Political economy.
Alesina, Alberto F.
Political Economy
Economists usually look at how policy should be conducted in a world
free of institutions in which a benevolent social planner maximizes
society's welfare. Such normative models are essential for
understanding the benchmark case of a planner who faces a
"representative individual"; however, they do not fully
explain the many apparent departures from first-best policies in the
real world.
My research focuses on positive aspects of economic policy and,
more specifically, on the interaction between politics and
macroeconomics. It recognizes first that there are no neutral social
planners; politicians respond to ideological and opportunistic incentives and pressures and are constrained by the institutions in
which they operate. Second, individuals and groups have conflicting
policy preferences, in particular because of the distributional
consequences of different policies. Economic policies emerge from the
resolution of these conflicts of interests through the political
process.
Political Business Cycles
In a 1987 paper, I consider the consequences for business cycles of
electoral uncertainty.(1) I develop a model in which two political
parties with different preferences for inflation and unemployment
alternate in office. Economic agents are rational and are aware of the
differences in the policy preferences of the two parties, but they
cannot anticipate post-election policy perfectly, since they are not
certain about which party will be elected.
Because of this uncertainty, the rate of inflation in the
post-electoral period cannot be anticipated perfectly before elections.
If nominal contracts must be signed, and they are not synchronized perfectly with the elections, then the model predicts the level of
economic activity will deviate from its "natural" level after
the elections. When the unemployment-averse party (left) is elected,
there will be rapid growth and rising inflation. After expectations
adjust to the new government, economic activity returns to its natural
level. Inflation remains high, because an unemployment-averse government
finds it difficult to commit credibly to a policy of low inflation. The
opposite outcome will occur when the inflation-averse party (right) is
elected. After an early downturn, economic activity returns to its
natural level with low inflation. Thus, the implications of this model
are quite difficult from the traditional business cycle model, in which
every government has the same opportunistic preferences and creates
rapid growth before each election.
My empirical research on the United States has supported my 1987
model.(2) Two other papers show that this correlation between elections
and economic fluctuations is common in many other OECD democracies as
well.(3) In particular, the pattern is stronger in countries in which
political changes between right and left are relatively unambiguous, as
opposed to countries with large center-left coalition governments with
frequent early elections and coalition collapses.
An important question raised by these findings is why political
parties remain polarized, rather than converging to the preferences of
the median voter. In a series of papers, I address the issue of the
degree of policy convergence in a two-party election.(4) These papers
develop electoral models in which two parties face each other in a
series of elections. Both parties want to win per se, but they have
different preferences over policies. In general, the parties will have
to trade off between the ideologically preferred policies and more
"moderate" policies that will increase their chances of
electoral victory.
The credibility of pre-electoral policy announcements also becomes
an important issue. Politicians face different incentives before and
after elections. Before, they want to appeal to the largest possible
electorate, and thus they would like to converge toward the median voter
preferences. Once in office, though, they may feel freer to pursue their
ideological objectives. The behavior of policymakers once in office may
be affected by reputational considerations, too: fear of losing
"reputation" in the eyes of the voters may constrain the
policies each government chooses. In general, reputational
considerations will reduce but not eliminate the political polarization in two-party systems.
Divided Government and the Mid-Term Voting Cycle
In American elections, the party holding the presidency always
loses seats in mid-term congressional elections relative to those won in
the previous presidential election year. This sometimes leads to a
"divided government" in which the president's party does
not have a majority in the House and/or in the Senate. In a recent paper
with Howard Rosenthal, I suggest that voters choosing between two
relatively polarized parties opt to counterbalance the president by
leaning toward the other party in the legislative elections.(5) In this
way, voters in the middle of the political spectrum can bring about
"moderate" policy outcomes.
Part of this balancing also occurs in the congressional election
held at the same time as the presidential election, but the voters have
a second chance to moderate in mid-term elections. In mid-term, the
voters already know who is in the White House and can choose the optimal
amount of balancing; in presidential election years, on the contrary,
the congressional vote in cast under uncertainty about which party will
win the presidency.
In a related paper, Rosenthal and I develop a macro-economic model
in which the two parties differ in their evaluation of the relative
costs of inflation and unemployment.(6) A newly elected Democratic
administration follows expansionary policies leading to a temporary high
growth rate. In mid-term congressional elections, the voters fear
excessive inflation and react by turning toward the Republican Party,
which gains representation.
The opposite occurs if the Republican candidate wins the
presidential elections. This model, which performs quite well on postwar
U.S. data, implies correlations between macroeconomic variables and
voting behavior that are quite different from those of the traditional
economic model of voting; in that model, voters simply reward the
incumbent if the economy is doing well before the elections. Our
approach also explains why traditional voting models do not perform as
well for congressional elections as they do for presidential elections.
More generally, our model suggests that voter myopia does not explain
observed voting patterns in the United States.
The Political Economy of Public Debt
In the last two decades, many industrial nations have experienced
large increases in government debt. In several countries (such as
Belgium, Italy, and Ireland) the debt-to-GNP ratio is around 100
percent. In the United States, the debt-to-GNP ratio rose sharply in the
1980s after a steady decline beginning after World War II. In two
papers, Guido Tabellini and I ask why so many governments have been
prone to peacetime deficits. We also explore the wide variance of debt
levels in different countries with relatively similar economic
conditions.(7)
We model government debt as the legacy that each government leaves
to its successors. In a polarized political system, each government may
be replaced by an opponent with very different preferences regarding the
desired distribution of the tax burden, and the level of and the
composition of spending. By manipulating the size of government debt,
each government can affect the state of the economy and thus the set of
policy options available to its successors. This strategic interaction
of the current government, supported by the majority of voters, with
future governments, possibly supported by different majorities, may lead
to deficits in excess of the first-best optimum.
One crucial testable implication of this view is that deficits
should be higher in countries and time periods with greater political
polarization; that is, when the ideological distance between alternating
governments is wide. A second implication is that when the current
government is not likely to win the next election, deficits should be
higher; the party in power has a stronger incentive to overspend and
manipulate the budget to influence the choices of future governments.
In LDCs, political polarization and uncertainty may lead to
accumulation of public external debt and private external assets
(capital flight) at the same time.(8) Suppose that a government allied
to business interests is in office. External public borrowing occurs as
a way of financing redistribution toward the groups supporting the
government. The burden of the debt is left to future governments, which
may be of the type supported by different groups, such as the
"workers." At the same time, the possibility of a change in
regime in favor of the workers' party interests implies a risk of
expropriatory taxes on capital: this political risk leads to capital
flight. We show that the parties supporting the interests of the capital
owners and the workers would follow different policies regarding the
imposition of capital controls and the choice between debt default and
fiscal adjustment. The empirical evidence of several indebted LDCs is
consistent with the predictions of this model.
Delayed Stabilizations
Countries often delay the adoption of stabilization programs, even
when they are unavoidable given the suboptimality and/or instability of
current policies. Delays are particularly inefficient when, as is often
the case, the lengthier wait will increase the cost of the
stabilization. For instance, explosive budget deficits financed by
inflation (degenerating into hyperinflations) often are allowed to
continue for prolonged periods, even though it is well understood that
sooner or later taxes will have to be raised to eliminate the deficit.
Sometimes it appears that "things have to get worse before they get
better."
Allan Drazen and I explain delays in the adoption of stabilization
programs as the result of distributional conflicts over the allocation
of the fiscal burden.(9) Delays occur because different groups attempt
to shelter themselves from the burden of taxation: each group, by
opposing stabilization programs unfavorable to them, hopes that in the
future other groups will bear a higher share of the burden. We model the
stabilization process as a "war of attrition" in which each
group tries to wait out the other. The more the expected distribution of
the burden of taxation after the stabilization, the longer
stabilizations will tend to be delayed. An uneven distribution of the
tax burden is more likely in politically polarized countries.
Delays also hinge on the uncertainty about which group has
sufficient economic and political resources to oppose policies
unfavorable to them. When this uncertainty is removed and a group is
forced to "given in," stabilizations occur: the political
consolidation of the "winners" leads to the imposition of a
disproportionate burden of taxation on the "losers" of the war
of attrition.
In an earlier paper, I study several interwar episodes of debt
adjustment policies in more detail.(10) These episodes also suggest a
war of attrition. In France, Germany, and Italy, all of which
experienced a period of extreme political instability and fragmentation after World War I, the fiscal adjustment was delayed, leading to bursts
of inflation. In these countries, stabilization policies were
implemented only when a political consolidation occurred. On the
contrary, in interwar England, the relatively stable political situation
with the Conservative Party in control led to an immediate postwar
fiscal stabilization.
This research on "delays" is applicable to more than
simply stabilization. It suggests a general politicoeconomic explanation
of why efficient policies are postponed, even if everybody knows that
sooner or later they will have to be adopted, and even if the more time
is wasted, the higher the aggregate costs of the policy will be.
In summary, I believe that the development and testing of positive
models of policy, with particular attention to political and
distribitional aspects, is crucial. First, these models help us to
understand empirical observations that are clearly inconsistent with
models based on the social planner assumption. Second, they provide
insights on how to set up institutions and policy rules to achieve the
best outcome, given the policymakers' ideological and opportunistic
incentives, and given the underlying conflicts of interest of different
individuals.
(1)A. F. Alesina, "Macroeconomic Policy in a Two-Party System as
a Repeated Game," Quarterly Journal of Economics 102 (August 1987),
pp. 651-678. (2)A. F. Alesina and J. D. Sachs, "Political Parties
and the Business Cycle in the United States, 1948-84," NBER Working
Paper No. 1940, June 1986, and Journal of Money, Credit and Banking 20,
1 (February 1988), pp. 63-82; and A. F. Alesina, "Macroeconomics
and Politics," in S. Fischer, ed., NBER Macroeconomics Annual 1988,
Vol. 3. Cambridge, MA: The MIT Press, 1988, pp. 13-52. (3)A. F. Alesina,
"Politics and Business Cycles in Industrial Democracies,"
Economic Policy 8, pp. 59-78; and A. F. Alesina and N. Roubini,
"Political Cycles: Evidence from OECD Economies," manuscript,
1990. (4)A. F. Alesina, "Credibility and Policy Convergence in a
Two-Party System with Rational Voters," American Economic Review
78, 4 (September 1988), pp. 796-806; A. F. Alesina and S. Spear,
"An Overlapping-Generations Model of Political Competition,"
NBER Working Paper No. 2354, August 1987, and Journal of Public
Economics 37 (December 1988), pp. 359-379; and A. F. Alesina and A.
Cukierman, "The Politics of Ambiguity," NBER Working Paper No.
2468, December 1987. (5)A. F. Alesina and H. Rosenthal, "Moderating
Elections," NBER Working Paper No. 3072, August 1989. (6)A. F.
Alesina and H. Rosenthal, "Ideological Cycles in Congressional
Elections and the Macroeconomy," NBER Working Paper No. 2706,
September 1988, and American Political Science Review, (June 1989).
(7)A. F. Alesina and G. Tabellini, "A Positive Model of Budget
Deficits and Government Debt," NBER Working Paper No. 2308, July
1987, and Review of Economic Studies, forthcoming, and "Voting on
the Budget Deficit," NBER Working Paper No. 2759, November 1988,
and American Economic Review, forthcoming. (8)A. F. Alesina and G.
Tabellini, "External Debt, Capital Flight, and Political
Risk," NBER Working Paper No. 2610, June 1988, and Journal of
International Economics, (November 1989). (9)A. F. Alesina and A Drazen,
"Why Are Stabilizations Delayed?" NBER WorkingPaper No. 3053,
August 1989. (10)A. F. Alesina, "The End of Large Public
Debts," in F. Giavazzi and Spaventa, eds., Surviving with a High
Public Debt: The Italian Experience, Cambridge, England: Cambridge
University Press, 1988.