Indian manufacturing productivity: what caused the growth stagnation before the 1990s?
Gupta, Abhay
The slow productivity growth in Indian manufacturing before the
late 1990s is cited as one of the major reasons why the Indian economy
could not achieve high rates of economic growth. Indian manufacturing
productivity growth was slower compared to that in other Asian economies
like China and Vietnam, as shown in Fernandes and Pakes (2008). But more
interestingly, the relative performance of the manufacturing sector in
India was poor compared to the Indian services sector. Chart 1 shows
output and output shares of manufacturing and services in India for
1960-2002. Manufacturing output grew during these 42 years, but that
growth was slower than the growth in services output, which starts
growing exponentially in the 1990s. The contrast between these two
sectors becomes clearer when looking at their shares of total output.
The share of services jumped from 0.29 in 1960 to 0.50 in 2002, while
the share of manufacturing went from 0.11 to 0.18 in 2002.
[GRAPHIC 1 OMITTED]
Why is it that under a similar economic environment the service
sector grew at remarkable rates while the manufacturing sector did not?
How did reforms in the 1990s spur productivity growth in the
manufacturing sector? This article differs from previous articles (2) in
its approach to answering these questions by introducing two new
factors. First, the role of intermediate inputs is examined, as this is
missing from the discussion despite being the most important difference
between manufacturing and services production processes. Second, this
article studies the effects arising from the combination and interaction
of policies, which can be totally different from the individual effects
of policies. Adding these two dimensions provides new insights into the
Indian economic growth experience.
By taking this appraoach, this article finds that the difference
between the growth performance of the manufacturing and the service
sector is caused by the greater reliance of the former on intermediate
inputs. Interactions and combinations of policies (inflexible labour
laws in the presence of a quota-permit system) and economic conditions
(high inflation in the presence of credit unavailability) in India
created distortions resulting in production inefficiency. These
mechanisms hampered productivity growth in manufacturing by forcing
firms to operate at non-optimal intermediate input allocation. Economic
reforms in the 1990s helped reduce these distortions by removing many of
these restrictions and, as a result, the mechanisms that caused
inefficiency disappeared. This article discusses the economic mechanisms
through which government policies affected manufacturing productivity at
the firm level.
To estimate the effect of a given policy, one needs to isolate it
from other policies. But the ceteris paribus assumption comes at a cost,
because the interaction of different economic conditions may give rise
to mechanisms or incentives that are totally different from the
predicted outcomes of any single policy. This is especially true in the
case of India, where different policies are not always coordinated or
synchronized. Rajan et al (2006) argue that the development policies
adopted after India's independence can be described as
"idiosyncratic". In fact, the reason manufacturing growth is
relatively slower lies in the way the Indian economy has evolved. By the
time industrial growth started to become the focus of five-year plans,
India had already embraced the socialist model of planning. Government
regulations and control greatly influenced Indian industry through the
notorious "license-raj" (the quota-permit system) and rigid
labour laws. Besley and Burgess (2004) show that pro-worker industrial
dispute regulation tend to lower output, investment, productivity and
employment in manufacturing. Fernandes and Pakes (2008) also find that
labour is underutilized in states with more restrictive labour laws
(e.g. an amendment to the Industrial Disputes Act which made the firing
of workers illegal except with previous permission from the appropriate
state government).
Why do these worker-friendly labour laws end up reducing
productivity and inducing the underutilization of labour? This article
shows that it is because of the presence of the additional (and often
ignored) policy of a quota system. The interaction of the quota system
with existing conditions and labour laws created economic mechanisms
that distorted the usage of intermediate inputs, which are very
important in manufacturing production (a share of 60 per cent of gross
output). This non-optimal allocation of intermediate inputs resulted in
inefficiencies in the manufacturing sector.
Unfortunately, the effect of the quota-permit system on Indian
industry has not received its due attention. Mohammad and Whalley (1984)
discuss some of those licenses and other controls. Their estimates of
the welfare losses from rent seeking in India are as high as 30-45 per
cent of GNP. The main sources of rent seeking were price controls and
rationing. Das (2004) finds that the structure of import licensing
remained restrictive and complicated throughout the 1980s and even in
the early 1990s. In general, labour laws have not changed dramatically
and economic reforms have focused on removing these license regulations
rather than labour rigidities. This indicates that the observed
improvements in productivity performance stem mostly from the removal of
the quota-permit system and the reason for differences in pre-reform and
post-reform performance is directly related to this quota system.
This article argues that the combination of the two distortions
caused by labour-rigidity and the materials-quota were impeding productivity growth. An optimizing firm has to equate its labour and
material ratio such that marginal returns are equal to the respective
prices. But if a firm cannot fire extra workers due to the labour laws,
it ends up requiring more material to reach its optimal allocation.
However, the firm cannot buy extra materials because of quota-permit
restrictions. Hence, the firm ends up operating at non-optimal levels.
In isolation, none of these policies would have resulted in a distorted
allocation.
This mechanism also explains the result observed by Chand and Sen
(2002) that the liberalization of intermediate-good sectors is better
for TFP growth than the liberalization of final-good sectors.
This article also provides another perspective on the role of
inflation in affecting growth in Indian manufacturing. Inflation
combined with credit unavailability forced firms to operate at
non-optimal input allocation because they could neither reduce labour
(due to labour laws) nor afford to buy materials (due to credit
constraints and significant increase in materials prices due to
inflation). This article finds a strong relationship between materials
inflation and real wages (labour productivity) indicating the presence
of this channel.
These results provide new perspectives for policymakers regarding
two widely used industrial policies: labour market regulations and
import substitution regimes. Ahsan and Pages (2007) find that in India
pro-worker labour policies are associated with reduced productivity
growth. Kruger (1997) discusses how it was thought that import
substitution in manufactures would be the key to development. Earlier
explanations about both these observations, i.e. labour laws slowing
growth and import substitution policies slowing growth, are based on
calculating implicit costs or wasted resources. This article finds a
direct channel (intermediate inputs) and the distortion mechanisms
through which productivity is affected.
One of the major impacts of economic reforms in India was to break
these interactions by removal of permit quotas and by increasing credit
availability. The distortion-inefficiency mechanisms described above no
longer remain relevant because the firms are not restricted when
choosing their material input allocation (layoff restrictions have still
not been removed). This article finds that the distortions in input
allocation and their effect on productivity growth fell significantly
after the reforms in the 1990s. It also shows that firms have started
over-substituting materials relative to labour. This explains the
phenomenon of jobless growth in Indian manufacturing. The firms are
producing more output because of this material-deepening, but they are
avoiding hiring additional workers to avoid future inflexibilities and
legal issues. Like many other studies, these findings call for the
policy makers to take another look at the existing labour market
regulations in India.
Industrial Economic Policies in India before 1991
The industrial sector became the focus and one of the early goals
of the Indian government's five-year plans. Just like every other
part of the economy, Indian manufacturing has experienced an evolution
of policies in the last three decades. It has been the subject of many
productivity and policy research studies, but often for the wrong
reasons. Unlike other sectors in India and unlike manufacturing sectors
in other developing countries, the manufacturing sector in India did not
register many years of consistent high growth until very recently. GDP (at 1993-94 prices) in manufacturing grew almost 10 times between 1960
and 2002. But the unimpressive labour productivity and TFP growth
estimates from various studies have portrayed Indian manufacturing as a
stagnant sector that is little affected by the early stages of policy
reform. Das (2004) finds the TFP growth over the period of 1980-2000 to
be negative and attributes this to structural factors.
Inflexible Labour Laws
The Industrial Disputes Act of 1947 states that the
"discharge, dismissal, retrenchment or termination" of an
individual workman by an employer "shall be deemed to be an
industrial dispute". This law has motivated many studies on the
role of labour market regulation in India. Labour regulation has become
a standard part of the explanations for India's poor growth
performance before the 1990s. Besley and Burgess (2004) show that Indian
states which made additional amendments to this act in favour of workers
experienced lower output and productivity in manufacturing. They also
find that pro-worker labour regulation is associated with increases in
urban poverty. Fernandes and Pakes (2008) use World Bank Investment
Climate Survey data to show that conditional on firm productivity,
factor costs and other factors faced by firms, labour was underutilized
in Indian manufacturing in 2001 and 2004. The supposed explanation is
that these inflexible labour laws restricting the firing of workers in
India resulted in firms lowering their demand for labour. Ahsan and
Pages (2007) discuss various types of labour laws in India, including
Chapter V(b) of the amendment to the Industrial Disputes Act which
prohibits firms that employ 100 or more workers from retrenching without
permission from the state. There are around 45 pieces of central
legislation covering various aspects of employment as well as a large
number of state laws. Even shifting the weekly schedules or days offs
without notice could be in non-compliance to the labour legislation.
Ahsan and Pages (2007) find that regulations that impede employment
adjustment are associated with negative effects on output.
Quantitative Restrictions: Import Permit Quota
Jagdish Bhagwati (1978) examined in detail the quantitative
restrictions which were the building blocks of industrial policy in
India. These were guided by the principle of import substitution and
were justified by the aim of protecting domestic producers. Commodities
were divided into various categories and producers needed to apply for
specific licenses for items not under open general license (oGL).
Licenses were required for producing new products or expanding
production capacities. Mohammad and Whalley (1984) estimate that the
cost of these rent seeking policies in India was as high as 30-45 per
cent of GNP and it "put India in a different category
altogether" in terms of the extent of distortions.
Despite being one of the most widely criticized policy choices, not
many studies have tried to identify and estimate how this quota system
affected the growth in Indian manufacturing. Bhagwati and Desai (1970)
document the industrial licensing scheme adopted in India after the
passage of the Industries (Development and Regulation) Act of 1951.
There were several separate license categories. A capital goods (CG)
license was required to import necessary capital goods, while actual
user (AU) licenses, issued to producers for imports of raw materials and
intermediate goods, had items specified in considerable detail to ensure
that only the approved production would be made feasible.
This also required that value and/or quantity limits were specified
for the listed importables on each license. These licenses even
specified the composition and the source of the goods and were
nontransferable between firms and even between plants within a firm.
This licensing system was inefficient since it lacked any evaluation
criteria and there were large administrative costs and delays.
Other Economic Conditions: High Inflation and Low Credit
Availability
Inflation has been consistently high in India. Annual average CPI inflation has been 8.2 per cent per year between 1970 and 2003. The
pre-1990s and post-1990s inflation rate averages were 8.6 per cent and
7.4 per cent respectively, both much higher than average inflation in
industrialized and newly industrialized countries. In China, the average
retail price inflation between 1978 and 2003 was around 5 per cent.
Intermediate input prices have also experienced the same kind of high
inflation throughout the last three decades. The average annual
inflation rate of materials prices was 7.5 per cent.
Using industry specific price index data from India's Central
Statistical organization, we calculate average inflation rates for
output in all 58 industries. The average inflation is higher than 7 per
cent per year for 53 industries, with a few industries experiencing
price increases averaging more than 11 per cent per year between 1973
and 2003. During this period, the annual nominal wage inflation in
Indian manufacturing was 9.6 per cent; 11.1 per cent per year before
1990 and 7.1 per cent per year after 1990.
It was the currency crisis of 1991 in India that paved the way for
a broad set of reforms including capital market reforms. Prior to that,
credit markets in India were unorganized and underdeveloped. Chart 2
shows the lending rates of various countries using data from the
IMF's International Financial Statistics. For India, lending rates
were 16.5 per cent for the entire decade of the 1980s. They were not
only higher than in developed countries such as United States and
Germany, but also higher than other Asian economies like Singapore and
Malaysia. Interest rates, which denotes the cost of borrowing, remained
very high in India until late 1990s. Capital markets were also
underdeveloped. Table 1 shows stock market capitalization in 1990 for
different countries. For India, market capitalization as percentage of
GDP was much lower than for other countries.
[GRAPHIC 2 OMITTED]
Role of Intermediate Inputs in Manufacturing Growth
To see the role of the materials-per-worker ratio in output growth
in manufacturing, let us consider a simple extension of Solow's
growth accounting model by including materials as an input in the
constant return to scale production function. Y =
A[K.sup.[alpha]][M.sup.[beta]][L.sup.(1--[alpha]--[beta])] (1)
where Y stands for output, K for capital, L for labour, A is a
measure of the production technology and other unobservable inputs,
[alpha] is the capital share in output and [beta] is the materials share
in output.
This can be rearranged in per-worker terms as Y/L =
A[(K/L).sup.[alpha]][(M/L).sup.[beta]] [equivalent to] y =
[Ak.sup.[alpha]][m.sup.[beta]] (2)
where k stands for capital per worker and m is materials per
worker.
Hence labour productivity growth between two periods can be
expressed as following. [DELTA] ln y = [DELTA] ln A + [alpha] x [DELTA]
ln k + [beta] x [DELTA] ln m (3)
Hence, labour productivity growth is the sum of TFP growth and the
contributions of capital per worker growth and materials per worker
growth. The last term in Equation 3 denotes materials-deepening, which
receives little attention in the literature, even though it can be of
crucial importance in explaining output growth of the manufacturing
sector. The estimated values of input shares for Indian manufacturing
are [alpha] = 0.2 and [beta] = 0.4, indicating that materials per worker
is very important for the gross output of the Indian manufacturing
sector.
Value-added (VA), which is widely used as the output measure in
industry-wide analysis, is obtained by subtracting the real intermediate
inputs (M) from real gross output (Y).
VA = Y--M = VA =
A[K.sup.[alpha]][M.sup.[beta]][L.sup.(1--[alpha]--[beta])]--M (4)
or in per-worked terms,
va = [Ak.sup.[alpha]][m.sup.[beta]]--m (5)
where va stands for value added per worker, and m is
materials-per-worker.
Hence the labour productivity growth (using value-added) is given
by [DELTA]va = [DELTA]y--[DELTA]m (6)
The above equation contradicts the notion that value added
productivity growth is independent of materials used. A change in the
materials-per-worker ratio between two time-periods affects labour
productivity growth even if the output is measured using a value-added
concept. In fact, some methodologies try to highlight the importance of
intermediate inputs, e.g. Domar weights and terms-of-trade
decomposition. But the general consensus is that if we are measuring the
output as value added, we do not have to worry about the intermediate
inputs. As shown in Equation 6, this is clearly a simplification, as it
assumes that the materials-per-worker ratio remains constant between
periods.
The importance of raw materials has not been studied widely in the
Indian manufacturing productivity literature. The reason is that ideally
this materials input should have been allocated to equate the returns
between the materials and labour; and hence value-added productivity
growth should have been independent of the materials input. But this has
not been the case with Indian manufacturing. Government policy, or to be
more specific the interaction of government policies, distorted the
materials input allocation compared to the labour input and this had a
negative effect on productivity growth. This article defines and
estimates some measures of this distortion by comparing the observed
materials-per-worker ratio to the (hypothetical) optimal
materials-per-worker ratio for the given materials' prices and wage
levels.
Input Distortions and Productivity
The presence of channels that transfer the effect of policy
interactions (labour laws in the presence of quantitative restrictions)
and economic conditions (high inflation with low credit access) to the
production process in Indian manufacturing can be verified using the
data. From production function estimates, one can identify whether the
value of materials-per-worker is higher than or lower than the optimal
(M/L). A lower (M/L) means the firm is either operating with less than
the desired materials input (due to a quota) or with more than optimum
number of workers (since the firms cannot lay-off workers).
We can see how these distortion-inefficiency channels work in
different scenarios by considering a simple production model Y = F (A,
K, L, M); where output Y is produced using capital K, labour L and
materials M. A is the measure of production technology and other
unobservable inputs. The optimization gives the following first order
conditions for input allocation in terms of price of labour w and price
of materials [P.sub.M].
w = [partial derivative]Y/[partial derivative]L ; [partial
derivative]Y/[partial derivative]L/[partial derivative]Y/[partial
derivative]M = w/[P.sub.M] (7)
For the Cobb-Douglas production function, this condition can be
written as
[alpha]L/[alpha]M * M/L = w/[P.sub.M] (8)
In response to a positive technology shock, there is upward
pressure on wages due to increased productivity. Since imported
materials prices ([P.sub.M]) are determined in the world market, the
optimality can only be achieved by either using more materials or using
less labour. In India, however, the quantitative restrictions do not
allow a firm to use more materials, and the inflexible labour laws
prohibit a firm from using fewer workers. As a result, the optimal
materials-per-worker ratio is not achieved. Due to these frictions, the
gains from technological progress are not fully realized and firms are
forced to operate at non-optimal factor allocations.
The distortion worsens in the presence of rising prices and limited
access to credit markets. Let us consider the effect of high inflation
in materials on the factor allocation choice of a firm. In absence of
credit, the firms may find it difficult to buy the same amount of
materials as in the last period due to increased prices. The firm can
still operate efficiently by shrinking its scale and reducing labour
input according to its budget. But even that is not possible. Since it
is difficult to layoff workers, the firms have to compromise on
materials and must operate at a lower materials per worker ratio than in
the last period. This causes the output to go down and hence reduces
productivity growth.
[P.sub.M] [up arrow], [l.bar] [??] (M/L) [down arrow] [??]
([partial derivative]Y/[partial derivative]L) [down arrow] (9)
Substitutability between Materials and Labour: An Example
one of the main differences between manufacturing industries and
services industries is that manufacturing primarily changes the physical
characteristics of a good. Unlike the substitutability between capital
and labour, materials and labour have limited substituability in
manufacturing. The increased capital input in the form of machinery
makes some of the workers redundant. But one cannot use labour input in
place of the materials that are required to create the final output.
Materials and labour inputs are still substitutable in the sense that
firms can outsource some of the process of converting to the final good.
Rather than producing some intermediate materials themselves, they might
directly buy it from other firms. For most of the manufacturing
industries, however, the actual production function of their final
output is Leontief in terms of the intermediate materials requirements.
Let us consider the example of a car manufacturer. The final good,
a car, is made by combining different intermediate goods like engines,
airbags, and tires. The production function would be
Y = F[K, L, M] = F[S(K, L), N(M)] (10)
where, S(K, L) = Scale of Production
N(M) = Maximum number of Cars that could be made using M.
The function N(M) has the following Leontief form:
N(M) = min (engines, tires/4, steering wheel, brake pedal,
airbags/2, ...) (11)
This materials upper-bound function N(M) is not relevant in cases
where the material input is not the limiting factor and hence only the
scale S(K,L) matters. In these cases, the concept of value-added by
capital and labour can explain the output growth correctly. But in the
case of India, N(M) had an upper bound due to import quota restrictions.
Indian manufacturing firms could have reduced their scales S(K,L)
accordingly, but labour laws made that difficult.
Table 2 provides a simple example of how these restrictions would
harm a typical car manufacturer by denying it the benefit of
technological advances. Note that even after the reforms the
manufacturer is not reaching the growth potential. The firms are not
hiring more workers even when it is optimal to do so, because they are
worried about firing restrictions and extra costs.
Productivity Estimation Methodology
The estimates used in this article are based on the Annual Survey
of Industries (ASI) data version 2 released by the Economic and
Political Weekly Research Foundation.
The Annual Survey of Industries is the principal source of
industrial statistics in India. It provides data on various vital
aspects of registered factories such as employment, wages, invested
capital, capital formation, inputs, gross output, depreciation and value
added, etc. It covers all factories registered under Sections 2m(i) and
2m(ii) of the Factories Act, 1948 i.e. those factories employing 10 or
more workers using power, and those employing 20 or more workers without
using power. The dataset is created from these surveys and has 31
variables for the years from 1973 to 2003. The article uses both
aggregate level data and industry level data for 58 industries based on
the 3-digit national industry classification (NIC) code.
Industry-specific price deflators are taken from the wholesale
price index series provided by India's Central Statistical
Organization (CSO). GDP, GDCF deflators and interest rate series were
available from the Reserve Bank of India publication titled Handbook of
Statistics of the Indian Economy.
Real value added is calculated using double-deflation. Gross output
is deflated using sector-specific price indexes, materials inputs are
deflated using the wholesale price index for manufacturing and fuels are
deflated using the fuel and energy price index available from CSO. The
business services input is estimated by subtracting the sum of materials
and fuel from the total value of inputs. This business services input is
deflated using the consumer price index. The capital input is generated
using the user-cost approach.
This article estimates the unit-input requirement, which is the
amount of each factor that is required to produce one unit of output in
each year. It also estimates the productivity growth measures based on
an index number method which has the advantage of incorporating the
effect of changes in factor shares. A Fisher index is used for
aggregating the input quantities. TFP growth is estimated as the ratio
of output growth and input quantity index growth. For gross output all
three inputs (capital, labour and materials) are used, while for value
added only capital and labour inputs are used.
X(t + 1, t) = Fisher Quantity Index ([Q.sup.t + 1], [P.sup.t + 1],
[Q.sup.t], [P.sup.t]) (12)
TFP = Y(t + 1, t)/X(t + 1, t)
The above set of estimates are calculated for all-industries data
(time period 1970-2003) and for panel dataset using 3-digit National
Industrial Classification (NIC) codes (time period 1973-2003).
Estimating Distortions
There have been few studies which estimate the extent of
distortions in factor allocation. Hsieh and Klenow (2007) quantify this
factor misallocation by comparing marginal products of labour and
capital in industries in India and China with those in the United
States. Fernandes and Pakes (2008) estimate the underutilization of
labour and capital across states for Indian manufacturing in 2001. This
article uses a similar concept, but rather than estimating absolute
values, it measures the distortions (under- or overutilization) relative
to the other factors.
[GRAPHIC 3 OMITTED]
We believe this is a superior approach. If one tries to measure the
misallocation or underutilization of factors by the amount of extra
labour that will be required to justify the wages, one is assuming that
capital is already optimally allocated, which defeats the purpose of
this counter-factual exercise. Measuring the relative distortions does
not depend on these assumptions and, as shown earlier for a Cobb-Douglas
specification, this ratio-based relative underutilization measure is
directly related to productivity growth.
Another problem with earlier approaches is the implicit assumption
that TFP estimates represent the unit-production-values, i.e. if one
amount of each input is employed, the output will be equal to the value
of estimated TFP for that period. This is hard to justify since there
are measurement errors and many of the unmeasured inputs such as
education and economic conditions are also included in the TFP
estimates. Therefore, it makes more sense to base the analysis on TFP
growth, as is done in this article, rather than on the absolute values
of TFP estimates.
Using ASI data, the production function for Indian manufacturing is
estimated using Olley-Pakes and Levinshon-Petrin methodologies on the
panel dataset. These methods give robust estimates for the labour,
capital and material shares. The optimal (K/L) and (M/L) ratios are
calculated using the estimated factor shares and observed factor prices
in the corresponding periods. These are obtained by making the ratios of
marginal returns on the factors equal to their relative prices. The
estimated underutilization is the difference between this optimal ratio
and the actual ratio of inputs used in that period.
Underutilization = Optimal (M/L) (Prices)--Actual (M/L) (13)
Similarly, the optimal relative substitution values are calculated
using observed changes in factor prices and factor allocations between
two timeperiods. The under-substitution is the difference between the
optimal and the actual changes of relative factor allocations.
Under-Substitution = Optimal [DELTA](M/L) ([DELTA] Prices) - Actual
[DELTA] (M/L) (14)
Underutilization of Materials and Productivity Growth in Indian
Manufacturing
Using data for all-industries, Chart 3 plots the movement of the
actual versus the optimal (M/L) ratio. Compared to 2003, the actual
materials-per-worker index is lower than what the optimal should have
been for the existing wages and materials' prices in each year. We
find that for the entire period (1970-2003) materials were on average 25
per cent underutilized compared to labour and this average is reduced by
half (i.e. 12 percentage points) after the reforms in the 1990s. When
estimating the underutilization of materials with a 3-digit NIC code
panel dataset, the unweighted average underutilization of (M/L) over 58
industries is almost the same as the all-industries average (24 per cent
for the 1973-2003 period and 11 per cent for the post-reform period of
1991-2003).
Similarly, the estimates show that compared to labour, capital
input is being over-utilized in the later periods. These results are
similar to those of Fernandes and Pakes (2008), who found
overutilization of capital in 2001 and 2004. This overutilization
happened because capital prices dropped significantly after 1990s and
Indian manufacturing firms started over-substituting capital relative to
labour. One explanation for this trend might be the fact that the
reforms did not change the labour laws. A firm still needs to obtain
government approval to layoff workers and such approval is rarely given.
Expecting these issues, firms prefer not to hire the workers and
over-substitute other factors (capital and materials) compared to what
is optimal at the existing prices. This leads to the observed
overutilization of capital.
This article finds that some industries (specified by their 3-digit
NIC code) are over-substituting the materials input relative to labour
input. This observed presence of over-substitution of materials relative
to labour in the 1970s and 1980s does not imply that few firms somehow
got around the licensing requirements. It simply means that even when
wages went down (relative to materials prices) the firms did not hire
more workers. The firms might have done this for two reasons. Their
input factor allocation was already distorted and materials were
underutilized, so the firms did not want to increase this distortion.
Another reason might be that these forward-looking firms knew that in
the future they would not be able to obtain the extra materials required
to make these workers more productive and neither would they be able to
fire these workers if relative prices change again. Thus, they chose not
to hire extra workers even when it was optimal to do so at the existing
prices.
The estimated average of over-substitution of materials relative to
labour for all-industries is around 3.6 per cent per year. But this
varies by period, with the average being 0.7 per cent in the 1970s and
7.2 per cent between 1996 and 2003. For the years after the reforms,
this over-substitution of materials relative to labour is continuously
increasing despite the fact that the materials are no longer
underutilized relative to labour. This trend indicates that producers
are unwilling to hire workers due to labour market inflexibilities and
firing costs, which should be a concern for Indian policymakers.
[GRAPHIC 4 OMITTED]
The period averages of estimated growth rates are shown in Table 3.
We can see that firms have been continuously increasing their materials
usage much faster than their labour input usage. This results in
increased labour productivity growth, averaging 6.2 per cent per year
for the 1980-90 sub-period and 6.9 per cent for 1997-2003 as the firms
try to move towards an optimal materials-per-worker allocation.
[GRAPHIC 5 OMITTED]
The estimates in Table 3 show that the immediate impact of the
reforms was negative, as both labour productivity growth and TFP growth
slowed down in the 1990-97 period. But if we look at the jump in labour
and capital imput growth during these years, the estimates make sense.
Since the industrial reforms coincided with the opening of capital
markets in 1991, Indian manufacturing units started expanding due to
easier access to capital irrespective of their productivity. But once
capital markets developed and competition from foreign firms increased,
the resources started flowing from inefficient units and industries to
more efficient ones (this reallocation is sometimes called churning).
The government disinvestment initiative also helped in this process. The
result was a 3.2 per cent annual average growth in gross output between
1997 and 2003, despite using less capital stock and fewer workers.
To verify whether the abolition of industrial licensing helped to
remove these distortions, this article estimates the industry-wide
average productivity growth in the years preceding and following the
reforms. Chart 4 presents the results based on a 3-digit industrial
panel data according to the average materials to gross output (nominal)
ratio for manufacturing. The industries using more materials should have
faced higher distortions and hence should have benefitted more from the
removal of the restrictions. The scatter-plot in Chart 5 confirms this.
It shows the increase in 10- year average annual productivity growth
rates between post and pre reform periods (i.e. 1990 to 2000, and 1981
to 1990) is higher for industries that use materials more heavily.
In the Indian manufacturing sector, the interaction of the quota
permit system and labour laws led to sub-optimal materials-per-worker
usage and thus slowed down labour productivity growth. This mechanism is
identified by finding the correlation between underutilization and
productivity growth. Similarly, the combination of high inflation in
materials and less developed credit markets reduced the intermediate
input usage in response to price increases, which in turn resulted in
lower labour productivity. This second mechanism is recognized by
looking at the relationship of materials inflation with productivity and
real wages. This article estimates these two channels using aggregate
data (all-industries) and panel data consisting of 58 industries based
on 3-digit NIC code. The summary of the main relationships for the panel
data is shown in Table 4 and Table 5; and the estimates are plotted in
Chart 5.
For both panel and aggregate data, underutilization of materials is
negatively correlated to labour productivity levels and growth. More
interestingly, the underutilization of (M/L) is also negatively related
to TFP growth. The labour productivity relation is simply an implication
of distorted input allocations. But it is not obvious why TFP growth
should be affected by materials and labour usage. One explanation can be
that this underutilization gives rise to other inefficiencies as well.
For example, to work with less material input per worker, the production
process needs to be reorganized and machines run fewer hours per week.
This change in schedule can cause disruption and lower productivity.
The distortion measures (underutilization and under-substitution)
are negatively related to TFP growth because of the nature of the Indian
government's policies. Labour is bounded by below and material
input has an upper bound. Since (M/L) is lower than the optimal at
existing prices, any change that makes this underutilization worse is
going to increase the inefficiencies. That is why labour growth is
negatively related to TFP growth and materials growth is positively
related to TFP growth.
Labour productivity measured in value-added terms is negatively
related to labour growth due to decreasing marginal product. The
estimates show that even value-added labour productivity is positively
related to materials growth. This highlights the importance of material
input for the manufacturing sector performance. The reason for this
finding is the widespread underutilization in materials in Indian
manufacturing resulting from the presence of restrictive industrial
policies. An increase in the growth rate of materials helps to reduce
this distortion and enables workers to increase their value-added.
The estimates show that the measures of productivity growth are
negatively related to under-substitution of materials relative to labour
and positively related to growth in materials usage. These results
support the presence of distortion-inefficiency channels operating
through the interaction of policies. The under-substitution leads to the
worsening of input distortion, and hence using less material inputs per
worker, resulting in lower productivity growth. An increase in materials
usage helps to bring the input allocation closer to optimal and
increases productivity growth. This article also finds that intermediate
input (materials) price inflation is negatively related to real wage
growth. This negative correlation occurs because in the absence of
credit availability, the rising materials prices mean fewer materials
per worker and thus reduced labour productivity. This lower labour
productivity means a drop in real wages. The overutilization of capital
relative to labour has a positive correlation with labour productivity,
which is the usual capital-deepening effect.
Role of Economic Reforms
India's current phase of economic reforms began in 1991 when
the government faced an exceptionally severe balance-of-payments crisis.
The Congress government at the time started short-term stabilization processes followed by longer-term comprehensive structural reforms. In
1991, the government of India adopted the New Industrial Policy. It
abolished industrial licensing for almost all industries, irrespective
of the levels of investment. This industrial policy was supported by
trade policy that removed import restrictions and liberalized foreing
direct investment as part of the multi-faceted gradual reform process.
Ahluwalia (2002) outlines and evaluates these sets of structural
reforms. India's reform program also included wide-ranging reforms
in the banking system and capital markets relatively early in the
process, with reforms in insurance introduced at a later stage.
These reforms broke down two major links that were responsible for
distorted input usage and lower productivity growth. The removal of
quantitative restrictions meant that firms were no longer forced to
operate at a sub-optimal level. Firms still cannot reduce the number of
workers, but they can increase the intermediate inputs usage (and
capital usage) and make the allocation optimal for given prices.
Similarly, improved credit access meant that firms could reach this
optimal allocation even in periods of high inflation. Firms can borrow
money, use the optimal inputs and repay the loan after selling the
output (because higher intermediate input prices usually mean that
output prices are also higher).
The estimated growth rates and relationships among them in Tables 3
and 4 clearly show the positive impact of the reforms. After the
reforms, materials growth averaged around 7 per cent per year between
1991 and 2003 for all-industries. The effect of materials growth on
labour productivity growth and TFP growth amplified after 1991. The
pooled OLS coefficient between materials growth and labour productivity
growth is 0.7 for the subsample 1991-2003, more than double the value
for the entire time period of 1970-2003. The increase in coefficient
value implies that materials growth is becoming more important in labour
productivity growth.
[GRAPHIC 6 OMITTED]
[GRAPHIC 7 OMITTED]
As mentioned earlier, some of the estimation results run contrary
to the conventional wisdom which suggests that growth in net value added
should not depend on materials at all. This article finds that labour
productivity growth and TFP growth measured in value added terms are
strongly correlated with growth in materials usage. This relationship
becomes stronger after the reforms (pooled OLS coefficient is 0.48 for
subsample of 1991-2003 compared to 0.18 for the entire time period). The
relationship between intermediate input inflation and real wages breaks
down after the reforms. The coefficient is close to zero and no longer
significant after 1991. The explanation is that the
inflation-productivity mechanism was being driven by low credit
availability. Reforms increased the credit availability by liberalizing
capital markets.
Another important consequence of the economic reforms was that one
of the restrictions that only applied to the manufacturing industry was
removed. The import quota and industrial licensing policies abolished
during the reforms were more relevant to the manufacturing sector than
the service sector. In recent years, the growth rates of the
manufacturing sector have been higher than the service sector growth
rates; this was something very uncommon in the years before the reforms.
Did Import Quotas Lead to Underutilization and Bottlenecks?
The quantity restrictions were only applicable to imported goods.
But there were no controls on buying intermediate inputs from within the
country. It will be prudent to make a distinction between imported and
domestic materials input and then re-do the whole analysis. The
underutilization and its negative effect on Indian manufacturing
productivity should exist only for imported materials. Unfortunately,
the ASI dataset does not have the split between domestic and imported
materials.
We can look at two different trends which indicate that the
imported intermediate inputs were the real bottlenecks in Indian
manufacturing. The actual production process of many manufacturing
industries can be characterized as a Leontief specification, where
production involves transforming the input. In such industries,
output--and thus labour productivity--becomes restricted by the least
freely available input. In the presence of an import permit-quota
system, the least freely available inputs were imported intermediate
goods.
If imported inputs were the bottlenecks, the removal of these
restrictions would lead to an increase in demand for these inputs
without corresponding increase in the other inputs. That is exactly what
happened in Indian manufacturing. As shown in Table 3, the materials
input grew at the average annual rate of 6.9 per cent and 5.4 per cent
for the 1990-97 and 1997-2003 periods respectively. The corresponding
average growth rate for labour input were 2.7 per cent and -3.7 per
cent. Chart 6 shows the growth in imported raw materials and
intermediate inputs. There is a distinct jump after the reforms. The
growth rates of all the imported items other than coal increased
significantly. Indian manufacturing firms that were previously forced to
operate at less than optimal (M/L) ratio due to quota restrictions
started moving towards their potential productivity by importing and
using more intermediate inputs.
The continuous increase in the material content of output, as shown
in Chart 7, indicates that Indian manufacturing is becoming more
specialized or high-end. But the production of (low value) intermediate
goods is not being outsourced to the unorganized manufacturing sector in
India, as both output share and output growth rates of the unorganized
manufacturing sector have declined in the years after the reforms (Chart
8).
This reaffirms the belief that only the imported
intermediate-inputs were the bottlenecks. The Indian manufacturing firms
were not restricted in their access to raw materials and
intermediate-inputs that were domestically available. But these goods
were not perfect substitutes for the quota-restricted imported
intermediate inputs. The production functions of manufacturing firms
(e.g. chemical, semi-conductors, electronics, and specialized goods)
often have Leontief type complementarities between intermediate inputs
and labour input. The restrictions on these goods created a bottleneck
that choked the productivity growth in Indian manufacturing.
In fact, the concurrent trends of the increase in the growth rates
of imported intermediate goods and the decrease in the growth rates of
unorganized manufacturing output are consistent with the mechanisms
discussed. Since there were no restrictions on buying domestically
produced raw materials, which were often bought by the unorganized
manufacturing sector, the reforms had no direct effect on these firms.
But the firms in the organized sector, which were previously using the
(imperfect) substitutes produced domestically by the unorganized sector,
started reducing their reliance on these domestic goods after the
reforms and started importing the desired intermediate inputs.
[GRAPHIC 8 OMITTED]
This is why the output growth rate of the unorganized sector fell
in the late 1990s.
Conclusion
This article has shown how the import permit-quota system in the
presence of inflexible labour laws resulted in input distortions in
Indian manufacturing that had negative effects on productivity growth.
The role of intermediate inputs in the manufacturing sector deserves
greater attention, especially for developing countries. Even though the
reforms have abolished import restrictions in India, labour laws are
still unchanged. Indian manufacturing firms are shying away from hiring
workers, which is not socially desirable. India has a huge pool of
unskilled workers and the need to move them out of the unproductive
agricultural sector is becoming more urgent. Policymakers should
reconsider these labour laws in view of the fact that they are hindering employment growth and leading to jobless output growth in Indian
manufacturing.
The evidence of the mechanisms identified in this article would be
more robust if the data on imported and domestic materials input were
included in the analysis. In the absence of such data, one could try to
rank the industries based on their imported input requirements and then
see whether the effects are more severe in the industries that use a
larger share of imported materials. Another important dimension in
analyzing the results is the production function complementarities
between materials and labour. We should see more prominent results in
industries which have Leontief type production processes.
References
Ahluwalia, M. (2002) "Economic reforms in India since 1991:
has gradualism worked? Journal of Economic Perspectives" Vol. 16,
No. 3, pp. 67-88.
Ahsan, A. and Pages, C. (2007) "Are all labor regulations
equal?: Assessing the effects of job security, labor dispute, and
contract labor laws in India," World Bank Working Paper, No. 4259.
Basu, K. and Maertens, A. (2007) "The pattern and causes of
economic growth in India," Oxford Review of Economic Policy, Vol.
23, No. 2, pp. 143-167.
Besley, T. and Burgess, R. (2004) "Can Labor Regulation Hinder Economic Performance? Evidence From India," Quarterly Journal of
Economics, Vol. 19, No. 1, pp. 91-134.
Bhagwati, J. (1978) Anatomy and consequences of exchange control
regimes, National Bureau of Economic Research.
Bhagwati, J, and Desai, P. (1970) India: planning for
industrialization: industrialization and trade policies since 1951,
Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Chand, S. and Sen, K. (2002) "Trade liberalization and
productivity growth: evidence from Indian manufacturing," Review of
Development Economics, Vol. 6, No. 1, pp. 120-132.
Das, D. (2004) "Manufacturing productivity under varying trade
regimes: India in the 1980s and 1990s," Economic and Political
Weekly, Vol. 39, No. 5.
Fernandes, A., and Pakes, A. (2008) "Factor utilization in
indian manufacturing: A look at the world bank investment climate
surveys data," NBER Working Paper, No. 14178.
Hsieh, Chang-Tai and Klenow, Peter, J. (2007) "Misal location
and Manufacturing TFP in China and India", NBER Working Papers, No.
13290.
Kochhar, K., U. Kumar, R. Rajan, A. Subramanian,, and I.
Tokatlidis, I. (2006) "India's pattern of development: What
happened, what follows?" Journal of Monetary Economics, Vol. 53,
No. 5, pp. 981-1019.
Krueger, A. (1997) "Trade policy and economic development: how
we learn.," American Economic Review, Vol 87, No. 1, pp. 1-22.
Mohammad, S. and J. Whalley (1984) "Rent seeking in India: its
costs and policy significance," Kyklos, Vol. 37, No. 3, pp.
387-413.
Abhay Gupta (1) MITACS
(1) The author is an analyst for Mathematics of Information
Technology and Complex Systems (MITACS) research network. This article
draws from the author's PhD thesis submitted to the Department of
Economics at the University of British Columbia. Email:
abhayg@abhayg.com.
(2) See Basu and Maertens (2007) for a survey of some of the
explanations for economic growth in India after the reforms.
Table 1
Stock Market Indicators in 1990, India and Other Countries, 1990
Market Market Value
Capitalization Cap. / GDP Traded / GDP
(billions US$) (per cent) (per cent)
India 38.6 12.2 6.9
Malaysia 48.6 110.4 24.7
Korea 110.6 43.8 30.1
Singapore 34.3 93.6 55.4
Hong Kong 83.4 111.5 46.3
Germany 355.1 22.2 21.4
United States 3,059.4 53.3 30.5
Table 2
Productivity Growth in Indian Manufacturing--An Example
Scenario Optimal Response L & M Only L
Restrictions Restrictions
(Pre-Reform) (Post-Reform)
Baseline L-Prod. = 1
Car/Worker.
L ! = 100
Workers.
M = 100 Engines.
400 Tires.
Y = 100 Cars.
Positive L-Prod. = 1.2 [bar.M] = 100 L' (still many
Technology Cars/Worker. Engines. 400 disincentives to
Shock. Tires. (fixed increase the
L ? (depending due to permit workers)
on wage increase quota)
and labour M = 120 Engines.
supply, assume L' (no incentive 480 Tires.
110). to increase the
workers) Y = 120 Cars.
M = 132 Engines.
528 Tires. Y = 100 Cars. L-Prod. = 1.2
Cars/Worker.
Y = 132 Cars. L-Prod. = 1
Car/Worker. Y Growth = 20%.
Y Growth = 32%.
Y Growth = 0%
Table 3
Growth Rates in Indian Manufacturing by Period
(average annual rate of change in per cent)
1970- 70-80 80-90 90-97 97-03
2003
Gross Output 6.0 6.4 6.6 7.0 3.2
Labour 1.1 3.6 0.4 2.7 -3.7
Capital 3.6 3.8 4.4 8.7 -3.9
Materials 6.5 4.8 8.8 6.9 5.4
value-Added 4.4 6.4 4.1 4.7 0.9
Using Gross-Output
Labour Productivity 4.9 2.8 6.2 4.3 6.9
TFP 1.3 2.4 2.2 -0.8 2.8
Using value-Added
Labour Productivity 3.2 3.0 3.6 1.9 4.3
TFP 2.3 4.6 4.2 -2.2 4.8
Table 4
Distortions and Productivity Correlations, 1970-2003, 3-Digit NIC
Code Panel
Productivity Distortion Measure (X) Corr. Co-Var.
Measure (Y)
Lab. Prod. (GO) Under-Util. M/L -0.69 -0.29
Over-Util. K/L 0.6 0.29
Lab. Prod. (Val-Add) Under-Util. M/L -0.26 -0.15
Over-Util. K/L 0.29 0.19
[DELTA] Lab. Under-Subs. M/L -0.42 -0.33
Prod. (GO) Over-Subs. K/L 0.18 0.2
[DELTA] Lab. Prod. Under-Subs. M/L -0.3 -0.28
(Val-Add) Over-Subs. K/L 0.21 0.25
[DELTA] TFP (GO) Under-Util. M/L -0.31 -0.27
Over-Util. K/L 0.2 0.13
[DELTA] TFP (Val-Add) Under-Subs. M/L -0.26 -0.21
Over-Subs. K/L 0.17 0.13
Productivity Distortion Measure (X) Pooled OLS
Measure (Y) [beta]
Lab. Prod. (GO) Under-Util. M/L -0.99 ***
Over-Util. K/L 0.74 ***
Lab. Prod. (Val-Add) Under-Util. M/L -0.5 ***
Over-Util. K/L 0.46 ***
[DELTA] Lab. Under-Subs. M/L -0.5 ***
Prod. (GO) Over-Subs. K/L 0.21 *
[DELTA] Lab. Prod. Under-Subs. M/L -0.34 ***
(Val-Add) Over-Subs. K/L 0.36 ***
[DELTA] TFP (GO) Under-Util. M/L -0.37 ***
Over-Util. K/L 0.23
[DELTA] TFP (Val-Add) Under-Subs. M/L -0.35 **
Over-Subs. K/L 0.19
* 10% significance level ** 5% significance level
*** 1% significance level
Table 5
Factor Inputs, Prices and Productivity, 1970-2003, 3-Digit NIC Code
Panel
Productivity Input/Price Pooled OLS [beta]
Measure (Y) Measures (X)
Real Wage Materials Inflation -5.91 ***
Inflation -8.6 *** (73-90)
0.003 (91-03)
[DELTA] Lab. Materials Inflation -0.32 ***
Prod. (GO)
[DELTA] Lab. Materials Inflation -0.39
Prod. (Val-Add)
Lab. Prod. L Growth, M Growth -0.39 ***, 0.11 **
(Val-Add)
[DELTA] Lab. L Growth, M Growth -0.46 ***, 0.33 ***
Prod. (GO) -0.73 ***, 0.7 *** (91-03)
[DELTA] Lab. L Growth, M Growth -0.34 ***, 0.18 ***
Prod. (Val-Add) -0.43 ***, 0.48 *** (91-03)
[DELTA] TFP L Growth, M Growth -0.22 ***, 0.2 *** (91-03)
(GO)
[DELTA] TFP L Growth, M Growth -0.23 ***, 0.12 ***
(Val-Add) -0.31 ***, 0.38 *** (91-03)
* 10% significance level ** 5% significance level
*** 1% significance level