Industrial R and D: determinants and consequences.
Hall, Bronwyn H.
In modern industrial economies, technical change and innovation are
considered to be a major impetus behind economic growth and improvements
in the standard of living. Although many "actors" are
important in creating a climate in which innovation can flourish, in a
market economy it is primarily private firms that deliver the benefits
of scientific research and technological innovation to consumers. For
this reason, I and other economists have focused on understanding and
measuring the forces that determine individual firm performance in this
area, and on evaluating the effectiveness and direction of industrial
research.
Economic analysis of industrial R and D has led many to question
whether private firms have an incentive to undertake the amount of R and
D that is optimal for society as a whole.(1) This causes us to ask by
how much the private returns to R and D fall below the social returns;
whether our capital market and corporate governance systems do a good
job of encouraging R and D investment and innovation; how effective such
government policies as the R and D tax credit are; and how our
performance and policies compare to those of other large developed
economies. My own recent research has examined: the consequences of U.S.
capital market structure and the corporate restructuring wave of the
1980s for the performance of R and D; the effectiveness of the R and D
tax credit in inducing firms to increase their R and D spending; the
contribution of industrial R and D both to productivity growth and to
the private returns of individual firms during the recent past; and
comparisons of U.S. firm performance in this area with that of France
and other countries.
The Market for Corporate Capital and Industrial R and D
During the past decade many observers viewed the wave of
restructuring and downsizing in the U.S. manufacturing sector as
inimical to investment in R and D in that sector. Some went so far as to
argue that the market for corporate control had a serious negative
impact on companies' long-term investment, which in turn
contributed to the decline of the United States in global
competitiveness. Beginning with a study for a 1987 NBER Conference on
Corporate Takeovers, I have investigated the evidence behind this
argument in a series of papers, and reached the conclusion that the
picture has been greatly overdrawn. Still, there is no doubt that a
variety of external forces led simultaneously to an increase in leverage
and a reduction in R and D investment in certain sectors.(2)
The financial restructuring of U.S. public corporations can be
divided loosely into three classes of activity: ordinary merger or
acquisition activity; leveraged buyout or going private transactions;
and large shifts in the balance sheet toward debt without going private.
During the 1980s, the relationship among these three activities and the
R and D activities of the firm varied substantially, with only the third
being clearly associated with declines in R and D spending. Ordinary
merger activity unaccompanied by changes in leverage seems to have gone
on throughout the period without having much impact on firms' R and
D policies. After a merger, the typical firm had an R and D-to-sales
ratio that was equal to a size-weighted average of the intensities of
the two merging firms.(3) Not only does this imply that mergers are not
necessarily negative for R and D investment, but it also indicates that
cost-saving on R and D was probably not the primary motive for these
mergers.
Leveraged buyouts and going private transactions increased
dramatically during the 1980s, but the potential impact on R and D
spending was minuscule, for the simple reason that most of these took
place in sectors where R and D investment historically had not been an
important part of business strategy (food, textiles, auto parts, tires,
fabricated metals, and miscellaneous manufacturing). In ten years, the total amount of annual R and D investment involved was less than 0.5
percent of annual industrial R and D spending during the period.
However, leveraged restructurings in which the firm was not taken
private also increased during the 1980s, and these transactions often
were followed by substantial declines in R and D investment throughout
the period and particularly in the latter half: for example, the decline
in R and D intensity for such firms was about 0.8 percent (from 3.4 to
2.6) for 1982 to 1987. The firms involved were primarily in sectors with
relatively stable long-horizon technologies (petrochemical, steel,
autos) that have been under pressure from foreign competition. Case
study evidence does not generally support the view that these foregone investments would have been highly productive for the firms in question.
The aim of these restructurings seems to have been shrinking excess
capacity in these industries.(4)
Thus, rather than interpreting the corporate restructuring wave as
negative for R and D and other long-term investments, it makes more
sense to view the two phenomena, increases in leverage and declines in
investment, as joint consequences of the higher overall cost of capital
during this period and changes in the relative price of debt to
equity.(5)
The Returns to R and D During the 1980s
To provide another perspective on the factors affecting changes in R
and D investment strategy in U.S. manufacturing during the 1980s one
needs to take a closer look at the ex ante and ex post returns to these
investments. Ex ante, the stock market signals its expectations of the
future profitability of investment in particular firms and sectors via
the discrepancy between the market value of existing capital and the
book value of the underlying assets (albeit with considerable random
error). During the 1980s, the ratio between the market value of ordinary
capital and the book value of that capital for the average firm rose
from somewhat less than one toward one in most manufacturing sectors.(6)
The implication of this finding is that the wave of restructuring and
downsizing that we experienced during the period had the effect of
removing less productive firms and capital from the sector.
In contrast, changes in the ratio between the market value and the
book value of capitalized R and D expenditure varied widely across
sectors in ways consistent with the restructuring scenario: in the
traditional medium technology sectors of nonpharmaceutical chemicals and
petrochemicals, metals, transportation equipment, and machinery, the
value of R and D rose from below one to close to one during the period,
as the sectors shrank. In pharmaceuticals it has remained above unity
throughout most of the past 20 years (through 1991). However, in the
electrical, scientific instruments, electronics, and computing sectors,
the value of capitalized R and D fell precipitously, becoming close to
zero at the end of the 1980s in the electronics and computing sectors.
This result admits of two (related) interpretations: either the expected
return to future investments in these industries is very low, or the
past investments have experienced a much faster depreciation of economic
returns than the rate at which they are traditionally capitalized (15
percent).
Ex post results on the contribution of R and D investment to firm
revenue support this interpretation. They show that the contribution of
R and D to sales growth was low during the 1970s and the first half of
the 1980s but has increased recently, except in the electrical industry
and in the large-firm part of the computing, machinery, metals, and
motor vehicle industries. The overall explanation for these findings is
that the very substantial restructuring of the manufacturing sector
during the 1980s raised the valuation of ordinary capital (and of R and
D capital in the medium-technology sectors). At the same time entry by
smaller firms and new technology coupled with a speedup in product
cycles eroded the profits in the electrical and computing sectors,
leading to a substantial decline in the valuation of their
investments.(7) It is noteworthy that although the private returns in
these sectors have been low, the benefits that have spilled over to
consumers have been large: almost all of the productivity gains in the
computing and electronics sectors have gone to the purchasers of their
products rather than to the industry itself. This is another piece of
evidence of the gap between the private and social returns to R and
D.(8)
Market Myopia Toward R and D
The argument that a liquid market for corporate capital such as the
United States experienced during the 1980s is not a market that
encourages investment in innovation often goes hand-in-hand with
complaints about short-termism in U.S. equity markets. That is, analysts
are focused on short-term earnings rather than on the potential payoff
from long-term investments, and this discourages firms from undertaking
them. One way to examine this claim is to measure the discount rate that
investors implicitly are applying to the cash dividend streams they
expect to receive from holding the shares in a company. Do they penalize firms that have low current earnings and high R and D investment rates?
The answer to this question is no.(9) Although it is perfectly true
that the average discount rate that investors apply to the future cash
dividends of firms is somewhat higher than the rate at which they
discount Treasury bills and bonds (as earlier researchers have found),
it is lower than average for firms with either higher R and D investment
or higher capital spending, and higher than average for firms with high
current earnings.(10) In addition, this discount rate seems to have
fallen somewhat during the 1980s, suggesting that investors have become
less myopic, if anything. In some respects, this finding is the mirror
image of the findings discussed earlier: if anything, investors in the
late 1970s and early 1980s were overly optimistic about the future
profits to be earned from R and D investments in some sectors, leading
to a tendency to discount such investments at a low rate.
R and D Tax Policy and the Cost of Capital
The potential for market failure in the allocation of resources for
industrial research has led to a desire for further understanding of the
cost of capital faced by firms undertaking R and D and of the effects of
corporate tax provisions on that cost of capital. Recent research has
addressed both these questions. In addition to the normal considerations
that apply to the cost of any type of investment, two features of R and
D require special consideration: first, the very fact that it typically
creates an intangible, highly idiosyncratic and risky asset will tend to
increase the effective cost faced by firms. Second, the U.S. tax system
contains several features intended to reduce this cost for R and
D-performing firms, among them the expensing of most R and D, the rules
on the allocation of R and D spending to foreign source income, and most
importantly, the incremental Research and Experimentation Tax
Credit.(11)
The asset created by R and D is to a great extent intangible
knowledge, embodied only in scientists and engineers. Its value is
typically difficult to signal to the market ex ante (even if it is
known). Therefore we might expect firms to find internal funds much
cheaper than external, and equity cheaper than debt (because of the lack
of a securable asset) when financing this investment. Whether or not
this is true matters, both because many innovative firms find it
difficult to generate the earnings necessary for investment and because
our tax system has an implicit subsidy for debt financing relative to
equity.
It is easy to find evidence for the preference of R and D-intensive
firms for equity over debt, but somewhat more difficult to evaluate the
importance of the "liquidity" constraint for these firms.(12)
There are two reasons for this difficulty: first, in general, finding
that investment of any kind is sensitive to cash flow always admits of
two interpretations. Either the firm is responding to positive or
negative demand shocks that appear as changes in cash flow, or the firm
indeed finds internal funds a cheaper source of capital, and so it
increases investments when these increase. Second, for R and D
investment in particular, adjustment costs are high, and firms have
incentives to smooth their investment paths. This fact will moderate any
year-to-year responsiveness to liquidity, although at the same time it
implies that firms will underinvest even more.(13) In spite of these
problems, a series of studies has documented the importance of liquidity
constraints for R and D investment by U.S. firms.(14)
Evidence that firms are not able to capture all the returns to R and
D investments, in spite of the legal mechanisms available, including
patenting and trade secret protection, implies that society as a whole
would be better off if we could induce firms to perform more R and D.
The R and D tax credit, which has been a feature of the U.S. tax system
since 1981, is the most prominent and wide-ranging of the government
policies designed for this purpose.(15) Before 1985, most researchers
found relatively weak evidence that firms responded to the tax credit by
increasing their R and D spending.(16) Most attributed this to the fact
that the effective tax credit faced by most firms amounted to a
reduction of 5 percent in the marginal cost of R and D, rather than the
statutory rate of 25 percent.
New results suggest that by 1990 the tax credit has become more
effective, in that the amount of additional R and D spending induced by
the credit has been greater than the cost in foregone tax revenue.(17)
This has occurred in spite of the fact that the effective credit rate is
small, because the average tax price elasticity for R and D spending is
around one in the short run, and also because it has taken firms some
time to adjust to the continuing presence of the tax credit in our
corporate tax system.(18)
International Comparisons
Many questions about the role of the government and institutional
environment in promoting innovation are difficult to answer by studying
the experience of a single country. The conclusion that U.S. firms
probably were investing and disinvesting "correctly" on
average during the 1980s, given the behavior of the stock market, real
interest rates, and other macroeconomic factors does not really answer
the question of whether other environments might elicit a more socially
productive level of investment. To explore such questions as these, we
have begun a collaboration with colleagues in several European countries
that differ in various ways from the United States.
The initial results of this project are described in a comparative
study using about 1000 manufacturing firms each from France and the
United States.(19) We find that the contribution of R and D to sales
productivity growth declined during the 1980s in France as well as in
the United States. The simultaneity among sales growth and both Rand D
and ordinary investment is somewhat higher in the United States than in
France, possibly reflecting the greater importance of liquidity
constraints for investment in the United States. Future work will
incorporate comparisons to the United Kingdom, Germany, and Japan.
1 See R. R. Nelson, "The Simple Economics of Basic Scientific
Research," Journal of Political Economy (1959), pp. 297-306; and K.
Arrow, "Economic Welfare and the Allocation of Resources for
Invention," in The Rate and Direction of Inventive Activity, R. R.
Nelson, ed. Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1962, pp. 609-625.
Empirical evidence on the topic has been surveyed by Z. Griliches,
"The Search for R and D Spillovers," NBER Reprint No. 1758,
November 1992, and Scandinavian Journal of Economics, (1992).
2 See B. H. Hall, "The Effect of Takeover Activity on Corporate
Research and Development," NBER Reprint No. 1091, December 1988,
and in The Economic Effects of Takeover Activity, A. J. Auerbach, ed.
Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1988; and "The Impact of
Corporate Restructuring on Industrial Research and Development,"
Brookings Papers on Economic Activity (1990:1), pp. 85-136; and
"Corporate Restructuring and Investment Horizons, "Business
History Review 68 (Spring 1994), pp. 110-143.
3 See B. H. Hall, "The Effect of Takeover Activity . . ."
and "The Impact of Corporate Restructuring . . .," ops. cit.
4 See the evidence reviewed in B. H. Hall, "Corporate
Restructuring . . .," op. cit. For a different way of looking at
the same phenomenon, see M. C. Jensen, "The Modern Industrial
Revolution, Exit, and the Failure of Internal Control Systems,"
Journal of Finance 48 (1993), pp. 831-850.
5 This point also has been made by M. M. Blair and R. E. Litan,
"Corporate Leverage and Leveraged Buyouts in the Eighties," in
Debt, Taxes, and Corporate Restructuring, J. B. Shoven and J. Waldfogel,
eds. Washington, DC. Brookings Institution, 1990.
6 See B. H. Hall, "Industrial Research During the 1980s: Did the
Rate of Return Fall?" NBER Reprint No. 1858, March 1994, and
Brookings Papers on Economic Activity: Microeconomics 2 (1993), pp.
289-344; and "The Stock Market Valuation of Research and
Development Investment During the 1980s," American Economic Review
83 (may 1993), pp. 259-264, for the evidence discussed here.
7 See B. H. Hall, "The Stock Market Valuation . . .," op.
cit.
8 See B. H. Hall, "The Private and Social Returns to Research
and Development: What Have We Learned?" paper presented to the
American Enterprise Institute/Brookings Institution Conference on the
Contributions of Research to Economic Growth and Society, Washington,
DC, October 1994 (forthcoming in the conference volume); and Z.
Griliches, "Productivity and the Data Constraint," American
Economic Review 84 (1994), pp. 1-43 for more detailed discussion.
9 See B. H. Hall and R. E. Hall, "The Value and Performance of
U.S. Corporations," Brookings Papers on Economic Activity (1993:1),
pp. 1-50.
10 See, for example, R. Mehra and E. C. Prescott, "The Equity
Premium: A Puzzle," Journal of Monetary Economics 19 (1985), pp.
145-161.
11 For a review of the foreign source income allocation rules for R
and D intensity in the cross section, see J. R. Hines, Jr.,
"International Taxation," NBER Reporter, Fall 1994, pp. 10-15.
12 For evidence that leverage is inversely correlated with R and D
intensity in the cross section, see M. S. Long and I. B. Malitz,
"Investment Patterns and Financial Leverage," in Corporate
Capital Structures in the United States, B. M. Friedman, ed. Chicago:
University of Chicago Press, 1985; and B. H. Hall, "Research and
Development Investment at the Firm Level: Does the Source of Financing
Matter?" NBER Working Paper No. 4096, June 1992.
13 See B. H. Hall and F. Hayashi, "Research and Development as
an Investment," NBER Working Paper No. 2973, May 1989; Z.
Griliches, B. H. Hall, and A. Pakes, "R&D, Patents, and Market
Value Revisited: Is There a Second (Technological Opportunity)
Factor?" Economics of Innovation and New Technology 1 (1991), pp.
183-202; S. Lach and M. Schankerman, "Dynamics of R&D and
Investment in the Scientific Sector," Journal of Political Economy
97 (1988), pp. 880-904. and J. L. Bernstein and M. I. Nadiri,
"Financing and Investment in Plant and Equipment and Research and
Development," in Prices, Competition, and Equilibrium, M. H. Peston
and R. E. Quandt, eds. Oxford, England: Philip Allan, 1986, pp. 233-248,
for evidence that R and D spending is relatively smooth within firms and
displays high adjustment costs.
14 See B. H. Hall, "Research and Development Investment at the
Firm Level . . .," op. cit., and C. P. Himmelberg and B. C.
Peterson, "R&D and Internal Finance: A Panel Study of Small
Firms in High Tech Industries," Review of Economics and Statistics
(1994), pp. 38-51.
15 Many countries have similar measures, including Canada, France,
and Japan among the G-7 countries.
16 See R. Altshuler, "A Dynamic Analysis of the Research and
Experimentation Credit," National Tax Journal 41 (1988), pp.
453-466; R. Eisner, S. H. Albert, and M. A. Sullivan, "The New
Incremental Tax Credit for R&D: Incentive or Disincentive?"
National Tax Journal 37 (1984), pp. 171-183; and E. Mansfield, "The
R&D Tax Credit and Other Technology Policy Issues, "American
Economic Review 76, pp. 190-194. 17 See B. H. Hall, "R and D Tax
Policy During the Eighties: Success or Failure?" in Tax Policy and
the Economy, Volume 7, J. M. Poterba, ed., Cambridge: MIT Press, 1993,
pp. 1-36; M. N. Baily and R. Z. Lawrence, "Tax Incentives for
R&D: What Do the Data Tell Us?" study commissioned by the
Council on Research and Technology, Washington, DC (1992); and
"Fiscal Policy Towards R&D in the United States: Recent
Experience," paper presented to the OECD Meeting on Fiscal Policy
and Innovation, Paris, France, January 19, 1995, Paris: OECD,
forthcoming.
18 See B. H. Hall, "R and D Tax Policy During the Eighties . .
.," op. cit., and J. R. Hines, Jr., "On the Sensitivity of R
and D to Delicate Tax Changes: The Case of U.S. Multinationals," in
International Taxation, A. Giovannini, R. G. Hubbard, and J. B. Slemrod,
eds., Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1994. For estimation of an R
and D price elasticity that does not rely on the tax treatment, see J.
I. Bernstein and M. I. Nadiri, "Interindustry R&D Spillovers,
Rates of Return, and Production in High Tech Industries," American
Economic Review 78 (1988), pp. 429-434.
19 See B. H. Hall and J. Mairesse, "Exploring the Relationship
Between R and D and Productivity in French Manufacturing Firms,"
NBER Reprint No. 1962, April 1995, and Journal of Econometrics 65
(1995), pp. 263-293; and "Estimating the Productivity of Research
and Development: An Exploration of GMM Methods Using Data on French and
United States Manufacturing Firms," in International Productivity
Comparisons, Wagner, Karin, and van Ark, eds., Amsterdam: Elsevier-North
Holland, forthcoming.