in those cases in which breach is not
deliberate (a situation that has already received comprehensive
treatment) but rather inadvertent. We analyze the effects of alternative
remedies on parties' decisions with respect to taking precautions
against inadvertent breach and with respect to investment in reliance on
contractual performance.
Litigation and Settlement
About a decade ago, I participated in initiating game-theoretic
analysis of litigation and settlement decisions. A large literature has
grown since then, and my 1984 model of pre-trial bargaining under
imperfect information has been used by many of the subsequent
papers.(15) I have remained very interested in this area and am
currently working on two subjects within it.
One subject is the credibility of threats to sue. In
negative-expected-value (NEV) suits, the expected litigation costs
exceed the expected judgment. While it is widely believed that
plaintiffs with NEV suits are often able to get something from the
defendant, the question is what enables such potential plaintiffs to
have a credible threat and to succeed in extracting value.
One possible explanation for the success of such suits, which I
advanced in an early article on the subject, is rooted in the existence
of imperfect information on the defendant's side.(16) My more
recent work, however, has examined the numerous situations in which the
plaintiff is known to have an NEV suit.(17) In an article published last
year and in a subsequent paper, I developed a model that can explain why
plaintiffs might have a credible threat in such situations.
My model is based on the recognition that litigation costs are
generally not incurred all at once but rather over time, with bargaining
possibly taking place at various points throughout the litigation
process. This divisibility of the litigation process plays a critical
strategic role. Indeed, I demonstrate that greater divisibility of
litigation costs can never hurt - and may help - the plaintiff's
strategic position. Because of this effect of divisibility, plaintiffs
have credible threats in a much wider set of cases - including numerous
small-stake cases - than has been suggested by the prior economic
analysis of the subject.
My analysis also attempts to identify the conditions under which a
plaintiff with an NEV suit will succeed in extracting a settlement. In
particular, my work shows how the credibility of such threats is shaped
both by the relative sizes of the parties' litigation costs and by
the ways in which the parties' litigation costs are expected to be
distributed over time.
Second, I am working on an analysis of the terms of settlement.
Much of the literature on settlement has focused on the factors
determining its likelihood. The likelihood of settlement is of interest
to economists, of course, since it determines the extent to which the
deadweight costs of litigation will be incurred. In analyzing the effect
of the law on behavior, however, the terms of settlement are also of
great importance. And some of my current research concerns how these
terms are effected by various procedural, institutional, and contractual
arrangements.
In a recent paper, I analyze the effect of fee-shifting rules on
the terms of settlement.(18) For each of the main fee-shifting rules,
the analysis examines whether the rule will make settlement terms more
favorable to the plaintiff or the defendant - and also whether the rule
will move these terms closer to, or further away from, the expected
judgment.
In another recent paper, Howard Chang and I model the effects of
offer-of-settlement rules on the terms of settlement.(19) Under such
rules, if a party to a lawsuit makes a formal offer to settle and the
offer is rejected, then this offer will become part of the record in the
case and the allocation of litigation costs will depend on how the
judgment in the case compares with this offer. Our model makes it
possible to derive the expected settlement amount under any given
offer-of-settlement rule. Our analysis also shows how such a rule can be
designed, if this is deemed desirable, to eliminate the bargaining
disadvantage that a party with higher litigation costs would have
otherwise.
Finally, in a recent article Andrew Guzman and I(20) analyze the
strategic role that fee arrangements between lawyers and clients can
play in settlement negotiations. Compared with an hourly fee
arrangement, contingent fee arrangements strengthen the bargaining
position of the side employing them, and thus make the terms of
settlement more favorable to this party.
1 See M. Barclay and C. Holderness, "Private Benefits from
Control of Public Corporations," Journal of Financial Economics 25,
(1989), pp. 371-95.
2 See L. Bebchuk, "Efficient and Inefficient Sales of
Corporate ControL" NBER Reprint No. 2012, October 1995, and
Quarterly Journal of Economics 109, (1994), pp. 957-93.
3 See L. Bebchuk and J. Fried, "Efficient and Inefficient
Freezeouts of Minority Shareholders," mimeo, Harvard Law School (1997).
4 See L. Bebchuk and L. Zingales, "Corporate Ownership
Structures: Private versus Social Optimality," NBER Working Paper
No. 5584, May 1996.
5 See L. Bebchuk and H. Chang, "Bargaining and the Division of
Value in Corporate Reorganization," Journal of Law, Economics, and
Organization 8, (1992), pp. 253- 79.
6 See L. Bebchuk, "A New Approach to Corporate
Reorganization," Harvard Law Review 101, (1988), pp. 775-804.
7 See P. Aghion, O. Hart, and J. Moore, "The Economics of
Bankruptcy Reform," Journal of Law, Economics, and Organization 8,
(1992), pp. 523-546.
8 See L. Bebchuk and J. Fried, "The Uneasy Case for the
Priority of Secured Claims in Bankruptcy," The Yale Law Journal
105, (1996), pp. 857-934.
9 See L. Bebchuk, "On the Effects of Deviations from Absolute
Priority on Ex Ante Corporate Decisions," mimeo, Harvard Law School
(1996).
10 See L. Bebchuk and R. Picker, "Bankruptcy Rules, Managerial
Entrenchment, and Firm-Specific Human Capital," forthcoming in the
Journal of Law and Economics.
11 See L. Bebchuk and S. Shavell, "Information and the Scope
of Liability for Breach of Contract: The Rule of Hadley v.
Baxendale,"Journal of Law, Economics, and Organization 7, (1991),
pp. 284-12.
12 See I. Ayres and R. Gertner, "Filling Gaps in Incomplete
Contracts: An Economic Theory of Default Rules,"Yale Law Journal
99, (1989), pp. 87-130.
13 See L. Bebchuk and O. Ben-Shahar, "Pre-Contractual
Reliance," mimeo, Harvard Law School (1996).
14 See L. Bebchuk and L P'ng, "Damage Measures for
Inadvertent Breach of Contract," mimeo, Harvard Law School (1996).
15 See L. Bebchuk, "Litigation and Settlement under Imperfect
Information," Rand Journal of Economics 15, (1984), pp. 404-15.
16 See L. Bebchuk, "Suing Solely to Extract a Settlement
Offer," Journal of Legal Studies 17, (1988), pp. 437-50.
17 See L. Bebchuk, "A New Theory Concerning the Credibility
and Success of Threats to Sue," Journal of Legal Studies 25,
(1996), pp. 1-26; L. Bebchuk, "On Divisibility and Credibility: the
Effects of the Distribution of Litigation Costs over Time on the
Credibility of Threats to Sue," mimeo, Harvard Law School (1996).
18 See L. Bebchuk, "The Effect of Fee-Shifting Rules on
Settlement Terms," Harvard Law School, Discussion Paper No. 202
(1996).
19 See L. Bebchuk and H. Chang, "The Effect-of-Settlement
Rules on the Terms of Settlements," mimeo, Harvard Law School
(1997).
20 See L. Bebchuk and A. Guzman, "How Would You Like to Pay
for That?", Harvard Negotiation Law Review 1, (1996), pp. 53-63.
Lucian A. Bebchuk is a research associate in the NBER's
Program in Law and Economics and a professor at Harvard Law School. His
profile appears later in this issue.