The economics of cities.
Glaeser, Edward L.
The fundamental questions of urban economics are: Why do cities
exist~ How does density - or agglomeration - affect people and firms?
Why do some cities flourish and others decay? Why are social pathologies
often more extreme in cities?
These questions address how spillovers actually operate. If the
effects of agglomeration and local spillovers lie behind phenomena as
important as economic growth, business cycles, and the formation of
human capital (as many researchers now suspect), then urban economics
has a special role to play in helping us to understand how these
spillovers work in their rawest form. My work tries to use the evidence
from cities both to understand urban density itself and to shed light on
other topics that are hopefully of interest to the broader economics
community.
The Causes and Extent of Agglomeration Economies
Cities now exist for three primary reasons: 1) they reduce transport
costs for goods; 2) they eliminate the space between people; and 3)
cities facilitate a faster flow of ideas. More precisely, dense
agglomeration reduces the transport costs for goods, people, and ideas.
These three different sources of "agglomeration economies"
have equivalents in other literatures. For example, the role of reduced
transport costs for goods in the formation of cities is similar to the
idea that the comovement of output over the business cycle occurs
because a productivity shock to one firm increases demand for other
firms.
Albert Ades and I(1) measure causes of urban agglomeration using
cross-county evidence by looking at the extent to which countries'
populations are concentrated in a single city. We find that population
is more spread out in countries where transport costs for physical goods
are lower (measured by development of internal transport networks), and
when external trade is smaller (which Paul Krugman and Raul Livas(2)
argue is a further implication of transport cost models of urban
agglomeration). While transport costs do matter, our results suggest
that political factors, for example dictatorship and instability, are
far more important in explaining which countries have concentration in a
single city. For example, dictatorships have 50 percent more of the
population in their largest cities than do stable democracies. When
political systems are not stable and democratic, politicians respond to
the rent-seeking activities of people who live in their cities by
transferring rents to those cities, and population flows follow these
rents.
To understand why people in the United States may be more productive
in cities, David Mare and I(3) examine why workers are paid
substantially higher wages in cities. The urban wage premium persists
even after we control for a full battery of individual factors
(education, race, age), job-related factors (industry and occupation
dummies), and for differential selection into cities. Unless workers in
cities were more productive, firms would leave. Thus, even though real
wages seem to be constant over space (as evidence on real prices suggest
that they are), we believe that there is a productivity premium in
cities.
Surprisingly, and counter to many theories of agglomeration, the
urban wage premium does not immediately accrue to workers who come to
the city, and it does not disappear immediately (or at all) for workers
who leave the city. Instead, there appears to be a slow but steady
increase in the rate of wage growth for workers in cities relative to
workers outside cities (the urban wage premium is also higher among
older workers). One possible interpretation is that the urban wage
premium works through faster skill accumulation in cities which accrues
over time, and stays with workers when they leave cities. I(4) provide a
theoretical analysis of this view and some suggestive evidence that
shows that the individuals who choose to live in big cities are drawn
disproportionately from groups who would presumably value the skill
accumulation role of cities (that is, young, college educated persons).
Hedi Kallal, Jose Scheinkman, Andrei Shleifer, and I(5) examine the
connection between local area characteristics and the growth of
particular "city-industries" (for example steel in Detroit or
retail trade in New York). We find that employment growth is faster in
city industries that are highly competitive (where competition is the
number of firms relative to total employment), not concentrated (where
concentration is measured by the share of the city-industry in the total
city's employment), and in diverse cities (where diversity is
measured by employment concentration of the city in its largest
industries). We interpret these findings as a test of growth theories;
they may imply that diversity and competition, not industrial
concentration, inculcate growth, presumably through the generation of
new ideas.
Scheinkman, Shleifer, and I(6) extend this work and examine the
connection between city-level characteristics, population growth, and
income growth. Population growth and income growth have moved together
at the city level over the past 40 years, and all of our results hold
for either of these variables. Initial levels of schooling predict later
growth. The connection between schooling and growth has increased since
1970, perhaps because the rise in returns to skill has made the
intellectual spillovers that are available in high human capital cities
more important. Cities with high unemployment levels that were
concentrated in manufacturing have seen a substantial decline in both
manufacturing and non-manufacturing employment. Few attributes of the
public bundle (that is, the level of taxation, or types of spending)
seem to influence the growth of particular cities.
Jess Gaspar and I(7) ask whether information technology will make
cities obsolete. Improvements in telecommunications will shift time away
from face-to-face contacts towards electronic contacts within a
relationship, but these improvements also increase the overall number of
relationships, and many of these new relationships also will involve
face-to-face contact. The theoretical effect of telecommunications on
cities is ambiguous. Empirically, we find that across countries and
across areas within countries, urbanization and telephone usage go
together, even after controlling for costs and income. Telephone contact
is higher between regions that are close spatially. Business travel
(another form of face-to-face contact) has soared as information
technology has improved. Silicon Valley, which should have the best
access to the newest telecommunications technology, is the textbook example of geographic concentration of industry. Still, there
doesn't seem to be persuasive evidence that the internet will
destroy the city.(8)
Glenn Ellison and I(9) attempt to measure agglomeration economies by
developing an index of geographic concentration that measures the degree
of concentration of particular industries. This index takes the overall
concentration of manufacturing employment as given and corrects for the
fact that the lumpiness of manufacturing will suggest geographic
concentration whenever returns to scale dictate that production take
place in a few large plants. We find that the famed geographic clusters
of particular industries are exceptions rather than rules. While the
famous examples are all quite observable in the data, the mass of
industries display a statistically significant level of industrial
concentration that appears (to us at least) to be relatively mild
economically. The fact that industrial clusters appear to be relatively
rare also can be interpreted as suggesting that many of the most
important agglomeration economies occur across, rather than within,
industries.
Guy Dumais, Ellison, and I(10) extend this work and use the
Longitudinal Research Database (which provides almost complete
information on every manufacturing industry in the United States) to
examine the dynamic components of geographic concentration. We find a
large amount of movement of particular industries across space (even
among the most concentrated industries) which casts doubt on the general
applicability of anecdotes used by theorists to suggest that geographic
location often is determined by decades-old happenstance. The
longitudinal research database also suggests that the geographic
concentration of manufacturing is a delicate balance of the creation of
new manufacturing plants, the expansion and contraction of pre-existing
plants, and plant closures. Plant openings occur away from pre-existing
industrial centers and act to lower geographic concentration. Plant
closures act to reinforce concentration, because they are much more
likely away from pre-existing industrial centers (even after controlling
for the fact that these peripheral areas are likelier to have newer
plants). We also find that while industries that share input-output
relationships locate together, these effects are small. The dominant
force in determining which manufacturing industries locate together is
that they hire the same kinds of workers.
Urban Pathologies
American cities are not just technological wonderlands. Many urban
centers face extreme poverty, crime, and other social problems.
Fundamentally, the social problems of cities appear to be the result of
many of the same agglomeration economies that fuel urban productivity.
The same intellectual spillovers that make Silicon Valley also may lead
to the transmission of ideas (or norms) about crime within the inner
city.
Bruce Sacerdote and I(11) ask "Why is there more crime in
cities?" The connection between city size and crime rates is
pervasive and longstanding. We find that only 15 percent of the
connection between city size and crime appears to come from lower
probability of arrest in cities, and 25 percent appears related to
higher financial returns from criminal activity in cities. Almost 50
percent of the urban crime premium is related to the fact that the
disadvantaged (particularly female heads of household) end up in cities.
The connection between growing up with one parent and crime is not
nearly as strong as the connection between living in areas with large
numbers of single parents and the level of crime. While this difference
could be explained by omitted area-level variables that are correlated with single-parent families, it may also come from spillovers within
those areas. Having one parent may not induce a child to become a
criminal, but growing up in an area where all one's peers all have
missing parents may create peer effects that lead to crime. Sacerdote,
Scheinkman, and I(12) create a methodology for measuring the extent of
social interaction based on a simple local interactions model. We find
large amounts of social interaction in criminal behavior, and we believe
that these social interactions explain the wide diversity of crime rates
across space.
To further examine the role of local spillover effects, David Cutler and I ask whether ghettos are good or bad.(13) We document that young
African-Americans growing up in segregated areas are more likely to be
unemployed or idle (that is, neither at work nor in school), or to have
a child out of wedlock, and are less likely to graduate from high
school, than young African-Americans who grow up in less segregated
areas. This is true even after controlling for city-specific
characteristics and looking at the difference between white and
African-American outcomes within cities. Furthermore, we use a variety
of instruments (including number of governments and topographical
barriers) in order to avoid the problem that individuals choose their
neighborhoods. All of our results essentially confirm the striking
negative effect of segregation on African-American outcomes in 1990. We
suspect that the mechanism linking racial segregation with poor outcomes
for non-whites is not physical access to jobs, but rather the
intellectual and social isolation of disadvantaged communities which
then works against the acquisition of human capital among youth.
Cutler, Jakob Vigdor, and I examine the roots of segregation and its
current history.(14) We find that segregation rose during every decade
between 1890 and 1960, but that it has declined quite substantially in
the twenty years since 1970. Segregation cannot be explained by many
city-level characteristics except for city size: bigger cities are
generally more segregated. We use housing prices and survey evidence to
determine the extent to which segregation occurs: because of a greater
willingness among whites to pay to live in white neighborhoods (in which
case, whites should be paying more in more segregated cities) or;
because of "collective action racism," where whites collude to
force blacks to live in particular neighborhoods (in which case, we
would expect African-Americans to be paying more to live in more
segregated cities). We find that in 1940, segregation was driven
primarily by collective action racism (supported by legal devises
including restrictive covenants), but that by 1990, the remaining
segregation is driven primarily by white tastes for white neighborhoods.
Denise DiPasquale and I examine a final form of urban pathology:
riots.(15) We find a strong connection between urbanization and rioting
across countries, particularly among countries that are ethnically
fragmented. Using a sample of race riots in the 1960s, we find regular
evidence for basic economic hypotheses about rioting (higher
unemployment increases rioting; police resources decrease rioting) and
little evidence for more sociological hypotheses about relative poverty
and deprivation. We do find, however, that ethnic diversity is deeply
linked to conflict, both in the United States and around the world. The
major role of ethnicity requires models that move beyond the cost of
punishment and the opportunity cost of time into understanding the
far-reaching effects of ethnic identity.
Some of my work has focused on policy responses to these problems.
One paper published in 1996 suggests that property taxes provide better
incentives for revenue maximizing local governments who would choose to
maximize property values in an attempt to maximize total revenues.(16)
In a forthcoming paper, I argue that indexing transfer payments to local
price levels could lead to pernicious results because of migration
effects.(17) In a work on my own(18) and with Erzo Luttmer,(19) I
consider the effects of rent control on misallocating housing across
consumers. Overall, though, my primary focus has been on the issues in
the study of urban economies, not on the appropriate government response
to these economies.
Conclusion
Cities are unique combinations of the best and worst features of
modern society. Agglomeration effects appear to create faster learning
and greater productivity, but they also seem to further crime, riots,
segregation and ghetto poverty. Further research on cities can play a
role in helping us to both understand how to improve urban areas and how
agglomeration economies actually operate.
1 A.F. Ades and E.L. Glaeser, "Trade and Circuses: Explaining
Urban Giants," Quarterly Journal of Economics 1995, pp. 195-228.
2 P. Krugman and R. Liras, "Trade Policy and the Third World
Metropolis," NBER Working Paper No. 4238, December 1992.
3 E.L. Glaeser and D.C. Mare, "Cities and Skills," Hoover
Institution Working Paper E-94-11, 1994.
4 E.L. Glaeser, '"Learning in Cities," NBER Working
Paper No. 6271, November 1997.
5 E.L. Glaeser, H. Kallal, J. Scheinkman, and A. Shleifer,
"Growth in Cities," Journal of Political Economy 100 (1992)pp.
1126-52.
6 E.L. Glaeser, J. Scheinkman, and A. Shleifer, "Economic Growth
in a Cross-Section of Cities," Journal of Monetary Economics 36
(1995) pp. 117-43.
7 J. Gaspar and E.L. Glaeser, "Information Technology and the
Future of Cities," NBER Working Paper No. 5562, May 1996, and
Journal of Urban Economics, forthcoming.
8 E.L. Glaeser, "Are Cities Dying," Journal of Economic
Perspectives, Winter 1998, forthcoming.
9 G. Ellison and E.L. Glaeser, "Geographic Concentration in U.S.
Manufacturing Industries: A Dartboard Approach," Journal of
Political Economy 105 (1997)pp. 889-927.
10 D. Dumais, G. Ellison, and E. L. Glaeser, "Geographic
Concentration as a Dynamic Process," NBER Working Paper No. 6270,
November 1997.
11 E.L. Glaeser and B. Sacerdote, "Why is There More Crime in
Cities?" NBER Working Paper No. 5430, January 1996.
12 E.L. Glaeser, B. Sacerdote, and J. Scheinkman, "Crime and
Social Interactions," Quarterly Journal of Economics CXI (1996) pp.
508-48.
13 D. Cutler and E.L. Glaeser, "Are Ghettos Good or Bad?"
NBER Working Paper No. 5163, June 1995, and Quarterly Journal of
Economics CXII (1997) pp. 827-72.
14 D. Cutler and E.L. Glaeser, "The Rise and Decline of the
American Ghetto," NBER Working Paper No. 5881, January 1997.
15 D. DiPasquale and E.L. Glaeser, "The L.A. Riot and the
Economics of Urban Unrest," NBER Working Paper No. 5456, February
1996, and Journal of Urban Economics, forthcoming.
16 E.L. Glaeser, "The Incentive Effects of Property Taxes on
Local Governments," Public Choice 89: pp. 93-111.
17 E.L. Glaeser, "Should Transfer Payments be Indexed to Local
Price Levels?" NBER Working Paper No. 5598, May 1996, and Regional
Science and Urban Economics, forthcoming.
18 E.L. Glaeser, "The Social Costs of Rent Control
Revisited," NBER Working Paper No. 5441, January 1996.
19 E.L. Glaeser and E. Luttmer, "The Misallocation of Housing
Under Rent Control," NBER Working Paper in progress.
Edward L. Glaeser is a Faculty Research Fellow in the NBER's
Program on Economic Fluctuations and a Associate Professor at Harvard.
He is profiled in this issue.