Productivity and economic growth in Europe: a comparative industry perspective.
Timmer, Marcel P. ; Inklaar, Robert ; O'Mahony, Mary 等
THE BENEFITS OF THE MODERN KNOWLEDGE economy differ greatly between
advanced economies. The EU-15, that is the 15 European Union countries
that constituted the Union up to 2004, experienced a sharp slowdown in
labour productivity growth (measured as GDP per hour of work) from an
annual rate of 2.7 per cent during 1973-1995 to 1.5 per cent during
1995-2007. At the same time, labour productivity in the United States increased sharply from 1.3 per cent to 2.1 per cent between 1973-1995
and 1995-2007 respectively. While differences in the timing of business
cycles in the United States and the European Union may have some effect
on this comparison, they do not explain these divergent trend growth
rates.
The slower labour productivity growth rates in Europe compared to
the United States since 1995 reverse a long-term pattern of convergence.
This article first reviews the productivity and economic growth of
Europe since 1950, identifying three periods characterized by different
drivers of productivity. In the period 1950-1973, European growth was
characterized by a traditional catch--up pattern based on the imitation and adaptation of foreign technology, coupled with strong investment and
supporting institutions. However, the traditional postwar convergence
process came to an end by the mid-1970s (Crafts and Toniolo, 1996;
Eichengreen, 2007). Then, in the period from 1973 to 1995, output and
productivity growth in both Europe and the United States began to slow.
However, while the gap in output (and average per capita income) growth
rates narrowed between the two regions, Europe's productivity
growth remained much faster than in the United States. During this time,
Europe experienced a strong decline in labour force participation and a
fall in average hours worked, which in turn triggered a substitution of
capital for labour bringing capital-labour ratios in some major European
economies to levels well above those of the United States by the
mid-1990s. Since 1995, U.S. productivity growth accelerated until around
2004, after which it began to slow, whereas the rate of productivity
growth in Europe fell throughout the period, with the exception of two
brief positive spells during the peaks of the business cycle at the end
of the 1990s and around 2006-2007. Finally, during the Great Recession
in 2008-09, the productivity growth rates in Europe and the United
States rapidly diverged, as the United States saw a pickup in
productivity growth as the labour market shrunk well beyond that in the
European Union. The EU saw a decline in productivity parallel to the
contraction of the economy.
In the second section of this article, we focus on the European
growth experience, especially in the period from 1995 to 2007, using a
new and detailed database called the EU KLEMS Growth and Productivity
Accounts. (2) The level of detail in this database allows a discussion
of a number of developments during this period: changes in patterns of
capital-labour substitution; the increasing importance of investment in
information and communications technology; the use of more high--skilled
labour; the different dynamics across sectors, like those producing
information and communications technology, or manufacturing and services
more generally; and the diversity of productivity experiences across the
countries of Europe.
We show that the productivity slowdown in Europe since the
mid--1990s is mainly attributable to the slower emergence of the
knowledge economy compared to the United States. In the third section we
consider various explanations for the slowdown which are not mutually
exclusive: for example, lower growth contributions from investment in
information and communication technology in Europe, the relatively small
share of technology--producing industries in Europe, and slower
multifactor productivity growth (which can be viewed as a proxy for
advances in technology and innovation). Underlying these explanations
are issues related to the functioning of European labour markets and the
high level of product market regulation in Europe. This article
emphasizes the key role of market service sectors in accounting for the
productivity growth divergence between the two regions.
In the final section we look at some of the policy implications for
Europe to strengthen its productivity growth performance. The slowing
productivity growth and faltering emergence of the knowledge economy in
Europe since the mid--1990s has led to an ambitious action program of
the European Commission, called the 'Lisbon Agenda,' which was
executed during the first decade of the 21st century. Its goal was to
make Europe by 2010 'the most competitive and dynamic
knowledge--based economy in the world.' This program was succeeded
in 2010 by a new growth strategy, named 'Europe 2020,' which
aimed to make Europe a smart, sustainable and inclusive economy. Both
strategies have focused on the importance of employment growth and
innovation, especially through ambitious targets for research and
development, as well as environmentally friendly growth strategies. Both
agendas have so far not led to a reversal in Europe's downward
productivity trend.
Although we do not think there is one silver bullet to revive growth, we argue that the future for European productivity growth will
strongly depend on the performance of its services sector. The nations
of Europe also need to find their own ways of adjusting to the
opportunities and dislocations of the new information and communications
technologies. Thus, within the broader growth and competitiveness
agenda, we emphasize greater labour mobility and flexibility of service
product markets within and across countries as being especially
important.
[GRAPHIC 1 OMITTED]
European Productivity: 1950-2007
Europe's productivity growth performance relative to the
United States since 1950 can be usefully divided into three periods:
1950-1973, 1973-1995, and 1995-2007. The comparative European experience
in GDP per capita and in GDP per hour is illustrated in Chart 1. The
measures are compared relative to the U.S. levels and are adjusted for
differences in relative price levels using the GDP-based purchasing
power parities for 2005 from the OECD. We also added the latest years
for which data are available, 2008 and 2009, on the basis of provisional national accounts estimates.
European Catch-Up: 1950-1973
During the first period, from 1950-73, rapid labour productivity
growth in the European Union went together with catching--up in terms of
per capita income levels with the United States. The reasons for this
dual catching-up process during the 1950s and 1960s have been
extensively discussed in the literature and can broadly be divided into
two groups: technology imitation and new institutions (for example,
Boltho, 1982; Crafts and Toniolo, 1996; Eichengreen, 2007).
Imitation of technology and incremental innovation allowed European
countries to speed up both output and productivity growth quite rapidly
following the Depression of the 1930s and the devastation of
Europe's economies during World War II. Many European countries
could draw upon their legacy as industrializing nations during the
nineteenth and early twentieth century. Compared to other parts of the
world, Europe after World War II already had a relatively well--educated
population and a strong set of institutions for generating human capital
and financial wealth, which allowed a rapid recovery of investment and
absorption of new technologies developed elsewhere, notably in the
United States.
This process was strengthened by the emergence of a new set of
institutions in the area of wage bargaining (Eichengreen, 2007).
Although there were important differences between countries, essentially
these arrangements involved limiting wage demands in exchange for a
rapid redeployment of profits for investment. Through this arrangement,
a consensus was developed between workers and capitalists that benefited
both productivity and per capita income. In addition, European capital
markets favored the emergence of large 'national champion'
companies while at the same time (notably in Germany) supporting a
strong system of small- and medium--sized enterprises. In several
northwest European countries, the education system tended to emphasize
technical and vocational training. These characteristics of European
institutions largely lasted until the end of the 1960s, after which
labour markets became increasingly tight, leading to substantially
higher wage demands.
The Productivity Slowdown: 1973-1995
The 'golden age' of post-World War II growth came to an
end rather abruptly in the early 1970s, followed by a period of
significantly slower growth lasting almost two decades on both
continents (Maddison, 1987). Table 1 shows that while U.S. GDP growth
slowed from 3.9 per cent on average per year in the period 1950-1973 to
2.9 per cent in the period 1973-1995, EU-15 growth slowed substantially
more from 4.9 per cent in the period 1950-1973 to only 2.2 per cent in
the period 1973-1995. However, average growth rates of per capita income
between the United States and the EU-15 became quite similar at 1.8 per
cent (for the EU) and 1.9 per cent (for the United States) between 1973
and 1995. (3)
Looking back at Chart 1, one striking observation is that while per
capita income in Europe hovered between 70 to 80 per cent of the U.S.
level between 1973 and 1995, the productivity gap between Europe and the
United States continued to narrow. Indeed, average annual labour
productivity growth in the EU-15 was still more than twice as fast as in
the United States, at 2.7 per cent in the EU-15 against 1.3 per cent in
the United States from 1973 to 1995. Thus, the labour productivity gap
virtually closed from more than 30 percentage points in 1973 to only 7.6
percentage points in 1995, as shown in Table 2. In some European
countries, including Belgium, France, Germany, and the Netherlands, GDP
per hour worked was even higher than the U.S. level in 1995. In Europe,
the combination of an unchanged gap in per capita income and a narrowing
gap in labour productivity was related--by accounting identity--to a
decline in labour force participation rates and a fall in working hours
per person employed. Working hours per capita in the European Union
countries declined from 11 per cent above the U.S. level in 1973 to 84
per cent of the U.S. level by 1995, as shown in Table 2.
A substantial literature has explored why Europe's labour
market institutions have led to less work, in particular during the
period 1973-1995. Blanchard (2004) stresses how the trade-off between
preferences for leisure and work developed differently in Europe and the
United States. Prescott (2004) estimates that the role of income taxes
can account for virtually all of the difference in labour participation
rates across European countries. Nickell (1997) shows that in addition
to high payroll taxes, other labour market issues, such as generous
unemployment benefits, poor educational standards at the bottom, and
high unionization with little coordination also play an important role
in accounting for Europe's rise in unemployment since the
mid-1970s. Europe's welfare state rapidly expanded in the 1970s,
causing an increase in labour cost, a strong bias towards insiders in
the labour market, and an increase in structural unemployment, in
particular among youth and older workers.
One result of Europe's slowing growth in labour input was a
rapid increase in capital intensity, as the rise in wages led to the
substitution of capital for labour. Table 2 shows that Europe's
capital stock per hour worked was at 75.3 per cent of the U.S. level in
1973, but had reached 103.6 per cent of the U.S. level by 1995. European
countries with a higher capital stock per hour worked than the United
States in 1995 include Austria, Belgium, Finland, France, Germany, and
the Netherlands. As a result, the high labour productivity levels in the
European Union by the mid-1990s should be interpreted with care.
Economists draw a distinction between labour productivity, which
can be measured by GDP per hour worked, and multifactor productivity,
which relates to the level of output after accounting for labour as well
as capital inputs. As we will argue in more detail below, even though
Europe experienced relatively strong growth in labour productivity, the
growth in multifactor productivity was much lower. This indicates that
Europe's higher labour productivity growth during this period may
not have been so much the result of catch-up, access to superior
technology, or even faster innovation, but can be largely attributable
to accumulated labour market rigidities.
Europe's Falling Behind: 1995-2007
Since the mid-1990s, the patterns of productivity growth in Europe
and the United States changed dramatically. In the United States,
average annual labour productivity growth accelerated from 1.3 per cent
during the period 1973-95 to 2.1 per cent during 1995-2007. Comparing
the same two time periods, annual labour productivity growth in the
European Union declined from 2.7 to 1.5 per cent. By 2007, GDP per hour
worked in the EU was 13 percentage points below the U.S. level, while
capital intensity levels remained relatively high, above the U.S.
levels, suggesting that the productivity adjustment was mainly made
through a slowdown in multifactor productivity growth (Table 2).
The slowdown in labour productivity may be related to the rapid
growth in labour input in many European countries. During the late 1980s
and the 1990s, several European countries introduced labour market
reforms and instigated active labour market interventions to bring
long-term unemployed people back into the workforce and raise the
participation rate. The slowdown in productivity growth and the
stability in capital intensity in Europe realtive to the United States
since 1995 suggest the possibility that just as limited employment
growth accompanied higher labour productivity in Europe in the 1973-1995
period, perhaps that pattern reversed itself in the more recent time
period (Gordon, 2004).
While in the short run labour productivity growth may decline due
to the dampening of real wage growth and consequent reduction in the
rate of substitution of capital for labour, it is unlikely that the
elasticity of labour input with respect to productivity is large in the
medium and long term. According to Blanchard (2004), the
employment-productivity trade-off would only exist under the assumption
of stagnant output growth, which is an unrealistic assumption for the
medium and long run.
Indeed, despite slowing productivity growth, the European Union has
not experienced a slowdown in GDP growth since 1995. A related argument
is that increases in employment have raised the share of low-skilled
workers in the workforce, causing labour productivity to decline.
However, there are no signs of a significant decline in the growth of
the skill level of the labour force, which would presumably arise if the
underlying cause was a large rise in low-skilled labour in Europe. On
the contrary, the average skill-level of the employed labour force
continued to improve since the mid-1990s. Thus, the labour market is
unlikely to be the main explanation for the slowdown in productivity
growth.
When put into a comparative perspective, the productivity slowdown
in Europe is all the more disappointing as U.S. productivity growth has
accelerated since the mid-1990s. The causes of the strong U.S.
productivity resurgence have been extensively discussed (see, for
example, Jorgenson, Ho, and Stiroh, 2008). In the mid-1990s, there was a
burst of higher productivity in industries producing information and
communications technology equipment, and a capital-deepening effect from
investing in information and communications technology assets across the
economy. In turn, these changes were driven by the rapid pace of
innovation in information and communications technologies, fuelled by
the precipitous and continuing fall in semiconductor prices. With some
delay, arguably due to the necessary changes in production processes and
organizational practices, there was also a multifactor productivity
surge in industries using these new information and communications
technologies--in particular in market services industries (Triplett and
Bosworth, 2006).
In Europe, the advent of the knowledge economy has been slower
since the mid-1990s. In the next section, we exploit the EU KLEMS
database on industry-level growth accounts to develop a better view of
how inputs and productivity have contributed to the change in the growth
performance of European countries since 1995, in particular in
comparison with the United States.
Divergence During the Great Recession: 2007-2009
In 2008-09, advanced economies were hit by the deepest recession
since the 1930s. In 2008, GDP growth in the EU-15 slowed to 0.3 per cent
and then dramatically fell to -4.3 per cent in 2009. The United States
experienced a standstill in GDP growth in 2008, but contracted less
severely than the EU-15, at -2.6 per cent, in 2009 (Table 3).
Traditionally productivity is pro-cyclical, which implies that during a
downturn productivity growth slows or even declines as initially output
growth slips more than the growth in employment. Businesses typically
hold on to their staff (labour hoarding) and equipment at least for a
while to see how the economy will develop before laying off people or
scrapping machines. Adjustments are usually made through lowering
capacity utilization and reducing working hours of staff.
This typical pattern of pro-cyclicality in productivity can be
observed for Europe's performance during the recession. The EU-15
showed a slowdown in productivity growth of -0.7 per cent per year from
2007-2009. The United States, however, showed an atypical increase in
productivity of 1.6 per cent per year over the same period (0.8 per cent
in 2008 and 2.5 per cent in 2009). As the U.S. recessions of 1990-91 and
2001-02 also exhibited such counter-cyclicality going into the
recession, various explanations have been put forward for the change in
the relationship between output, productivity, and employment in the
United States. These range from labour market-based explanations,
pointing at increased flexibility in hiring and firing, technology-based
explanations pointing at the role of ICT in continuing productivity
increases during recessions, and explanations related to financial
market incentives and executive compensation. The latter may have
stimulated short term gains in performance over long term concerns with
regard to the sources of growth in U.S. companies.
While there may be no unique explanation for the continued
productivity growth in the United States vis-a-vis the typical
pro-cyclicality in the European Union during the recession, it should
also be pointed out that Europe itself has not shown a unique pattern of
productivity growth. For example, in Germany labour productivity growth
declined by 2.4 per cent from 2007-2009, as government and businesses
chose to use shorttime working schemes and other instruments to dampen
the threat of large layoffs. Total hours worked in Germany therefore
only fell by 1.4 per cent. In contrast, in Spain, large structural
labour market problems led to massive layoffs of temporary and migrant employees in tourism, construction and agriculture, causing a drop in
hours worked of 6.3 per cent between 2007 and 2009, but a productivity
improvement of 3.3 per cent.
Clearly there is no silver bullet to deal with productivity issues
during recessions, and ultimately the long-term strength of an
economy's economic structure, as measured by its industry
composition and sources of growth, determines its long term growth
potential.
Growth Accounting for Europe and the United States
To assess the contribution of various inputs to GDP growth, we
apply the neoclassical growth accounting framework pioneered by Solow
(1957) and further developed by Jorgenson and associates (Jorgenson and
Griliches, 1967; Jorgenson, Gollop, and Fraumeni, 1987). Using this
framework, measures of output growth can be decomposed into the
contributions of inputs and productivity within a consistent accounting
framework. This approach allows researchers to assess the relative
importance of labour, capital, and intermediate inputs to growth, and to
derive measures of multifactor productivity growth.
The output contribution of an input is measured by the growth rate
of the input, weighted by that input's income shares. Under
neoclassical assumptions, the income shares reflect the output
elasticity of each input, and assuming constant returns to scale, they
sum to one. The portion of output growth not attributable to inputs is
the multifactor productivity residual. Multifactor productivity
indicates the efficiency with which inputs are being used in the
production process, and includes disembodied technological change, along
with changes in returns to scale and in mark-ups. Multifactor
productivity, as a residual measure, also includes measurement errors
and the effects from unmeasured output and inputs, such as research and
development and other intangible investments, including organizational
improvements (Corrado, Hulten and Sichel, 2009; van Ark et al., 2009).
Our growth decompositions are based on the November 2009 release of
the EU KLEMS database. This database provides harmonised measures of
economic growth, productivity, employment creation, and capital
formation at a detailed industry level for European Union member states,
Japan, and the United States from 1980 to 2007. In particular, this
database contains unique industry-level measures of the skill
distribution of the work force and a detailed asset decomposition of
investment in physical capital. Labour input reflects changes in hours
worked, but also changes in labour composition in terms of age, gender,
and educational qualifications over time. Physical capital is decomposed
into six asset categories. Three of the asset categories are related to
information and communications capital--including information technology
hardware, communication equipment, and software--and three are related
to capital that does not involve information and communications
technology--machinery and equipment, transport equipment, and
nonresidential structures. Residential capital, which does not
contribute in any direct way to productivity gains, is excluded from the
analysis.
The EU KLEMS database makes it possible for the first time to
compare and analyze the role of high-skilled labour and information and
communications technology capital for productivity growth at an industry
level between countries. Our focus here is on the market economy, which
means that we exclude health and education services, as well as public
administration and defense. This exclusion implies a faster acceleration
of output growth in both the European Union and the United States since
1995 than for the total economy reported in the previous section, but
the difference in pace of acceleration between the two regions does not
change. Also, in the remainder of this discussion, the European Union
only includes 10 countries, excluding Greece, Ireland, Luxembourg,
Portugal, and Sweden from our original 15, because no industry-level
accounts back to 1980 were available for these five countries.
Table 4 provides a summary of the contributions to growth of factor
inputs and multifactor productivity to labour productivity growth in the
market economy in the ten European Union countries and in the United
States for the periods 1980-1995 and 1995-2007. When comparing the
period before and after 1995, the annual growth rate of output in the
European Union accelerates, and the growth differential relative to the
United States drops from 1.2 percentage points (2.1 per cent in Europe
versus 3.3 per cent in the United States) to 1.0 percentage point (2.5
per cent in Europe versus 3.5 per cent in the United States). As
described in the previous section, hours worked in the European Union
grew rapidly after 1995, to some extent making up for the shortfall in
the earlier period. In contrast, the growth in hours worked slowed down
substantially in the United States-in particular after 2000-even though
the average growth rate in hours was comparable to that of the European
Union between 1995-2007. As a result, labour productivity growth in the
U.S. market economy increased significantly (0.6 percentage points)
compared to a large slowdown in Europe after 1995 (0.9 percentage
points).
Table 4 shows that changes in labour composition contributed
0.2-0.3 percentage points to labour productivity growth both in the
European Union and the United States during this entire time period.
Even though this contribution is small, its positive sign implies that
the process of transformation of the labour force to higher skills has
proceeded at roughly equal rates in Europe and the United States, thus
confirming the observation above that Europe has not raised its share of
low-skill workers. Instead, the upward trend in the skill content of the
workforce shows that newcomers on the labour market have had on average
more schooling than the existing labour force.
Concerning the total contribution of capital deepening to labour
productivity growth, measured by capital services per hour, Table 4
shows somewhat larger differences between the European Union and the
United States compared to labour composition. This contribution declined
in Europe while rising in the United States. between the two time
periods. The specific contribution of information and communications
technology per working hour in Europe has been lower than in the United
States, and since 1995, it accelerated more slowly (Timmer and van Ark,
2005). This slower uptake in deepening of information and communications
technology capital is in part related to the overall decline in the rate
of growth of capital-labour ratios across Europe since the mid-1990s, as
European employment grew rapidly.
The largest difference between the European Union and the United
States shown in Table 4 is in the contribution of multifactor
productivity growth. Whereas multifactor productivity growth in the
United States accelerated by half a percentage point from 0.7 per cent
from 1980-1995 to 1.2 per cent from 1995-2007, it fell by the same
degree from 1.1 to 0.6 per cent between these two periods in the
European Union. As a residual measure, multifactor productivity has
multiple interpretations, but in some way it does reflect the overall
efficiency of the production process. Its reduced growth rate is
therefore a major source of concern across Europe.
It should be stressed that the multifactor productivity growth
differential between the EU and the United States was especially strong
between 1995 and 2004. The differences became significantly smaller
after 2004 when Europe saw an acceleration in multifactor productivity
growth in the market economy from 0.4 per cent (from 1995-2004) to 1.2
per cent (from 2004-2007) due to a cyclical peak, whereas U.S.
multifactor productivity growth slowed from 1.4 per cent to 0.4 per cent
between the two periods.
When looking at these growth accounts from the perspective of the
emerging knowledge economy, one might focus on the summed contributions
of three factors: direct effects from investments in information and
communication technology; changes in labour composition mostly driven by
greater demand for skilled workers; and multifactor productivity growth,
which--as indicated above--might include the impact of intangible
investments such as organizational changes related to the use of
information technology. Table 4 shows that the combined contribution of
these three factors to labour productivity growth declined by 0.5
percentage points in Europe between the two time periods, from 1.8
percentage points from 1980-1995 to 1.3 percentage points from
1995-2007. In contrast, in the U.S. economy the contribution of these
three knowledge economy components increased from 1.7 percentage points
from 1980-1995 to 2.4 percentage points from 1995-2007.
There is a large variation in labour productivity growth across
European countries. Similar to the rows in Table 4, the first column of
Table 5 shows the growth rate of output for 10 European countries over
the 1995-2007 time period. The second and third columns divide that
growth in output into changes in hours worked and changes in output per
hour, or labour productivity. Columns 4-7 divide up the growth in labour
productivity into the contributions from four factors: changes in labour
composition; investments in information and communication technology
capital; investments in other types of physical capital; and multifactor
productivity.
One key observation to be drawn from this table is that the main
difference in labour productivity growth between individual European
economies and the United States is to be found in multifactor
productivity, not in differences in the intensity of growth of the
production factors. Indeed the bottom row shows that the standard
deviation for multifactor productivity growth across the set of
countries is by far the largest, with multifactor productivity growth
ranging from -0.6 per cent in Spain to 2.8 per cent in Finland. By way
of illustration, the difference in the contribution of capital deepening
in information and communications technologies between a high investor
like the United States and a low investor like Italy explains 0.7
percentage points out of a labour productivity growth difference of 2.2
percentage points between those two countries during 1995-2007. The
remaining 1.5 percentage point difference is (more than) accounted for
by the differences in multifactor productivity growth. Differences in
multifactor productivity growth also seem to have driven the divergence
in labour productivity growth between European countries. In Belgium,
multifactor productivity growth has been close to zero per cent per
year, and in Denmark, Italy, and Spain, it is even negative. Only
Finland significantly exceeded the U.S. growth rate of multifactor
growth in the market economy (2.8 per cent versus 1.2 per cent).
How should we explain the large differences in multifactor
productivity growth across countries? In the next section, a breakdown
of the aggregate market economy measures by industry allows us to focus
attention on the performance of the market services sector.
Structural Change and Sectoral Productivity Growth
During the postwar period Europe has experienced a large shift of
production and employment from manufacturing and other goods-producing
industries (such as agriculture and mining) towards services. Market
services include a wide variety of activities, ranging from trade and
transportation services, to financial and business services, and also
hotels, restaurants, and personal services. Over the period 1980-2007,
the share of labour input going to manufacturing has typically declined
by one-third or more in most countries. Market services now account for
almost half of the market economy employment in all countries. The share
of total labour hours going to market services is not much lower in
Europe than in the United States. While there are differences across
European countries, even in Germany, a country in which manufacturing
traditionally plays an important role, the number of hours worked in
market services is now more than 2.5 times larger than in manufacturing.
(4)
The growing importance of market services is the result of a number
of interacting forces (Schettkatt and Yocarini, 2006). Higher per capita
income leads to higher demand for services. There is also an increasing
marketization of traditional household production activities, including
meal preparation, cleaning, and care assistance. Finally, many
manufacturing firms are outsourcing aspects of business services, trade,
and transport activities. Whatever the underlying causes of the shift
from manufacturing to services, it has important implications for
productivity growth. Traditionally, manufacturing activities have been
regarded as the locus of innovation and technological change, and thus
the central source of productivity growth. For example, more productive
manufacturing was the key to post-World War II productivity growth in
Europe through a combination of economies of scale, capital
intensification, and incremental innovation. More recently, rapid
technological change in computer and semiconductor manufacturing
seemingly reinforces the predominance of innovation in the manufacturing
sector. In contrast, the increasing weight of services in output was
thought to slow aggregate productivity growth. Baumol (1967) called this
the 'cost disease of the service sector.' The diagnosis of the
disease argues that productivity improvements in services are less
likely than in goods-producing industries because most services are
inherently labour-intensive, making it difficult to substitute capital
for labour in service industries. Although Baumol originally mainly
referred to services activities like education, health, and public
services, it was widely believed to hold for many other services sectors
as well. This hypothesis has subsequently been disputed in the
literature (for example, Triplett and Bosworth, 2006) and, as the
following discussion will show, is not supported by the evidence from
the EU KLEMS data.
To evaluate the effect of structural changes on productivity
growth, we need to look at the contributions of individual sectors on
the aggregate economy. Table 6 shows labour productivity growth for the
market economy split into contributions from labour productivity growth
in the information and communications technology production sector
(including production of electrical machinery and telecommunication services), goods production (including agriculture, mining,
manufacturing other than electrical machinery, utilities, and
construction), and the market services sector (including trade, hotels
and restaurants, transport services, financial and business services,
and social and personal services), each weighted by its share in value
added, along with an adjustment in the final column for the reallocation of hours between industries with different productivity.
Table 6 shows that slow productivity growth in market services is
not a universal truth, even among advanced countries with large service
sectors. First, productivity growth in market services has been much
faster in the United States than in Europe. At an average annual labour
productivity growth rate of 1.2 per cent, market services contributed
only 0.6 percentage points to labour productivity growth in Europe from
1995-2007. In contrast, labour productivity in market services increased
at 3.0 per cent in the United States, contributing 1.8 percentage points
to U.S. productivity growth. Second, within Europe two countries-the
Netherlands and the United Kingdom-also showed rapid productivity growth
in market services. Market services in the United Kingdom contributed
almost as much to aggregate labour productivity growth as in the United
States, mainly due to strong performance in trade and business services
industries. (5) In contrast, Italy and Spain show almost zero
contributions from market services to aggregate labour productivity
growth. Previous studies on the growth differential between Europe and
the United States also stressed the differentiating role of market
services (O'Mahony and van Ark, 2003; Losch, 2006; Inklaar, Timmer,
and van Ark, 2008).
The importance of market services for the productivity growth gap
between Europe and the United States dwarfs the differences for other
major sectors. Even though the United States has a somewhat bigger share
in information and communications technology-producing sectors, the
productivity growth rates in these sectors are not dramatically
different. As a result, the effect on the aggregate growth differential
is only 0.4 percentage points (0.8 per cent in the United States
compared to 0.4 per cent in Europe). Goods production seems to be
somewhat more important for aggregate productivity growth in Europe than
in the United States. The contribution from labour productivity growth
in goods production in Europe is about the same as that of market
services, despite the former's relative size of only one-third of
market services value added. For example, in France and Germany,
manufacturing industries like machinery and car manufacturing are still
important sources of productivity growth. In Spain and Italy, lackluster productivity performance is not only due to slow growth in market
services, but also in manufacturing, as traditional labour-intensive
sectors have faced a particularly tough challenge from increasing
low-wage competition from eastern Europe and China.
A more in-depth focus on these industries reveals that
cross-Atlantic growth differences were especially large in distributive trade and in business services. This is shown in Table 7 where we focus
on the contribution of four major groups of market services industries,
namely distributive trade (including retail and wholesale trade and
transport services), financial services, business services and personal
services (including community and social services). In Europe, the
distribution sector contributed 0.7 percentage points to labour
productivity growth in aggregate market services during 1995-2005,
compared to 1.5 percentage points in the United States. In business
services a similar gap existed as this sector had a negative
contribution in Europe while it contributed 0.7 percentage points in the
United States. Interestingly in the light of the global financial crisis
in 2007-08, the measured contribution from the finance sector to
aggregate labour productivity growth was not disproportionate, adding
about 0.5 percentage points in both the EU and US. The contribution of
personal services was negligible as productivity growth in this sector
was close to zero in both regions, echoing Baumol's cost-disease
hypothesis.
Drilling more deeply into the data, it turns out that for
distribution services and business services, multifactor productivity
and not factor intensity was the key to the productivity growth
differential between Europe and the United States. Differences in
'factor intensity', which include the total contribution from
changes in labour composition and deepening of all types of capital,
appear very small. The fuelling of U.S. multifactor productivity growth
from trade, finance, and business services is confirmed in studies by
Jorgenson, Ho, and Stiroh (2005) and Triplett and Bosworth (2006).
Recently the release of a comprehensive revision of GDP by industry
data for the United States by the Bureau of Economic Analysis has led to
significant changes in the productivity estimates for the United States,
especially in the services sector. This raises the question of whether
the productivity advantage for services will still be observed in the
latest data. A comparison of the data suggests that the revision of the
labour productivity growth rates for market services is small for the
past decade, that is, from 2.8 per cent pre-revision to 2.6 per cent
post-revision from 1998-2007 (EU KLEMS, November 2009 release; BEA,
2010).
Patterns of Growth: Yeast versus Mushrooms
With the availability of more industry-level data, an increasingly
detailed picture of the patterns and sources of growth has become
feasible. At the same time, there is a need to find insightful ways to
summarize the wealth of industry detail. The most straightforward
approach is to aggregate industries into larger groups and analyse the
performance of these groups as a whole. However, by doing this we run
the risk of possibly missing sizeable within-group heterogeneity.
Alternatively, one can provide graphs with detailed industry data. But
these graphs do not provide a clear interpretation of the overall growth
process. So to complement our discussion we use in this section the
Harberger diagram as a way to characterise the growth pattern of all
industries (Harberger, 1998). Specifically, we use these diagrams and a
number of summary statistics to characterise how widespread (yeast) or
localised (mushroom) capital deepening and productivity growth is.
These Harberger diagrams can be used to shed light on some of the
hypotheses about productivity growth in the United States and other
countries that have circulated in recent years. At various points, it
has been suggested that the acceleration of US labour productivity
growth and/or the difference with other countries can be traced mostly
to ICT production, the strong performance of a small number of ICT-using
industries or a broad set of services industries. Harberger diagrams
provide an intuitive and standardised way to determine how widespread
growth and changes in growth are within an economy. They can also be
used to determine how evenly new technology spreads across an economy.
For instance, we use Harberger diagrams to analyse whether ICT capital
is growing at similar or very different rates across industries.
[GRAPHIC 2 OMITTED]
The Harberger diagram provides a convenient graphical summary of
the industry pattern of growth. The diagram shows the cumulative
contribution of the industries to aggregate growth on the y-axis and the
cumulative share of these industries on the x-axis. It is based on a
data set of industries and their contributions to aggregate growth
calculated as outlined in Timmer et al. (2010, Chapter 5). The
industries are first ranked by growth rate to ensure a concave diagram,
so the fastest growing industries are to be found near the origin. The
resulting pattern can have a more yeasty or mushroom character,
depending on the number of industries contributing positively to
aggregate growth and the distribution of growth rates. Growth is yeasty
when it is broad-based and takes place in many industries or firms.
Mushroom growth indicates a pattern in which only a limited number of
industries contribute positively to aggregate growth. (6)
For illustration purposes, Chart 2 shows two examples of Harberger
diagrams. For easy comparison, the sum of the industry contributions is
the same for both diagrams, implying equal aggregate growth. Diagram A
is an example of mushroom-type growth. Not all industries have positive
growth, as the downward sloping part of the diagram implies some
industries have negative growth. The second diagram is an example of
more yeasty, balanced growth. It is closer to the straight diagonal
line, so the growth rates of the industries are relatively close to each
other and in addition, all industries have positive growth.
Diagrams such as these can be useful to quickly identify how
important certain industries are in achieving growth. To compare
diagrams of different shapes and with different levels of aggregate
growth, Inklaar and Timmer (2007) devised summary statistics of the
Harberger diagram. Chart 2 illustrates that the general shape of the
diagram can be summarized by three statistics:
* Aggregate growth, which is the sum of industry contributions,
* the cumulative share of industries with positive contributions,
as an indicator of the pervasiveness of growth (7) and
* the curvature as measured by the area between the diagram and the
diagonal line (the shaded areas in Chart 2) divided by the total area
beneath the diagram. This relative area measure lies between zero and
one; it is zero when all industries have equal growth and when industry
growth rates start to diverge, the relative area increases to a maximum
of one. (8)
In Table 8 we report aggregate multifactor productivity growth, the
share of industries with positive multifactor productivity growth and
the relative area underneath the Harberger diagram for European
countries and the United States before and after 1995. The column with
aggregate multifactor productivity growth shows a familiar picture of a
decline in multifactor productivity growth in most European countries
and an increase in the United States. What is novel is that in almost
all cases the decline in aggregate multifactor productivity growth
coincides with an increase in the number of industries showing declines
in multifactor productivity growth. To illustrate: before 1995, almost
three quarters of the industries in Europe had positive multifactor
productivity growth while after 1995 this share had dropped below 60 per
cent. Furthermore, the relative area statistic increased from 0.47 to
0.69, implying that growth had become more concentrated among a few
industries, i.e. had become more mushroom-like. Multifactor productivity
growth in the United States is marked by the reverse pattern: increasing
aggregate growth, a larger share of industries with positive multifactor
productivity growth and a more yeast-like pattern as evidenced by the
decline in relative area. How ever, this is not a uniform relationship.
For instance, in Spain multifactor productivity growth declined (and
even became negative), but the relative area declined as well, implying
a broad-based decline. Multifactor productivity growth in Belgium after
1995 also stands out: while aggregate growth is zero, almost 40 per cent
of industries had positive multifactor productivity growth. This is also
an illustration of extremely mushroom-like growth as the relative area
is 1.
[GRAPHIC 3 OMITTED]
[GRAPHIC 4 OMITTED]
Chart 3 shows the multifactor productivity Harberger diagrams for
the period 1995-2005 for Europe and the United States. European growth
is characterised by a mix of industries contributing positively and
negatively to aggregate growth. In the United States, the multifactor
productivity growth process is clearly more yeast-like with only a few
industries showing negative growth and the positive contributions adding
up to almost 1.6 per cent. These diagrams therefore suggest that the
growth gap between Europe and the United States is broad-based: numerous
industries show positive growth in the United States and negative growth
in Europe. The alternative would have been a more mushroom-like pattern,
for instance if the growth gap could have been fully attributed to a
larger contribution from a limited set of industries like ICT production
and retail trade.
Chart 4 shows the pattern of the European multifactor productivity
slowdown after 1995 in Harberger diagrams for both periods. A common
factor in both periods is the large negative contribution from business
services (the rightmost industry in the diagram in both periods).
However, for the 1980-1995 period, the contribution was smaller since
the average value added share of business services was only 10 per cent
rather than the 15 per cent for 1995-2005. In addition, the 1995-2005
period shows considerably more industries with multifactor productivity
declines. These declines show up in some manufacturing industries but
also in construction and motor vehicle trade. In contrast, in some
industries growth held up well, such as in ICT manufacturing,
telecommunication services and utilities. The result of this is a more
mushroom-like multifactor productivity growth process.
The Future of European Productivity Growth
Since the mid-1990s, the European Union has experienced a slowdown
in productivity growth, at a time when productivity growth in the United
States accelerated significantly. The resurgence of productivity growth
in the United States appears to have been a combination of high levels
of investment in rapidly progressing information and communications
technology in the second half of the 1990s, followed by rapid
productivity growth in the market services sector of the economy in the
first half of the 2000s. Conversely, the productivity slowdown in
European countries is largely the result of slower multifactor
productivity growth in market services, particularly in trade, finance,
and business services.
European economies therefore face major challenges if they are to
increase economic performance and living standards through productivity
growth. One negative factor is the projected slowdown in labour growth
during the 2010-2020 period, which is the result of the rapid ageing of
the population and limited attraction for skilled immigration. This
calls for an even larger emphasis on productivity, meaning that Europe
needs to find mechanisms to exploit innovations to achieve greater
multifactor productivity growth, especially in services. Unfortunately,
the traditional catch-up and convergence model of the 1950s and 1960s
may not help Europe get back on track. Because Europe had reached the
productivity frontier by the mid-1990s, it now may require a new model
of innovation and technological change to make better use of a
country's own innovative capabilities (Acemoglu, Aghion, and
Zilibotti, 2006). Arguably innovations in services are more difficult to
imitate than 'hard' technologies based in manufacturing. The
greater emphasis on human resources, organizational change, and other
intangible investments are strongly specific to individual firms.
Moreover, the firm receives most of the benefits of such changes, which
reduces the legitimization for government support such as research and
development and innovation subsidies to support 'technology'
transfer in services. Service activities also tend to be less
standardized and more customized than manufacturing production; they
depend strongly on the interaction with the consumer and are therefore
more embedded in national and cultural institutions. In this situation,
the spillover of technologies across firms and nations becomes much more
difficult. Recent work by Bloom and Van Reenen (2007) links corporate
management practices to productivity. They find significant
cross-country differences in corporate management practice, with U.S.
firms being better managed than European firms on average, as well as
significant within-country differences as firm distributions have a long
tail of badly managed firms. In other words, a simple
'copying' of practices from other countries--or even from
other firms within the same country--is not the most likely way for
European service companies to attain greater productivity growth.
Second, a more flexible approach towards labour, product, and
capital markets in Europe would allow resources to flow to their most
productive uses. Crafts (2006) discusses the increasing evidence that
restrictive product market regulations, in particular those limiting new
entry, hinder technology transfer and have a negative impact on
productivity, although most studies relate only to manufacturing
industries. The diversity in productivity growth across European
countries shows that some countries have been addressing these issues
relatively successfully, while others have not. Even though most
European countries have begun to make changes to institutional
arrangements that increase flexibility and competitiveness in labour and
product markets, such changes vary greatly across countries. The changes
that have occurred depend, for example, on the size and maturity of the
industry, the industry concentration, the nature of the education
system, the availability of capital for startups, the sophistication of
the consumer, and the characteristics of the legislative framework. More
research is needed to understand the determinants of the differences in
country experiences regarding innovation and regulations, in particular
in services industries.
Finally, many service industries in Europe could benefit from a
truly single market across Europe, in which competition can be
strengthened and scale advantages may be realized. Of course, the
European 'single market' program has since the 1980s aimed at
removing the barriers to free movement of capital, labour, and goods,
but the effect on the services industry is generally seen as limited.
The present drive in Europe towards a greater openness of service
product markets across the European Union, may hold the potential to
increase productivity growth across Europe in the coming decade.
References
Acemoglu, D., P. Aghion, and F. Zilibotti (2006) "Distance to
Frontier, Selection, and Economic Growth," Journal of the European
Economic Association, Vol. 4, No. 1, pp. 37-74.
Baily, M.N. and J.F. Kirkegaard (2004) Transforming the European
Economy (Washington, DC: Institute for International Economics).
Baumol, W.J. (1967) "Macroeconomics of Unbalanced Growth: The
Anatomy of Urban Crisis," American Economic Review, Vol. 57, No. 3,
pp. 415-26.
Blanchard, O. (2004) "The Economic Future of Europe,"
Journal of Economic Perspectives, Vol. 18, No. 4, pp. 3-26.
Bloom, N. and J.V. Reenen (2007) "Measuring and Explaining
Management Practices across Firms and Countries," Quarterly Journal
of Economics, Vol. 122, No. 4, pp. 1351-1408.
Boltho, A. (1982) The European Economy: Growth and Crisis (Oxford:
Oxford University Press).
Bureau of Economic Analysis (2010) Advance GDP by Industry
Statistics for 2009 and Revised Statistics for 1998-2008 (Washington
D.C.).
Crafts, N. (2006) "Regulation and Productivity
Performance," Oxford Review of Economic Policy, Vol. 22, No. 2, pp.
186-202.
Crafts, N. and G. Toniolo (1996) Economic Growth in Europe since
1945 (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press).
Corrado, C., C. Hulten and D. Sichel (2009) "Intangible
Capital and US Economic Growth," Review of Income and Wealth, Vol.
55, No. 3, pp. 661-685.
Eichengreen, B. (2007) The European Economy since (1945):
Coordinated Capitalism and Beyond (Princeton: Princeton University Press).
Gordon, R.J. (2004) "Why Was Europe Left at the Station When
America's Productivity Locomotive Departed?" Center for
Economic Policy Research Discussion Paper 4416 (London).
Harberger A.C. (1998) "A Vision of the Growth Process,"
American Economic Review, Vol. 88, No. 1, pp. 1-32.
Inklaar, R. and M. P. Timmer (2007) "Of Yeast and Mushrooms:
Patterns of Industry-Level Productivity Growth", German Economic
Review, Vol. 8, No. 2, pp. 174-187.
Inklaar, R., M.P. Timmer and B. van Ark (2007) "Mind the Gap!
International Comparisons of Productivity in Services and Goods
Production," German Economic Review, Vol. 8, No. 2, pp. 281-307.
Inklaar, R., M.P. Timmer and B. van Ark (2008) "Market
Services Productivity across Europe and the U.S," Economic Policy,
Vol. 53, No. 1, January, pp. 141-94.
Jorgenson, D.W., Frank M. Gollop and Barbara M. Fraumeni (1987)
Productivity and U.S. Economic Growth (Cambridge, MA: Harvard University
Press).
Jorgenson, D.W. and Z. Griliches (1967) "The Explanation of
Productivity Change," Review of Economic Studies, Vol. 34, No. 3,
pp. 249-83.
Jorgenson, D.W., M.S. Ho and K.J. Stiroh (2005) Information
Technology and the American Growth Resurgence (Cambridge, MA: MIT Press).
Jorgenson, D.W., M.S. Ho and K.J. Stiroh (2008) "A
Retrospective Look at the U.S. Productivity Growth Resurgence,"
Journal of Economic Perspectives, Vol. 22, No. 1, pp. 3-24.
Jorgenson, D.W. and M.P. Timmer (2011) " Structural Change in
Advanced Nations: A New Set of Stylised Facts," Scandinavian
Journal of Economics, Vol. 113, No. 1, pp. 1-29.
Losch, M. (2006) Deepening the Lisbon Agenda: Studies on
Productivity, Services and Technologies (Vienna: Austrian Federal
Ministry of Economics and Labour).
Maddison, A. (1987) "Growth and Slowdown in Advanced
Capitalist Economies: Techniques of Quantitative Assessment,"
Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. 25, No. 2, pp. 649-98.
Nickell, S. (1997) "Unemployment and Labour Market Rigidities:
Europe versus North America," Journal of Economic Perspectives,
Vol. 11, No. 3, pp. 55-74.
O'Mahony, M. and M.P. Timmer (2009) "Output, Input and
Productivity Measures at the Industry Level: The EU KLEMS
Database," Economic Journal, Royal Economic Society, Vol. 119, No.
538, pp. F374-F403.
O'Mahony, M. and B. van Ark (eds.) (2003) EU Productivity and
Competitiveness: An Industry Perspective: Can Europe Resume the
Catching-up Process? (Luxembourg: Office for Official Publications of
the European Communities).
Prescott, E.C. (2004) "Why Do Americans Work So Much More Than
Europeans?" Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis Quarterly Review,
Vol. 28, No. 1, pp .2-13.
Schettkat, R. and L. Yocarini (2006) "The Shift to Services
Employment: A Review of the Literature," Structural Change and
Economic Dynamics, Vol. 17, No. 2, pp. 127-17.
Solow, R. (1957) "Technical Change and the Aggregate
Production Function," Review of Economics and Statistics, Vol. 39,
No. 3, pp. 212-20.
Timmer, M.P. and B. van Ark (2005) "Does Information and
Communication Technology Drive EU-US Productivity Growth
Differentials?" Oxford Economic Papers, Vol. 57, No. 4, pp.
693-716.
Timmer, M.P., R. Inklaar, M. O'Mahony and B. van Ark (2010)
Economic Growth in Europe, A Comparative Industry Perspective
(Cambridge: Cambridge University Press).
Triplett, J.E. and B.P. Bosworth (2006) "'Baumol's
Disease' Has Been Cured: IT and Multifactor Productivity in US
Services Industries," in Jansen D.W.(ed.) The New Economy and
Beyond: Past, Present and Future, pp. 34-71 (Cheltenham: Elgar).
Van Ark, B., J.X. Hao, C. Corrado and C. Hulten (2009)
"Measuring intangible capital and its contribution to economic
growth in Europe," EIB Papers, European Investment Bank, Vol. 14,
No. 1, pp. 62-99.
Marcel P. Timmer and Robert Inklaar
University of Groningen
Mary O'Mahony
University of Birmingham
and Bart van Ark (1)
The Conference Board
(1) Marcel P. Timmer is a Professor and Robert Inklaar is an
Assistant Professor at the University of Groningen, Mary O'Mahony
is a Professor at the Birmingham Business School at the University of
Birmingham, and Bart van Ark is Chief Economist at The Conference Board.
This article is based on our recent book, Economic Growth in Europe, A
Comparative Industry Perspective, published by Cambridge University
Press in 2010, drawing in particular from Chapter 2 and 5. The article
includes industry level estimates from the EU KLEMS growth accounting
databases which are updated to 2007 and preliminary estimates of the
impact of the crisis on the comparative growth performance of the
European Union and United States from 2007-2009. We are grateful to
Vivian Chen, Ben Cheng and Reitze Gouma for updates on the latest
estimates. The research for this article is based on the EU KLEMS
project on Growth and Productivity in the European Union. This project
was supported by the European Commission, Research Directorate General
as part of the 6th Framework Programme, Priority 8, 'Policy Support
and Anticipating Scientific and Technological Needs. E-mails:
m.p.timmer@rug.nl, R.C.Inklaar@rug.nl, m.omahony@bham.ac.uk,
bart.vanark@conference-board.org.
(2) The November 2009 release of this industry-level database
provides time series on output, inputs and productivity for more than 65
industries over the period 1970 to 2007. It covers not only data for 25
European Union countries, but also for the United States, Australia,
Canada, Japan and South Korea. The data are publicly available at
http://www.euklems.net/. For a summary overview of the methodology and
construction of the EU KLEMS database, see O'Mahony and Timmer
(2009) and Chapter 3 in Timmer et al. (2010).
(3) Further details on the growth slowdown during this period are
provided by Crafts and Toniolo (1996), Baily and Kirkegaard (2004), and
Eichengreen (2007).
(4) See Jorgenson and Timmer (2011) for an in-depth comparison of
structural change in Europe, Japan and the United States.
(5) Incidentally, market services also appear to exhibit rapid
productivity growth in other Anglo-Saxon economies, such as Australia
and Canada (Inklaar, Timmer, and van Ark, 2007).
(6) The analogy with yeast and mushrooms comes from the fact that
yeast causes bread to expand slowly and evenly, while mushrooms are
scattered and pop up almost overnight, in a fashion that is not easy to
predict (Harberger, 1998).
(7) Harberger (1998) stresses the importance of the share of
industries that together make up aggregate growth. In other words, he
focuses on the crossing of the aggregate growth line in Chart 2. We feel
that a split between industries with positive growth and with negative
growth is a more natural distinction.
(8) In practice, the diagrams are not smooth as in Chart 2, as we
have a discrete number of industries. Instead, they consist of piecewise
linear plots. This means that the area underneath the diagram can be
calculated as the sum of triangles and squares.
Table 1
Average Annual Growth Rates of GDP, GDP per Capita,
and GDP per Hour Worked, EU-15 and United States,
1950-2007
(per cent)
GDP GDP per
GDP per capita hour worked
1950-1973
EU-15 4.9 4.2 4.9
United States 3.9 2.5 2.6
1973-1995
EU-15 2.2 1.9 2.7
United States 2.9 1.8 1.3
1995-2007
EU-15 2.4 2.0 1.5
United States 3.2 2.1 2.1
Source: Calculations based on The Conference Board Total Economy
Database, January 2011, at
http://www.conference-board.org/data/
economydatabase/.
Notes: See Chart 1. The growth rates are presented as differences
in the log of the levels of each variable instead of a percentage
change in the actual level in order to facilitate aggregation to
regional averages and a decomposition of growth sources.
Table 2
Levels of GDP per Capita, Hours Worked per Capita, GDP per
Hour Worked and Capital Input per Hour Worked in EU-15
Relative to the United States, 1950, 1973, 1995 and 2007
(United States =100, per cent)
1950 1973 1995 2007
GDP per capita 51.5 75.4 77.1 76.2
Hours worked per capita 126.2 110.9 83.5 88.1
GDP per hour worked 40.8 68.0 92.4 86.6
Capital input per hour worked * 75.3 103.6 103.0
Source: Calculations based on The Conference Board Total Economy
Database, January 2011, at
http://www.conference-board.org/data/
economydatabase
Note: Output and capital levels are converted by GDP purchasing
power parities for 2005.
* Measured as capital stock per hour worked.
Table 3
Growth Rates of GDP, GDP per Capita, Total Hours Worked
and GDP per Hour Worked, EU-15 and the United States,
2007-2009
(annual and average annual per cent change)
GDP per Total Hours GDP per
GDP capita Worked hour worked
2007
EU-15 2.8 2.3 1.6 1.1
United States 1.9 0.9 1.0 1.0
2008
EU-15 0.3 -0.2 0.4 -0.1
United States 0.0 -0.9 -0.8 0.8
2009
EU-15 -4.3 -4.6 -3.0 -1.3
United States -2.6 -3.5 -5.0 2.5
2007-09
EU-15 -2.0 -2.4 -1.3 -0.7
United States -1.3 -2.2 -2.9 1.6
Source: Calculations based on The Conference Board Total Economy
Database, January 2011, at
http://www.conference-board.org/data/
economydatabase.
Table 4
Contributions to Real Output Growth in the Market Economy,
European Union and the United States, 1980-2007
(annual average growth rates, in percentage points)
European Union *
1980-1995 1995-2007
1 Growth rate of market economy output 2.1 2.5
2 Hours worked -0.5 0.8
3 Labour productivity 2.5 1.6
Contributions from
4 Labour composition 0.3 0.2
5 Capital services per hour 1.2 0.9
6 ICT capital per hour 0.4 0.5
7 Non-ICT capital per hour 0.8 0.4
8 Multifactor productivity 1.1 0.6
Contribution of the knowledge economy 1.8 1.3
to labour productivity (4)+(6)+(8)
United States **
1980-1995 1995-2007
1 Growth rate of market economy output 3.3 3.5
2 Hours worked 1.3 0.9
3 Labour productivity 2.0 2.6
Contributions from
4 Labour composition 0.2 0.3
5 Capital services per hour 1.0 1.2
6 ICT capital per hour 0.7 0.9
7 Non-ICT capital per hour 0.3 0.3
8 Multifactor productivity 0.7 1.2
Contribution of the knowledge economy 1.7 2.4
to labour productivity (4)+(6)+(8)
Source: EU KLEMS database, November 2009;
see O'Mahony and Timmer (2009).
Notes: * excludes 5 member states of EU-15: Greece, Ireland,
Luxembourg, Portugal and Sweden; Data for European Union
refers to ten countries: Austria, Belgium, Denmark, Finland,
France, Germany, Italy, the Netherlands, Spain, and the
United Kingdom.
** based on USA old standard industrial classification.
'ICT' is information and communications technology.
Table 5
Contributions to Real Output Growth in the Market
Economy, EU Economies and the United States, 1995-2007
(annual average growth rates, in percentage points)
Growth Output contribution
rate of from
output
Hours Labour
worked productivity
1 = 2+3 2 3=4+5+6+7
Austria 2.8 0.6 2.2
Belgium 2.5 0.8 1.7
Denmark 2.3 1.3 1.0
Finland 4.6 1.3 3.3
France 2.5 0.5 2.0
Germany 1.4 -0.3 1.7
Italy * 1.5 1.1 0.4
Netherlands 3.1 1.0 2.1
Spain 3.7 3.0 0.6
United Kingdom 3.2 0.6 2.6
European Union ** 2.5 0.8 1.6
United States *** 3.5 0.9 2.6
standard deviation **** 0.9 0.8 0.9
Labour productivity contributions from
Non-ICT
Labour ICT capital capital MFP
composition per hour per hour growth
4 5 6 7
Austria 0.1 0.5 0.0 1.5
Belgium 0.2 0.9 0.4 0.1
Denmark 0.1 1.0 0.1 -0.1
Finland 0.1 0.5 -0.1 2.8
France 0.3 0.3 0.4 0.9
Germany 0.0 0.5 0.5 0.7
Italy * 0.1 0.2 0.4 -0.4
Netherlands 0.4 0.5 0.0 1.1
Spain 0.4 0.4 0.5 -0.6
United Kingdom 0.4 0.8 0.4 1.0
European Union ** 0.2 0.5 0.4 0.6
United States *** 0.3 0.9 0.3 1.2
standard deviation **** 0.1 0.3 0.2 1.0
Labour productivity
contribution of the
knowledge economy
4+5+7
Austria 2.2
Belgium 1.3
Denmark 0.9
Finland 3.5
France 1.6
Germany 1.2
Italy * 0.0
Netherlands 2.0
Spain 0.1
United Kingdom 2.2
European Union ** 1.3
United States *** 2.4
standard deviation **** 1.0
Source: Calculations based on EU KLEMS database, November 2009;
O'Mahony and Timmer (2009).
Notes: 'ICT' is information and communications technology. 'MFP' is
multifactor productivity.
* Data for Italy exclude agriculture and private households.
** Data for the European Union exclude 5 member states of EU-15:
Greece, Ireland, Luxembourg, Portugal. Numbers may not sum exactly
due to rounding.
*** based on old U.S. standard industrial classification
**** Standard deviation for EU countries and the United States.
Table 6
Major Sector Contributions to Labour Productivity Growth in the
Market Economy, EU Economies and the United States, 1995-2007
(annual average growth rates, in percentage points)
Contributions from
Market
Economy ICT Goods
1=2+3+4+5 production production
2 3
Austria 2.2 0.3 1.7
Belgium 1.7 0.3 0.9
Denmark 1.0 0.3 0.4
Finland 3.3 1.7 1.3
France 2.0 0.4 0.8
Germany 1.7 0.5 0.9
Italy 0.4 0.2 0.2
Netherlands 2.1 0.4 0.6
Spain 0.6 0.1 0.2
United Kingdom 2.6 0.5 0.7
European Union ** 1.6 0.4 0.7
United States *** 2.6 0.8 0.3
Contributions from
Market
services Reallocation *
4 5
Austria 0.2 -0.1
Belgium 0.6 -0.1
Denmark 0.4 -0.1
Finland 0.5 -0.1
France 0.7 0.0
Germany 0.4 0.0
Italy 0.0 -0.1
Netherlands 1.2 -0.2
Spain 0.3 -0.1
United Kingdom 1.6 -0.2
European Union ** 0.6 -0.2
United States *** 1.8 -0.2
Source: Calculations based on EU KLEMS database, November 2009;
O'Mahony and Timmer (2009).
Notes: The reallocation effect in the last column refers to labour
productivity effects of reallocations of labour between sectors.
The European Union aggregate refers to the ten countries in the
table. Information and communications technology production
includes manufacturing of electrical machinery and post and
telecommunications services. Goods production includes agriculture,
mining, manufacturing (excluding electrical machinery),
construction, and utilities. Market services include distribution
services; financial and business services, excluding real estate;
and personal services. Numbers may not sum exactly due to rounding.
* Data for Italy exclude agriculture and private households.
** Data for the European Union exclude 5 member states of EU-15:
Greece, Ireland, Luxembourg, Portugal. Numbers may not sum exactly
due to rounding.
*** based on old U.S. standard industrial classification
Table 7
Major Sector Contributions to Labour Productivity Growth
in Market Services, EU Economies and the United States,
1980-2005
(average annual percentage points)
European Union United States
1980- 1995- 1980- 1995-
1995 2005 1995 2005
Market services labour productivity 1.4 1.0 1.5 3.0
Distribution services contribution 1.1 0.7 1.2 1.5
factor intensity growth 0.4 0.5 0.4 0.5
multifactor productivity growth 0.7 0.2 0.8 1.0
Financial services contribution 0.2 0.4 0.2 0.5
factor intensity growth 0.3 0.2 0.7 0.5
multifactor productivity growth 0.0 0.1 -0.6 0.1
Business services contribution 0.0 -0.1 -0.1 0.7
factor intensity growth 0.4 0.4 0.2 0.8
multifactor productivity growth -0.4 -0.5 -0.3 0.0
Personal services contribution -0.1 -0.1 0.2 0.2
factor intensity growth 0.1 0.1 0.1 0.1
multifactor productivity growth -0.2 -0.1 0.1 0.1
Contribution from labour reallocation 0.1 0.0 0.0 0.0
Source: Calculations based on EU KLEMS database, March 2008; see
O'Mahony and Timmer, 2009). Notes: European Union aggregate refers
to 10 countries. Factor intensity relates to the total contribution
from changes in labour composition and in capital deepening of
information and communications technology (ICT) and non-information
and communications technology (non-ICT) assets. The reallocation
effect refers to the impact of changes in the distribution of
labour input between industries on labour productivity growth in
market services. Numbers may not add up due to rounding.
Table 8
Patterns of Market Economy Multifactor Productivity
Growth EU Economies and the United States, 1980-2005
Aggregate MFP growth % of industries with
(average annual rate positive MFP growth
of change)
1980-1995 1995-2005 1980-1995 1995-2005
Austria 1.3 1.1 81 74
Belgium 0.7 0.0 63 39
Denmark 1.1 0.1 73 53
Finland 1.4 2.6 73 91
France 1.3 0.8 68 56
Germany 0.8 0.3 73 59
Italy 0.8 -0.7 65 29
Netherlands 0.4 1.0 64 63
Spain 0.6 -0.9 63 23
Sweden 1.7 1.6 68 59
United Kingdom 1.6 0.9 74 78
European Union 1.0 0.4 73 59
United States 0.7 1.3 61 73
Relative area
under Harberger
1980-1995 1995-2005
Austria 0.41 0.53
Belgium 0.61 0.99
Denmark 0.54 0.93
Finland 0.43 0.39
France 0.55 0.58
Germany 0.50 0.81
Italy 0.62 0.56
Netherlands 0.75 0.53
Spain 0.71 0.49
Sweden 0.64 0.51
United Kingdom 0.40 0.44
European Union 0.47 0.69
United States 0.63 0.48
Source: Calculations based on EU KLEMS Database, March 2008.