Economic fluctuations.
Hall, Robert E.
The U.S. business cycle continues to be the main concern of the
NBER's Program on Economic Fluctuations. We have examined the
sources of the business cycle, propagation mechanisms, and policy
responses. The program is organized around a number of specialized
research groups, each of which studies some aspect of the business cycle
with a combination of analytical and empirical methods. Their results
are presented at research meetings three times a year.
The program also maintains the semi-official chronology of the U.S.
business cycle. This function is the responsibility of the Bureau's
Business Cycle Dating Committee.
The 1991 Business Cycle Trough
On December 22, 1992, the Business Cycle Dating Committee announced
its determination that the U.S. economy reached a trough of activity in
March 1991. Previously, the committee had determined that the economy
reached a peak of activity in July 1990. The eight-month period between
July 1990 and March 1991 thus entered the NBER's chronology as a
recession. The recession ended in March 1991 and an expansion began; the
expansion is still underway at this writing.
The committee waited nearly two years to identify the trough.
Although this period was unusually long and the committee was criticized
for the delay, the sluggish performance of the economy during 1991 and
1992 compelled the long wait. The committee followed its normal policy
of waiting to determine the trough date until there was no doubt that
any future downturn in the economy would be considered a new recession
and not a continuation of the recession that began in July 1990. An
important fact to the committee was that the broadest measure of
economic activity--gross domestic product in constant dollars--did not
surpass its previous peak, according to data available at the time,
until the third quarter of 1992. Not until December did the overall
pattern of economic activity appear to be strong enough to warrant the
determination of the trough date.
The behavior of the economy in 1991 made deciding on a trough date
particularly challenging. Two important monthly indicators related to
the production and sales of goods--industrial production, and
manufacturing-trade sales in constant dollars--had unambiguous troughs
in early 1991 (in March and January, respectively). Two other monthly
indicators had declined to close to their minimum values by early 1991,
but continued to decline slightly for the rest of that year. Real
personal income reached its trough in November 1991, at a minuscule 0.07
percent below its level in April. Total hours of all nonagricultural
employees reached its trough in April. The choice of March 1991 as the
trough date was based primarily on the fact that various averages of the
monthly indicators reached clear troughs in that month.
The Business Cycle Dating Committee meets as needed to keep the
chronology up to date. The next meeting will occur when it appears
appropriate to determine the date of the next peak in activity, or if
new data become available that suggest that an existing date should be
adjusted.
Overview of Modern Research in Economic Fluctuations
The unifying theme of research in the program is movements over time
in national output, employment, productivity, interest rates, and
inflation. Interestingly, none of the research tackles all of these
issues jointly. Members of the program are not engaged in a collective
effort to build a complete empirical model of the U.S. or world
economies. Instead, research generally isolates particular parts of the
economy, such as the behavior of the consumer, or considers issues of
the overall performance of the economy in terms of relatively simple and
admittedly stripped-down models of the determination of output and
employment.
Most of the research within the program looks at data on the U.S.
economy within a rather fully specified analytical framework. The
research is oriented toward scientific findings about technology,
preferences, and other fundamentals, rather than toward descriptions and
correlations. Most of the papers presented to the program's
research groups and at its research meetings are quite technical, even
when the basic factual results ultimately can be explained in a
nontechnical way. A number of program members use methods from the
frontier of econometrics, and are seen by the profession as
econometricians as much as macroeconomists.
Where research considers issues of fluctuations by looking at
particular sectors of the economy, the actual research closely resembles
work by economists in other branches of applied microeconomics. Many of
the papers produced within the program are of great interest to those in
labor economics, industrial organization, and other fields of
microeconomics. And many of the economists who attend group meetings or
program meetings come from microeconomic specialties. Although the
long-run goal of many researchers of providing a microeconomic theory of
macroeconomic fluctuations has proven elusive, the assimilation of
microeconomic thinking into macroeconomics, as it is practiced in the
fluctuations program, has been complete.
Macroeconomic Complementarities
For a number of years, the EF program has had an active research
group on macroeconomic complementarities under the direction of Russell
W. Cooper. Complementarities--that is, favorable nonmarket interactions
between firms, or between workers and firms--could play an important
role in explaining the vulnerability of the national economy to
relatively unimportant shocks.
In an economy without complementarities, markets have a strong role
as shock absorbers. For example, a downward shift in consumption, such
as apparently occurred around 1990 in the United States, should have
relatively little effect on output and employment. Instead of triggering
a recession, the shock should bring responses in credit markets that
offset it. If consumers spend less, interest rates should fall, raising
the demand for investment goods and exports.
By contrast, with complementarities there can be a magnification of
small shocks. If the productivity of one firm depends on the level of
activity of related firms, a negative shock can move the economy to a
substantially lower level of output at its new equilibrium.
Another potential result of complementarities is multiple
equilibriums. An economy can have a high-level equilibrium, in which
firms and workers mutually reinforce each other's productivity. The
same economy can have a low-level equilibrium, in which no single firm
can expand profitably because of the low level of activity of other
firms.
Currently, work in the complementarities group falls into three broad
areas. Attacks on the tough theoretical issues raised by
complementarities are being made by Douglas Gale, Alberto Trejos,
Randall Wright, Andrew John, B. Ravikumar, Costas Azariadis, and Bruce
Smith. The second type of work mixes theoretical and quantitative
analysis. The common goal is to assess the quantitative plausibility of
models with complementarities. Group members taking this approach are
Satyajit Chatterjee, Russell W. Cooper, Paul Beaudry, Michael Devereux,
and Jordi Gali. The last approach is strongly empirical. Suzanne Cooper
and Steven N. Durlauf have developed a method for detecting the presence
of the types of behavior associated with complementarities in aggregate
data. Peter Klenow is studying complementarities that take the specific
form of one firm learning from the experience of another firm making the
same product. Klenow is using detailed data for computer chips.
Consumption Inequality and Its Aggregate Implications
A second important area of research in the program since its
inception 15 years ago is the behavior of the consumer. Under the
direction of Marjorie A. Flavin and Knut Mork, and more recently Orazio
Attanasio, most of the research applies sophisticated models of
household behavior to survey data on their purchasing decisions.
Households gather and process information about their future well-being
in order to make current decisions. Families do not just consume a
certain fraction of their current income; they tend to put windfall
income into the bank and to consume it slowly over future years. Our
research also has rejected the opposite view--that families follow
exactly the optimal information-processing strategy to distinguish
temporary from permanent changes in income. There is some evidence that
families let consumption track income too closely to be explained by
models of optimal behavior. But a newly developed body of thought holds
that refinement of the models can explain these departures.
Research by Attanasio and Steven J. Davis shows how the relative wage
gains experienced by older and better-educated households during the
1980s were reflected in relative consumption gains. Angus Deaton and
Christina H. Paxson study the effects of demographic changes in the
United States, the United Kingdom, and Taiwan on the cross-sectional
inequality in consumption. Wouter den Haan extends the method of
parameterized expectations to solve and simulate several versions of an
asset pricing model. Giuseppe Bertola is studying the effect on
aggregate saving and growth of factor distribution. James Banks, Richard
Blundell, and Agar Brugiavini are measuring consumption and income
variance, and quantifying their effects on consumption growth. R. Glenn
Hubbard, Jonathan S. Skinner, and Stephen P. Zeldes are using numerical
simulations to assess the importance of the precautionary motive for
saving. Several realistic features, such as liquidity constraints,
failing health, and "means-tested" Social Security provisions
are part of the model.
Micro and Macro Perspectives on the Aggregate Labor Market
A third area of research in recent years has been the functioning of
labor markets. Under the direction of Wright and Richard Rogerson, the
EF program has had a research group on labor supply and related issues;
Davis led a separate group on employment dynamics. Recently these groups
combined.
The elasticity of labor supply is of central importance in
understanding overall economic fluctuations. When the economy booms,
many people are working, and the typical worker is putting in unusually
long hours. In a slump, both the number of people at work and their
hours fall. Can these movements be interpreted as occurring along a
labor supply curve?
The traditional macroeconomic answer was no. A recession was seen as
a time of involuntary unemployment, a breakdown of the labor market.
Modern thinking, which emphasizes market interpretations of
fluctuations, has tried to provide a deeper analysis of the issue. One
view is that the labor supply may be much more elastic in the short run
than in the long run. Another looks at the time allocation of workers
between working and looking for work. A further area of research in the
macro-labor field is the sources of unemployment, job destruction; and
the sources of reemployment, job creation. Very detailed micro data from
individual plants provide important new insights into these processes.
The macro-labor group has been meeting for three years. The
group's focus is on the behavior and performance of the aggregate
labor market, including employment and productivity fluctuations, human
capital accumulation and growth, and unemployment. Dale Mortenson and
Christopher Pissarides have studied matching models of the labor market
to analyze the relationship between job creation and destruction and
cyclical fluctuations and growth. They build on the empirical work of
Davis and John C. Haltiwanger on firm-level employment dynamics, which
also has been represented in the group. Victor Rios-Rull shows how labor
market regulations can emerge endogenously and create long wave growth
cycles. Rogerson and Raquel Fernandez study the interaction between
income distribution and education, and point to inefficiencies in a
system of local provision of public education.
Empirical Methods in Macroeconomics
Durlauf and Francis Diebold recently organized a new group on
empirical methods in macroeconomics, focusing on the interface between
time-series econometrics and empirical macroeconomics. Their first
meeting was in Palo Alto on February 6. Lucrezia Reichlin is working on
the problem of invertibility in multivariate time-series models, and
developing new diagnostic procedures for assessing the likelihood of
neglected moving average components in VAR analyses. Robert F. Engle is
working on modeling "common features" in economic and
financial time series. Simon Potter is working with nonlinear impulse
response functions and exploring their application in a number of
macroeconomic contexts. Durlauf and Louis Maccini are using the
Durlauf-Hall signal extraction approach to decompose inventory
fluctuations into a model-consistent part and a "noise" part,
thereby providing a natural metric for evaluating the fit of inventory
models. Kenneth D. West and David W. Wilcox are exploring the properties
of advanced estimation methods using Monte Carlo methods. Halbert White
is continuing his work on neural networks, with particular focus on
their strengths and weaknesses as approximators. Bent Sorenson is
examining whether productivity is cointegrated with other determinants
of long-run growth.
Impulses and Propagation Mechanisms
Since 1989, a group under the direction of Lawrence J. Christiano and
Martin Eichenbaum has studied impulses and propagation mechanisms in the
business cycle. Its winter 1992 meeting, organized jointly with the
University of Arizona, focused on theoretical and empirical aspects of
the interaction of monetary policy and business cycles. Four of the
seven papers concerned international aspects of the problem. Alan C.
Stockman presented a theoretical model of the impact of price rigidities
on the trade-off between exchange rate targeting and monetary control.
Don Schlagenhauf and Jeff Wrase analyzed the effects of monetary policy
shocks on nominal and real exchange rates. Eichenbaum and Charles L.
Evans showed empirical evidence of the effects of U.S. monetary policy
shocks on exchange rates. Nobuhiro Kiyotaki discussed joint work with
John Moore on the role of balance sheet constraints in propagating
business cycle shocks. Christiano, Eichenbaum, and Evans gave a progress
report on their ongoing work studying the impact of monetary policy
shocks on the Flow of Funds data. Mark Gertler and Simon Gilchrist
presented their work on the response of large and small firms to
monetary policy shocks. Vittorio U. Grilli and Nouriel Roubini described
international evidence on the exchange rate effects of monetary policy
shocks.
At the NBER Summer Institute, the group discussed three papers on the
interaction of monetary policy and the business cycle. Gertler and
Gilchrist described the differential response to monetary policy shocks
in the inventory investment behavior of small and large manufacturing
firms. Stephen D. Oliner and Glenn Rudebusch looked at other differences
in the response of large and small firms to monetary policy shocks.
Christiano and Evans presented a paper with Eichenbaum on the effects of
a monetary policy shock on the borrowing and lending activities of
different sectors of the economy.
Two papers analyzed international estimates of productivity growth.
Evans showed that measures of monetary policy shocks lead to a prolonged
rise in standard measures of productivity. Patricia Reynolds presented
improved estimates of productivity growth for different countries, and
contrasted them with the existing literature. Two papers focused on
fiscal policy in equilibrium business cycle models. Lee Ohanian
presented a progress report on his work with Thomas Cooley that uses an
equilibrium model to assess the effects of the policies pursued by the
United Kingdom and the United States during World War II on their
postwar economic performance. Ellen McGrattan discussed her ongoing
study with Phillip A. Braun on the impact of fiscal policy on U.S.
economic performance during and after World War II. David Levine
analyzed the implications of income risk for the equity premium puzzle.
Gali presented his research on models of spatial location; his
theoretical discussion focused on the role of externalities and
increasing returns in the propagation of sectoral shocks.
High-Frequency Economic Fluctuations
Until his recent move to the staff of the Council of Economic
Advisers, Matthew D. Shapiro was the director of a research group on
fluctuations that occur relatively rapidly over time. The group also is
concerned with variations in economic activity over space and their
relationship to similar variations over time. Participants include John
Shea, Mark Bils, and James Kahn, who are working on spatial--temporal
issues; Benjamin Eden, whose research in the group deals with inventory
fluctuations; Valerie A. Ramey, who is continuing her research on the
intertemporal elasticity of substitution; Ana Aizcorbe, who is studying
variations over time in the productivity of auto assembly plants; and
Susanto Basu and Argia Sbordone, whose research deals with labor
hoarding and cyclical capital utilization.