Crowding effects on intrinsic motivation.
Frey, Bruno S.
The basic idea that rewards, and in particular monetary rewards,
may crowd out intrinsic motivation emanates from two quite different
branches of literature in the social sciences. In his book The Gift
Relationship, Richard Titmuss (1970) argued that paying for blood
undermines cherished social values and would therefore reduce or totally
eliminate people's willingness to donate blood. However, he was
unable to come up with any serious empirical evidence.
A second strand of literature stems from psychology. A group of
cognitive social psychologists identified that, under particular
conditions, monetary (external) rewards undermine intrinsic motivation
(Deci, 1971; Deci and Ryan, 1985; Deci with Flaste, 1995). People have
intrinsic motivation when they just like to act in a certain way or
because they have internalised social norms. Providing monetary rewards
for undertaking an activity may have the negative consequence that
people reduce their work effort.
The theories on intrinsic motivation emanating from social
psychology have in the meantime been integrated into economic theory
(Frey, 1992). Arguably, this 'crowding-out effect' is one of
the most important anomalies in economics. It suggests the opposite of
the most fundamental economic 'law' stipulating that raising
monetary incentives increases supply of effort. If the crowding-out
effect holds, raising monetary incentives reduces, rather than
increases, this supply. Under certain circumstances, it is therefore not
advisable to use the price mechanism to elicit a higher supply.
Moreover, one should rely on a quite different type of incentive, namely
intrinsic motivation.
This article discusses the crowding-out effect and its correlate,
the 'crowding-in effect', with special regard to its empirical
validity. It is demonstrated that these effects are empirically
well-founded and have been observed in many different and important
areas of the economy and society.
Intrinsic motivation in economic thinking
Monetary incentives crowding out the motivation to undertake an
activity may be considered a major anomaly: it predicts the reverse
reaction to the one expected according to the relative price effect, on
which much of economics is based. The successes of the 'economic
approach to human behaviour' (Becker, 1976; Frey, 1999) and its
'economic imperialism' (Lazear, 2000a) are due to the skilful
application of the relative price effect. It is based on extrinsic
motivation, i.e. on incentives coming from outside the person in
question. By way of contrast, major schools in psychology emphasise the
intrinsic motives coming from within the person.
Standard economic theory does not normally differentiate between
different sources of motivation. Motivation is just seen as a
manifestation of the underlying preference for the reward that is
associated with performing a task. Intrinsic motivation is assumed to be
an exogenously given constant, and often it is completely disregarded.
Motivation crowding theory tries to mediate between standard economic
thinking based on purely extrinsic motivation and psychological theories
by stipulating a systematic interaction between extrinsic and intrinsic
motivation.
For the analysis of economic issues, the 'hidden cost of
reward' has been generalised in two respects:
1) All interventions originating from outside the person under
consideration, i.e. both positive monetary rewards and regulations
accompanied by negative sanctions, may affect intrinsic motivation.
2) External interventions may crowd-out or crowd-in intrinsic
motivation (or leave it unaffected).
The figure below shows the interaction of the crowding-out effect
and the price effect graphically. S is the traditional supply curve
based on the relative price effect: raising the external reward for work
effort from O to R increases work effort from A to A' leading to a
location in point B. The crowding-out effect induces the supply curve to
shift towards the left to S'. Thus, raising the reward from O to R
leads to point C (instead of B). As the figure is drawn, the
crowding-out effect dominates the relative price effect, and raising the
reward from O to R reduces work effort from A to A". Once intrinsic
motivation has been crowded out completely, the normal supply curve
takes over again, and raising the reward unequivocally increases work
effort (movement along S').
[FIGURE 1 OMITTED]
The effects of external interventions on intrinsic motivation have
been attributed to two psychological processes. The first is impaired
self-determination. When individuals perceive an external intervention
as reducing their self-determination, intrinsic motivation is
substituted by extrinsic control. The locus of control shifts from
inside to outside of the person affected. Individuals, who are forced to
behave in a specific way by outside intervention, feel over-justified if
they maintain their intrinsic motivation. The second is impaired
self-esteem. When outside intervention carries the notion that the
actor's motivation is not acknowledged, his or her intrinsic
motivation is effectively rejected. The person affected feels that his
or her involvement and competence is not appreciated, which debases its
value. An intrinsically motivated person is deprived of the chance of
displaying his or her own interest and involvement in an activity when
someone else offers a reward, or orders them to do it. As a result of
impaired self-esteem, individuals reduce their effort.
The two processes identified allow us to derive the psychological
conditions under which the crowding-out effect appears:
1) External interventions crowd-out intrinsic motivation if the
individuals affected perceive them to be controlling. In that case, both
self-determination and self-esteem suffer, and the individuals react by
reducing their intrinsic motivation in the activity controlled.
2) External interventions crowd-in intrinsic motivation if the
individuals concerned perceive it as supportive. In that case,
self-esteem is fostered, and individuals feel that they are given more
freedom to act, thus enlarging self-determination.
Policy implications of motivation crowding
Crowding effects are potentially relevant in many different
economic areas. Examples are the labour market, where the effect of
higher compensation on work effort and, in particular,
performance-related pay are at issue; the natural environment, where the
effect of pricing instruments, such as pollution charges on
environmental ethics, is in question; social policy, where it must be
considered whether monetary incentives crowd out the notion of
responsibility for one's own fate; subsidies, where a possible
negative effect on entrepreneurship, innovation and creativity must be
taken into account; organisation theory, where the limits of the firm
must be reconsidered in view of the possible limits of relying purely on
extrinsic incentives; and contract theory, where relational or
'psychological contracts' may require intrinsic motivation and
hence crowding-out should be avoided (for further developments along
this line see Frey, 1997a; Osterloh and Frey, 2000).
Standard economics largely relies on the skilful application of the
price effect, and economists tend to overrate the power of payment-based
measures. An important example is pay-for-performance, which has become
the uncontested instrument for eliciting higher performance from
employees. Such a view is well supported by the theoretical economic
literature. According to principal-agency theory, incentives of employer
and employee are best aligned when the latter's pay is
performance-based. Recent empirical studies for a particular work
setting (mounting glass windshields in cars) are used to support the
presumed effectiveness of pay-for-performance (Lazear, 2000b). On this
basis, far-reaching claims were made on behalf of a general positive
effect of price incentives on work performance. Motivation crowding
theory serves as a warning against rash generalisations of conclusions
derived from simple task environments, where intrinsic motivation can be
assumed to play no role, and therefore the crowding-out effect is far
less likely to occur than under complex working conditions (see also Tom
Powdrill's article in this issue).
Empirical evidence
Laboratory evidence
A large number of laboratory experiments on the crowding effect
have been undertaken by psychologists. An extensive meta-study ably
surveys the 'hidden cost' phenomenon in social psychology
(Deci, Koestner and Ryan, 1999). 128 well-controlled experiments
exploring the effects of extrinsic rewards on intrinsic motivation
provide a clear and consistent result. Tangible rewards have a
significant negative effect on intrinsic motivation for interesting
tasks. On the other hand, verbal rewards have a significant positive
effect on intrinsic motivation. Tangible rewards do not crowd-out
intrinsic motivation when they are unexpected or not contingent on task
behaviour. Their overall conclusion for the use of rewards in the real
world is that rewards are able to influence people's behaviour,
which is presumably why they are so widely advocated. The main negative
effect of rewards is that they undermine self-regulation. As a
consequence of rewards, people take less responsibility for motivating
themselves.
Economists have also engaged in testing motivation crowding theory.
In laboratory evidence it has been shown that sanctions may crowd out
human altruism (Fehr and Rockenbach, 2003). Crowding-effects in contract
enforcement have been analysed in an evolutionary repeated contract game
model (Bohnet, Frey and Huck, 1999). The goal of this experiment is to
study how the participants' motivation and behaviour evolves,
depending on the institutional setting. When contracts are
near-perfectly enforced, first movers can rely on the legal system with
a high probability of being fined to deter second movers from breaching
the contract offered. Personal trust is hence replaced by institutional
trust. Low levels of legal enforcement, i.e. a low probability of
getting caught breaching the contract, tend to crowd-in intrinsic
motives to treat others fairly. When first movers in such a game decide
to offer a contract (despite the fact that both participants are aware
of the low probability of being fined for non-compliance), they signal
their trust that the second mover will not breach the contract. The
number of contracts offered increases in the course of the game. This is
contrary to standard economic expectations. An intermediate level of law
enforcement turns out to be most detrimental to intrinsically-motivated
trustworthiness and reciprocity-driven behaviour. First movers tend not
to offer contracts. Starting with the observation of a surprisingly high
rate of compliance by firms with pollution standards, Livernois and
McKenna (1999) discuss a similar problem. They find that under plausible
specifications of their model, higher compliance can be elicited with
lower fines for non-compliance.
The potentially negative effect on individual intrinsic motivation
of externally-imposed institutions is also found in a series of
experiments designed as contribution games to a pure public good
(Frohlich and Oppenheimer, 1998). Randomly reassigned individual payoffs
in the game lead to an expected increase in contributions to the public
good; on the other hand, the experimenters found strong evidence that
the institution of random payoffs itself shifted individual motivation
towards greater self-interest.
Field evidence
Work motivation
Motivation crowding theory has been subjected to econometric
studies in the case of work motivation. Barkema (1995) analyses the
behaviour of managers as agents in a firm. The managers are either
controlled by the parent company, i.e. by an impersonal relationship, or
by chief executive officers. It turns out that the former type of
supervision raises managers' performance, because intrinsic
motivation is little or not affected. In contrast, when the managers are
controlled by their firm's chief executive officer there is a
personalised relationship. Monitoring in this case tends to reduce the
agents' effort, as external intervention shifts the locus of
control towards external preferences, and the agents perceive that their
competence is not acknowledged by their superior. Intrinsic motivation
is crowded out. An econometric study looks at the voluntary sector (Frey
and Gotte, 1999). Intrinsic motivation is of great importance when it
comes to volunteering. The incidence of monetary rewards is found to
reduce the amount of volunteering. While the size of the rewards induces
individuals to provide more volunteer work, the mere fact that they
receive a payment significantly reduces their work efforts by
approximately four hours. The magnitude of these effects is
considerable. These findings have important implications for policy
regarding voluntary work. Direct incentives may backfire, leading to
less volunteering.
A comprehensive survey with decision-makers in the labour market
provides another avenue (Bewley, 1995). Practitioners seem well aware of
the possible traps of pay-for-performance schemes. They realise that
external intervention via monetary incentives should not be used as a
means of controlling, as it may undermine intrinsic motivations such as
work morale or creativity:
Managers claim that workers have so many opportunities
to take advantage of employers that it is not wise to
depend on coercion and financial incentives alone as
motivators. Also, employers want workers to operate
autonomously, show initiative, and use their imagination
while working, and workers who are scared or
disheartened do not do these things. (Bewley, 1995, 252)
The next section shows that crowding effects are of particular
importance outside the market sector.
Incentives and regulations in social and public policies
Day-care centres are confronted with the problem that parents
sometimes arrive late to pick up their children, which forces teachers
to stay after the official closing time. A typical economic approach
would suggest introducing a fine for collecting children late. Such a
punishment, economic theory predicts, induces parents to reduce the
occurrence of belatedly picking up their children. The effect of such a
policy has been studied for a day-care centre in Israel (Gneezy and
Rustichini, 2000a; see also 2000b). The number of late-coming parents
over a particular period of time was first recorded. In a second period,
extending over twelve weeks, a significant monetary fine for collecting
children late was introduced. After an initial learning phase, the
number of late-coming parents increased substantially, which is
consistent with the crowding-out effect. The introduction of a monetary
fine transforms the relationship between parents and teachers from a
non-monetary into a monetary one. As a result, the parents'
intrinsic motivation to keep to the time schedules is reduced or is
crowded-out altogether; the feeling now is that the teachers are
'paid' for the disamenity of having to stay longer. That
parents' intrinsic motivation was crowded out for good by the
introduction of a penalty system is supported by the fact that the
number of late-coming parents remained stable at the level prevailing
even after the fine was cancelled in the third phase.
Crowding-out effects were also identified with respect to
performance in the airline industry (Austin and Hoffer Gittell, 1999).
Different carriers use a variety of instruments to cope with delays.
Attributing a single delay as exactly as possible to its source (as
suggested by principal-agent theory) is negatively correlated with the
achieved end, namely the airline's on-time flight performance. The
most successful company in terms of departing on time is the one carrier
that uses the general term 'team delay' to indicate the source
of a delay caused by the personnel, independent of whether a single
employee, or one specific unit, was in fact responsible. A loose
attribution to the source of delay crowds-in the employees'
intrinsic motivation to help out other units and groups.
An econometric test of crowding theory refers to the important real
life issue of finding a site for locally unwanted projects (Frey and
Oberholzer-Gee, 1997). This is known as the 'not in my
backyard' or NIMBY problem. For many different projects and major
capital investments, a wide consensus exists that they are worth being
undertaken. But no community is prepared to tolerate the vicinity of,
for example, hazardous waste disposal facilities or airports. The
hypothesis that external incentives crowd-out civic duty or intrinsic
motivation, and therefore the willingness to accept the locally
undesired project, was tested by analysing the reaction to monetary
compensation offered for a nuclear waste repository in Switzerland. A
survey was undertaken among the population of the community, which was
chosen to harbour the site by the national government. More than half of
the respondents (50.8 per cent) agreed to have the nuclear waste
repository built in their community, 44.9 per cent opposed the siting,
and 4.3 per cent did not care where the facility was built. Thus, the
siting decision was widely accepted, in spite of the fact that a nuclear
waste repository is mostly seen as a heavy burden for the residents of
the host community. While 50.8 per cent of the respondents agreed to
accept the nuclear waste repository without compensation, the level of
acceptance dropped to 24.6 per cent when compensation was offered.
Compensation fundamentally alters the perceived nature of a siting
procedure. While external intervention, i.e. offering compensation,
manages to address concerns regarding the costs of a noxious facility,
it reduces the intrinsic motivation to permit the construction of such a
facility. In the case studied, this latter effect even outweighs the
benefits of external intervention, thereby reducing overall acceptance.
A corresponding effect was found for the siting of a nuclear repository
in Nevada, where raised tax rebates failed to increase acceptance
(Kunreuther and Easterling, 1990).
Crowding effects occur not only as a result of monetary
interventions but also of regulations. In a field experiment conducted
in Colombia, South America, a regulatory approach imposed from the
outside aimed at forestalling the exploitation of the local tropical
forest (which should have brought about welfare improvements according
to standard theory). However, it led to more egoistic behaviour on the
part of the population involved, thus intensifying forest destruction
(Cardenas, Stranlund and Willis, 1999). Introducing an external
regulation crowds-out the existing level of intrinsically motivated
other-regarding behaviour. Attempts to set incentives externally to lead
people towards a more efficient choice do in fact backfire.
Crowding theory can be applied to how constitutional and other
legal rules affect individual citizens. Civic virtue (a particular
manifestation of intrinsic motivation) is bolstered if the public laws
convey the notion that citizens are to be trusted. Such trust is
reflected in extensive rights and possibilities for political
participation. In contrast, a constitution implying a fundamental
distrust of its citizens, and seeking to discipline them, tends to
crowd-out civic virtue and undermines the support which citizens are
prepared to give to the basic law. The effects of such a distrustful
constitution manifest themselves in various ways. The citizens are
dissatisfied with the political system and respond by breaking the
constitution and its laws whenever they expect to be able to do so at a
low cost (Frey, 1997b). An important reaction to distrustful public laws
is a reduction of tax morale and, as a consequence, the evasion of taxes
(Feld and Frey, 2002). It has been well established that tax-paying
cannot be explained in an economically satisfactory way without taking
tax morale into account.
Crowding-out effects have also been observed for public laws and
institutions and for wages in the government sector. The fact that
government employees in many countries willingly work for a
significantly lower salary than their peers in the private sector may be
attributed to the higher intrinsic motivation of people seeking
employment in the public sector. An example would be those teachers who
want to work in state schools because they believe in the virtue of
public education for society. The increasing tendency to closely
supervise government employees, and to curtail their discretionary room,
has crowded out their work morale. This is consistent with a continuous
reduction of private sector wage premiums.
On a more general level, there is a cumulative body of research
indicating that people's perceptions of how they are treated by the
authorities strongly affect their evaluation of authorities and laws,
and their willingness to cooperate with them. Citizens who consider the
constitution and its laws, and the authorities upholding them, to be
fair and to treat them respectfully tend to be more compliant than those
with more negative perceptions of government (Tyler, 1990). In contrast,
the extensive use of adversary institutions for resolving public
conflicts as they prevail for example in the United States tends to
crowd-out civic virtue (Kelman, 1992).
Conclusion
This article shows that there is strong empirical evidence for
important crowding-out and crowding-in effects, which has been collected
in many different countries and time periods. This conclusion is based
on circumstantial evidence, laboratory evidence from both psychologists
and economists, and field evidence from econometric studies. The
evidence refers to a wide variety of areas of the economy and society:
monetary and symbolic rewards for undertaking various laboratory tasks;
the tendency to reciprocate in a laboratory setting, reflecting work
conditions in a firm; the amount of trust exhibited in a laboratory
situation of incomplete contracts; the reaction of managers to various
forms of supervision by their superiors; the readiness to offer
voluntary work; the observation of time schedules in day-care centres;
on-time flight performance in the airline industry; the readiness to
accept nuclear waste repositories (and other locally unwanted sites);
and the amount of civic virtue exhibited, in particular with respect to
fulfilling one's tax obligations (tax morale).
References
Austin, R. D. and Hoffer Gittell, J. (1999) Anomalies of High
Performance: Reframing Economic and Organizational Theories of
Performance Measurement, mimeo, Harvard Business School, Harvard
University.
Barkema, H. G. (1995) 'Do top managers work harder when they
are monitored?', Kyklos 48 (1): 19-42.
Becker, G. S. (1976) The Economic Approach to Human Behaviour,
Chicago, University of Chicago Press.
Bewley, T. F. (1995) 'A depressed labor market as explained by
participants', American Economic Review 85 (2): 250-4.
Bohnet, I., Huck, S. and Frey, B. S. (1999) More Order with Less
Law: On Contract Enforcement and Crowding, mimeo, Kennedy School of Law,
Harvard University.
Cardenas, J. C., Stranlund, J. and Willis, C. (1999) 'Local
environmental control and institutional crowding-out', mimeo,
Department of Resource-Economics, University of Massachusetts-Amherst.
Deci, E. L. (1971) 'Effects of externally mediated rewards on
intrinsic motivation', Journal of Personality and Social Psychology
18 (1): 105-15.
Deci, E. L. with Flaste, R. (1995) Why We Do What We Do: The
Dynamics of Personal Autonomy, New York, Putnam.
Deci, E. L., Koestner, R. and Ryan, R. M. (1999) 'A
meta-analytic review of experiments examining the effects of extrinsic
rewards on intrinsic motivation', Psychological Bulletin 125 (3):
627-68.
Deci, E. L. and Ryan, R. M. (1985) Intrinsic Motivation and
Self-Determination in Human Behaviour, New York, Plenum Press.
Fehr, E. and Rockenbach, B. (2003) 'Detrimental effects of
sanctions on human motivation', Nature 422: 137-40.
Feld, L. P. and Frey, B. S. (2002) 'Trust breeds trust: how
taxpayers are treated', Economics of Governance 3 (2): 87-99.
Frey, B. S. (1992) 'Tertium Datur: pricing, regulation and
intrinsic motivation', Kyklos 45 (2): 161-84.
Frey, B. S. (1997a) Not Just for the Money: An Economic Theory of
Personal Motivation, Cheltenham and Brookfield, Edward Elgar.
Frey, B. S. (1997b) 'A constitution for knaves crowds out
civic virtues', Economic Journal 107 (443): 1043-53.
Frey, B. S. (1999) Economics as a Science of Human Behaviour,
Boston, Dordrecht and London, Kluwer Academic Publishers.
Frey, B. S. and Gotte, L. (1999) 'Does pay motivate
volunteers?', unpublished manuscript, Institute for Empirical
Economic Research, University of Zurich.
Frey, B. S. and Oberholzer-Gee, F. (1997) 'The cost of price
incentives: an empirical analysis of motivation crowding-out',
American Economic Review 87 (4): 746-55.
Frohlich, N. and Oppenheimer, J. (1998) 'Optimal policies and
ethical behaviour: some unexpected contradictions', unpublished
manuscript, meeting of the Preferences Network Research Group.
Gneezy, U. and Rustichini, A. (2000a) 'Pay enough or
don't pay at all', Quarterly Journal of Economics 115 (3):
791-810.
Gneezy, U. and Rustichini, A. (2000b) 'A fine is a
price', Journal of Legal Studies 29 (1): 1-17.
Kelman, S. (1992) 'Adversary and cooperationist institutions
for conflict resolution in public policymaking', Journal of Policy
Analysis and Management 11 (2): 178-206.
Kunreuther, H. and Easterling, D. (1990) 'Are risk-benefit
trade-offs possible in siting hazardous facilities?', American
Economic Review 80 (2): 252-6.
Lazear, E. P. (2000a) 'Economic imperialism', Quarterly
Journal of Economics 115 (1): 99-146.
Lazear, E. P. (2000b) 'Performance pay and productivity',
American Economic Review 90 (5): 1346-61.
Livernois, J. and McKenna, C. J. (1999) 'Truth or
consequences: enforcing pollution standards with self-reporting',
Journal of Public Economics 71 (3): 415-40.
Osterloh, M. and Frey, B. S. (2000) 'Motivation, knowledge
transfer, and organizational forms', Organization Science 11 (5):
538-50.
Titmuss, R. M. (1970) The Gift Relationship, London, Allen &
Unwin.
Tyler, T. R. (1990) Why People Obey the Law, New Haven, Yale
University Press.
Bruno Frey is Distinguished Professor of Behavioural Science at
Warwick Business School, University of Warwick and Research Director of
CREMA, the Centre for Research in Economics, Management and the Arts,
Switzerland.
This article draws on a longer paper by Bruno S. Frey and Reto
Jegen, 'Motivation crowding theory: a survey of empirical
evidence', Journal of Economic Surveys 15 (5), 2001: 589-612.