首页    期刊浏览 2024年11月30日 星期六
登录注册

文章基本信息

  • 标题:Why were voters against the 2022 Munich Winter Olympics in a referendum?
  • 作者:Coates, Dennis ; Wicker, Pamela
  • 期刊名称:International Journal of Sport Finance
  • 印刷版ISSN:1558-6235
  • 出版年度:2015
  • 期号:August
  • 语种:English
  • 出版社:Fitness Information Technology Inc.
  • 摘要:The city of Munich (capital of the German federal state of Bavaria) had submitted a bid for the 2018 Winter Olympics. Munich would have been the first city ever to host Olympic Summer and Winter Games. However, it lost against Pyeongchang, South Korea, which won in the first round of voting. One issue with Munich's application was that several farmers were against the bid because they had ecological concerns and did not want to provide their land. Fifty-eight percent of voters from Garmisch-Partenkirchen, which would host Alpine skiing events, voted in favor of a petition in support of hosting the 2018 Winter Olympics only two months before the International Olympic Committee (IOC) met to decide the host for 2018; the timing hindered Munich's lobbying efforts. At the same time only 51% voted against a review of the contracts necessary to host the event (Mackay, 2013). This somewhat weak public support was also observed by the IOC members and may have influenced their decision. Public support is one of the requirements of a bid and the bid committee of the IOC is required to take public opinion into account when selecting an Olympic host city. For Munich's 2018 bid no referendum had been held.
  • 关键词:Referendum;Referendums

Why were voters against the 2022 Munich Winter Olympics in a referendum?


Coates, Dennis ; Wicker, Pamela


Introduction

The city of Munich (capital of the German federal state of Bavaria) had submitted a bid for the 2018 Winter Olympics. Munich would have been the first city ever to host Olympic Summer and Winter Games. However, it lost against Pyeongchang, South Korea, which won in the first round of voting. One issue with Munich's application was that several farmers were against the bid because they had ecological concerns and did not want to provide their land. Fifty-eight percent of voters from Garmisch-Partenkirchen, which would host Alpine skiing events, voted in favor of a petition in support of hosting the 2018 Winter Olympics only two months before the International Olympic Committee (IOC) met to decide the host for 2018; the timing hindered Munich's lobbying efforts. At the same time only 51% voted against a review of the contracts necessary to host the event (Mackay, 2013). This somewhat weak public support was also observed by the IOC members and may have influenced their decision. Public support is one of the requirements of a bid and the bid committee of the IOC is required to take public opinion into account when selecting an Olympic host city. For Munich's 2018 bid no referendum had been held.

The supporters of the bid planned to submit another bid for the 2022 Winter Olympics--but this time with the prior approval of the entire population of the host region. For this purpose, a referendum was held on November 10, 2013. People living in four different regions were allowed to vote: (1) city of Munich, (2) city of Garmisch-Partenkirchen (which would host the alpine skiing, ski jumping, and Nordic combined competitions), (3) district of Traunstein (including the community of Koenigssee, which would host the bob, luge, and skeleton competitions), and (4) district of Berchtesgadener Land (including the community of Ruhpolding, which would host the biathlon and cross country skiing competitions; Spiegel Online, 2013). In order for the referendum to pass, the majority of people in all four regions would have to vote for the bid. The outcome of the referendum was that all four regions voted against the bid, although the share of yes votes differed among communities: in Munich, 47.8% voted on favor of the bid, 48.4% in Garmisch Partenkirchen, 40.3% in the district of Traunstein, and 45.9% in the district of Berchtesgadener Land (Munich, 2013). The purpose of this study is to identify the effect of various community characteristics had on the percent of favorable votes in this referendum. Secondary community-level data on voting outcomes and community characteristics (i.e., proximity, socio-economic factors, and political factors) are used for the examination. Specifically, this study seeks to understand the determinants of voting on this referendum to learn if there are lessons for the broader public debate on hosting mega-events.

Referenda and Political Support

The present research question is a particularly interesting one in the sports policy literature for at least two reasons. First, referenda on hosting mega-events are rare because there is no culture of having referenda in many democratic states (with the exception of Switzerland, where referenda are common). Politicians are considered representatives of the population and make such decisions on their behalf. At the same time, the increasing spending that is associated with hosting mega-events and the increasing concerns of the population that the money could be spent elsewhere (e.g., health system, education) raises the pressure on politicians who delegate the decision of whether the city should submit a bid. Research has shown that many events were not found to deliver the predicted positive economic welfare (e.g., Baade, Baumann, & Matheson, 2010; Peeters, Matheson, & Szymanski, 2014). Another reason for the rareness of referenda could be that the bidding committee tries to avoid them because they were often lost.

One of the first referenda on hosting the Olympics was held in the context of Olympic Games in Denver. In 1970, Denver was awarded the 1976 Winter Olympics by the IOC. In 1972, a state-wide referendum was held and a bond issue that should have helped finance the Games was rejected. Consequently, Denver withdrew as an Olympic host (Hersh, 2015). In recent years, referenda on hosting mega-events are becoming more common. Indeed, there were at least four such referenda with regard to the 2022 Winter Olympics, in Krakow, Poland; Oslo, Norway; and St. Moritz/Davos, Switzerland, as well as in Munich. Only the Norway bid passed the referendum, while the Krakow bid and St. Moritz/Davos bid were not approved by the public. Moreover, the bid of the 2010 Winter Olympics in Vancouver, Canada, was preceded by a referendum that passed with 64% yes votes. At the time of writing, Boston was bidding for the 2024 Olympic Summer Games, but given the weak public support for this bid in recent polls, the U.S. Olympic Committee (USOC) is concerned when it comes to a referendum given the negative outcome of the Denver referendum (Hersh, 2015).

Second, the political parties in power--CSU (Conservative Party; state government) and SPD (Social Democratic Party; city of Munich government)--were strong supporters of the bid, yet the referendum failed. For example, Horst Seehofer (CSU), the Prime Minister of the state of Bavaria, supported the Olympic bid of Munich. He said that he would support the Olympic bid and would also express this support in the parliament (Focus, 2013). Christian Ude (SPD), the Mayor of Munich, also argued in favor of submitting the bid. He encouraged everyone who would be allowed to vote on that Sunday in Munich, Garmisch-Partenkirchen, in the Berchtesgadener Land, or who lives in the district of Traunstein to vote in favor of the Olympic idea and its chances. He stated that people should vote for the most sustainable concept and against the giantism-- and against a monopoly of dictatorial regimes as a host of future Olympic Games (German Olympic Sports Confederation [DOSB], 2013b). Joachim Herrmann (CSU), the Bavarian Minister of the Interior, stated further advantages of Munich hosting the 2022 Winter Olympics. He said that the 2022 Olympic Games would lead to a huge impulse for the development of mass, elite, and disability sport in Bavaria and that people should fight together for Olympic Games (DOSB, 2013a). While ruling party members supported the bid, members from opposition parties (e.g., Green Party, Leftist Party) were against it. For example, Ludwig Hartmann, leader of the parliamentary group of the Green Party in the Bavarian state parliament, stated that the financial risks of hosting Olympic Games and the destruction of the environment would be enormous (Abendzeitung Munchen, 2013). Similarly, members of the Leftist Party were against the bid and also supported the campaign NOlympia.

Olympic bids were also supported by leading politicians in other countries. In March 2010, the Polish head of state, Lech Kaczynski, stated he would like Poland to submit a bid for the 2022 Winter Olympic Games. Krakow's Mayor, Jacek Majchrowski, would have liked to see Krakow hosting the Games because he anticipated positive effects for the region: "I regret that the referendum has put a definite end to [...] the project that I considered to be very important for the development of the whole region" (Washington Post, 2014, n. p.). In Norway and Switzerland, the bid was mainly supported by leading politicians, but more people seemed concerned about the bid because of the financial burdens of hosting the Olympics. In Norway, one of the two political parties in power, the Progress Party, had voted against a state guarantee of 4 billion [euro], while the Conservative Party, including the Norwegian Prime Minister Erna Solberg, supported Oslo's bid (n-tv, 2014). Tarzisius Caviezel, Mayor of Davos, Switzerland, supported the bid, but expressed his frustrations because the critics would systematically frighten the population with calculations of the anticipated debts accompanied with hosting the Olympics (Tagesanzeiger, 2013).

Related Literature

Referenda in Sport

Previous research on referenda in sport has mainly looked at referenda in the context of building sport stadia in North America (e.g., Brown & Paul, 1999; Coates & Humphreys, 2006; Fort, 1997). One study examined the referendum on the location of a new professional football (soccer) stadium (Allianz Arena) that was held in Munich in 2001. Results showed that voters generally supported the construction of the new arena, but tried to shift the stadium away from their neighborhood (Ahlfeldt & Maennig, 2012). Yet, in the case of the Allianz Arena only the infrastructure (e.g., roads, public transport) was paid by the local government, not the facility itself. Moreover, several studies analyzed people's willingness to support bids for hosting Olympic Games (e.g., Atkinson, Mourato, Szymanski, & Ozdemiroglu, 2008; Preuss & Werkmann, 2011; Walton, Longo, & Dawson, 2008) using the contingent valuation method (CVM). However, previous research has not yet looked at referenda for hosting major sport events like the Olympic Games, possibly because referenda are relatively new in this context.

Factors Determining the Decision of Voters

The individual decision to vote for or against a bid for a mega-sport event can be conceptualized like a cost-benefit-analysis (Kesenne, 2005) or a utility maximization problem (Coates & Humphreys, 2006). Individuals may carefully think about the benefits and costs that hosting the Olympic Games would have for themselves and possibly also for the wider community or region. Their votes may be driven by individual perceptions of utilities in various areas. For example, an increase in public debt as a result of hosting the event may decrease the individuals' utility (Feld & Kirchgassner, 2001) and people may decide to vote against the bid. Altogether, it is assumed that the voters' decisions in the present research are influenced by a variety of factors that can be classified into at least three areas: (1) proximity, (2) socio-economic factors (e.g., population structure, importance of tourism, taxes, employment situation), and (3) political factors. These factors are explained in the next paragraphs.

First, it is relevant whether people live in close proximity to the event and are, thus, directly affected by the event. Applied to Olympic bids, it is important whether the community the individual is living in would host some of the events. On the one hand, people could demonstrate a "not in my backyard" attitude that was observed in the context of the Allianz Arena in Munich (Ahlfeldt & Maennig, 2012). On the other hand, people may appreciate the excitement of living close to the location of a megaevent and, thus, support the bid (Atkinson et al., 2008). Coates and Humphreys (2006) analyzed referenda for two sport facilities in the United States. They found evidence for proximity benefits: voters in close proximity to the facilities tended to support subsidies more than people living farther away from the facilities. For the present study it is difficult to formulate an assumption: while it looks like the majority of studies support a positive effect of proximity on the support of the event (e.g., Atkinson et al., 2008; Coates & Humphreys, 2006), a recent study on voting behavior in Munich--the geographic area of interest--found negative proximity effects (Ahlfeldt & Maennig, 2012).

Second, socio-economic factors including the population structure, importance of tourism, taxes, and employment situation may drive the decision to vote in favor or against the bid. Starting with the population make-up, the gender and age distribution may be critical. Research shows that males and younger people are more interested in sports and more likely to participate in sport themselves (e.g., Downward & Rasciute, 2015). Walton et al. (2008) documented a positive effect of male gender and a negative age effect when examining the determinants of willingness-to-pay (WTP) for hosting the 2012 Olympic Games. These results indicate that males and younger people provided more support for the Games given their significantly higher WTP. Yet, no significant effects of age and gender were found in Atkinson et al.'s (2008) study examining the same event. Similarly, Preuss and Werkmann (2011) found no significant effects of age and gender when examining the WTP for hosting the 2018 Winter Olympics in Munich. Given the inconsistent findings in previous research, the formulation of assumptions for the present study is difficult--particularly because the previous Munich study (Preuss & Werkmann, 2011) documented insignificant effects.

Moreover, the importance of tourism to the community may play a role in voting behavior. Specifically, if the community is a tourism destination, it would expect a greater demand for tourism services, like hotel accommodations and meals in restaurants, and thus may be more supportive of a bid to host a major tourism attraction. Indeed, some research shows that the tourism sector benefits from hosting major sport events (Daniels, Norman, & Henry, 2004). Yet, other studies indicate that the tourism benefits are often overstated (e.g., Baade et al., 2010; Peeters et al., 2014). For example, for the 2002 Winter Olympic Games in Salt Lake City, Utah, it was documented that not all sectors of the economy benefited equally from the Games. While the hospitality industry prospered, retailers (e.g., merchandise and department stores) suffered and their experienced losses were greater than the gains of hotels and restaurants (Baade et al., 2010). During the 2010 Football World Cup, South Africa experienced a large increase in net tourism during the event; yet, the net increase in tourists visiting the country was less than half compared with the predictions of the event organizers (Peeters et al., 2010). An overstatement of economic benefits is a common phenomenon in economic impact studies that are conducted ex ante. Ex-post studies are more likely to lead to realistic results because they can rely on observed expenditure, travels, tax income, spectators, etc. (Gratton et al., 2000; Porter & Fletcher, 2008).

While residents may appreciate hosting the Olympics, they may be deterred by other factors that may be accompanied by the event. Franck (2005) has shown that the reasons why referenda are rejected do not necessarily have to do with the actual decision due for approval, but more with the voters' subjective anticipated consequences. In the context of the Olympics, tourist venues may be concerned with using regular tourism--an assumption supported by a study on the 2002 Winter Olympics when Utah ski resorts actually lost sales during the event period (Baade et al., 2010). In this case, Olympic tourists may have crowded out regular tourism. Crowding out of tourists is a common phenomenon and has been observed in other contexts, too (e.g., Chou, Hsieh, & Tseng, 2014). Since many of the voting communities are tourist destinations, crowding out of regular tourists may be a concern of local voters.

Furthermore, tax competition can have an impact on voting outcomes in referenda (Feld, 1997). While economic benefits of events or facilities are conferred to a small set of actors, the costs are distributed among the public (Brown & Paul, 1999). In most cases, taxpayer money is used to build facilities and organize major sport events (e.g., Brown & Paul, 1999; Coates & Humphreys, 2006). Moreover, it can be interesting to know where taxpayer money comes from. Specifically, the type and amount of taxes a community generates may reflect the importance of various industry branches to the community. For example, communities generating high revenues from sales and business taxes tend to have many business companies, stores, or hotels. Given the evident discrepancy in tourism benefits between the hospitality industry and retailers (that are both covered by sales taxes) in previous research (Baade et al., 2010); it is difficult to make assumptions as to how the importance of different taxes within a community affects voting outcomes.

Moreover, the employment situation in the community must be considered from a socio-economic perspective. Employment effects of major sport events have been extensively examined in the literature (e.g., Coates & Humphreys, 2003; Hotchkiss, Moore, & Zobey, 2003; Jasina & Rotthoff, 2008). The majority of studies show that employment effects of sport events can be considered relatively small at best (e.g., Baade & Matheson, 2000; Coates & Humphreys, 2003) and are only short-term in nature (Spilling, 1999). For example, Feddersen and Maennig (2013) did not find any significant employment effects when examining the 1996 Atlanta Olympic Games. In their analysis, they contradict the results of Hotchkiss et al. (2003), who reported a substantial increase in jobs in the regions associated with the Games. Thus, a few studies such as the one above nurture the hope of local residents suffering from unemployment to find a new job in the context of the event. Independent of the scientific research in this field (which many voters may not be aware of), residents may perceive the event as an opportunity for creating new jobs. Therefore, it could be assumed that people tend to vote in favor of the Olympic bid in communities with high unemployment.

Third, the voting outcome may be affected by political factors. Generally speaking, decisions that are put to a vote are oftentimes complex in nature and in their entirety difficult to understand for the local population (Franck, 2005). Similarly, the decision to support an Olympic bid is complex in nature. Since individuals cannot gather all the information themselves, they have to trust in part what some of the people in charge (i.e., leading politicians) say. As outlined previously in this paper, financial risks and ecological concerns associated with hosting the Olympics are typically mentioned by opposition parties, while ruling party members tend to advance the positive effects of hosting the Olympics in terms of economic impact, image improvements, and sport development. Given these contradictory statements, people may trust the members of the party they usually give their vote. Thus, the voting behavior in political elections (e.g., elections of the state parliament) may represent an indicator for the outcome of a referendum. This implies that in communities with high support of the ruling political parties, the percentage of yes votes in the referendum may also be higher compared to communities where opposition parties receive a high share of the votes. As mentioned earlier, the ruling parties at the time of the referendum were the Conservative Party (Bavaria state government) and the Social Democratic Party (Munich city government). It can therefore be expected that the higher the support for these two ruling parties in the community, the higher the share of yes-votes in the referendum.

Data and Empirical Approach

Data Collection

To examine the factors that affected the voting outcome in the communities, secondary data on all 52 communities that participated in the referendum were collected. These communities include the cities of Munich and Garmisch-Partenkirchen, 35 communities in the district of Traunstein, and another 15 communities in the district of Berchtesgadener Land. Munich has more than 1.4 million inhabitants across 25 neighborhoods (i.e., suburbs) for which voting results are available and is by far the most populous community in the region. We consider two distinct samples, one that treats the 52 communities as equally influential observations and one of 76 communities in which the 25 neighborhoods of Munich are treated as separate observations. This last approach is feasible because the neighborhoods in Munich have several thousand inhabitants and thus are far larger than most of the more rural communities in the data.

The percentage of yes votes by community was made available from the official website of the city of Munich (Munich, 2013). Moreover, data on population numbers by age and gender, tourism, unemployment, and tax income were retrieved for every community from the official website of the German Federal Statistical Office (Federal Statistical Office, 2014). The respective population, tourism, and unemployment data for the 25 suburbs of Munich were collected from the website of the Statistical Office of Munich (Statistical Office Munich, 2014a; 2014b; 2014c); tax data are not available on the suburb level and so are other data on household characteristics that are only available at a district or state level. Thus, the sample with 76 communities in which the 25 neighborhoods of Munich are treated as separate observations limits the number of explanatory variables because of data availability issues.

Empirical Analysis

Regression models (OLS models with robust standard errors) examine the effect of various community characteristics on the referendum voting results. The dependent variable is the percent of favorable votes in each community. Several independent variables are included in the analysis. Since not all communities involved in the referendum would also be hosts, one variable captures whether the community is a potential host (1=yes). Potential tourism impact is proxied with the number of hotel beds in the community per capita. The labor market situation is measured with the number of unemployed people per capita. Two months before the referendum state election were held in Bavaria. The shares for the top five political parties are also included in the models to measure the political orientation of inhabitants. These are the Conservative Party (CSU), the Social Democratic Party (SDP), the Green Party (Bundnis 90/Die Granen), the Liberal Party (FDP), and the Leftist Party (Die Linke). The models also control for population characteristics including the share of males and the share of inhabitants of working age (18 to 64 years). Three sets of models are estimated. In the first set, all independent variables from Table 1 are included. In the second set, the models contain the best specification variables that were selected based on the corrected Akaike Information Criterion (AICC). Both sets of models are estimated for the larger sample (n=76; including the 25 Munich neighborhoods) and for the restricted sample (n=52; Munich represents one observation). In the third set, the best specification for the three regions (Munich, Traunstein, Berchtesgadener Land) using the AICC will be presented. (1) An -level of 0.1 is used for all statistical tests.

Results and Discussion

Descriptive statistics are reported in Table 1 for both samples. Because Munich is far more populous than any of the other voting districts, all explanatory variables are measured as percentages, proportions, or per capita. Although there is little difference between the two samples, some variables are worth noting. One of these is the potential host. Only one of the 25 neighborhoods of Munich is identified as a potential host of some Winter Olympic event; so in the 76 observations sample the proportion of potential hosts is about a third smaller than in the sample when Munich is a single observation. Also, the shares of the political parties differ between the two samples. In the sample in which Munich is a single observation the Conservative share is higher, while the Social Democrat share is lower than in the sample in which the 25 Munich neighborhoods are treated as separate observations. This is because the inhabitants of Munich favor the Social Democratic Party (and also have the mayor from this party), while people in the rest of Bavaria tend to support the Conservative Party. Thus, the Social Democrat share is higher when Munich is represented with 25 cases in the sample. The tax variables are not available for the individual neighborhoods of Munich. Consequently, our analysis can only use tax variables when the sample treats Munich as a single observation rather than as 25 separate voting districts. Tax variables are measured as thousands of Euros per capita. For example, the mean income tax revenue per capita of 0.367 indicates an average of 367 [euro] per person.

Results of regression models are reported in Tables 2 through 5. Table 2 shows two models, one using 76 observations, in which the 25 Munich neighborhoods are separate observations, and another with 52 observations with Munich as just one observation. The results between the two samples are quite similar. Many variables have roughly equal coefficient estimates in both samples, but often the estimate is only significant in the larger sample, if at all. In both samples, the stronger is the Leftist Party in a community, measured as the share of the vote from the previous federal state election, the lower is the likelihood of a vote in favor of the Munich Winter Olympics bid. Likewise, in both samples, the larger is the Green Party share of the vote, the lower is the likelihood of a vote for the bid. Thus, the effects of the opposition parties' share are significant and negative, while the effects of the ruling parties' share are inconsistent and mostly insignificant. The positive and significant effect of the potential host variable shows that districts identified as potential hosts of some portion of the event have a higher likelihood of a favorable vote. The positive effect of potential host is contrary to previous research examining voting behavior at a referendum in Munich where voters demonstrated a "not in my backyard" attitude (Ahlfeldt & Maennig, 2012).

A higher level of unemployment, as measured by the number of unemployed people per capita in the community, leads to a statistically significant increase in the likelihood of a favorable vote in the larger sample, but not in the smaller. Unemployed people may assume that employment opportunities are associated with the Olympics. The effect is only significant in the larger sample because unemployment rates are typically higher in large cities than in rural areas and the effect of Munich is stronger when its 25 neighborhoods are considered separately. In the larger sample, the higher the number of hotel beds per capita in a district, the smaller the likelihood of a yes vote. The initial hypothesis was that hotel beds per capita is a measure of the strength of tourism in the economy and would indicate support for the bid. Our results are at odds with that assumption. It is likely that the hotels in the regions are already well occupied in the winter and people may be afraid of losing their regular guests during the period of the Olympic Games. The concern of crowding out of regular tourists is nurtured by previous research (Baade et al., 2010; Chou et al., 2014).

A difficulty in voting studies of this sort is that the variables are all imperfect proxies for the determinants of individual voting behavior. Moreover, variables may be highly correlated with one another, leading to weak results from individual hypothesis tests. Consequently, joint significance tests are conducted on variables in groups. Table 2 reports the F-statistic and p-value for the null hypotheses that (a) all political party variables carry coefficients of zero, (b) all socio-economic variables' coefficients are zero (excluding the tax variables), (c) the three regional dummy variables have zero coefficients, and (d) all tax variables have zero coefficients in the restricted sample model. The alternative hypothesis in each case is that at least one of the coefficients in the group is non-zero. For this test, the tax variables are considered separately because they are not available for the larger sample including the 25 Munich neighborhoods. The results in Table 2 indicate that one can reject the null hypothesis for the political party and regional dummy variables in both models, but cannot reject the null hypothesis with respect to tax variables and the remaining socio-economic variables.

To aid interpretation, Table 3 presents elasticity estimates for the coefficients from the regression equations of Table 2. For example, a 10% increase in unemployment share raises the yes vote percentage by 1.28%. At the mean of the percent of favorable votes (M=44.1), 1.28% is about 0.56 percentage points of vote share; the share of favorable votes is not especially responsive to changes in the unemployment share. A 10% increase in the share of Leftist votes would decrease the percentage of yes votes by 1.79% (larger sample) and 1.98% (smaller sample), respectively. The corresponding percentage points of vote share at the mean of the percent of favorable votes are 0.79 (larger sample) and 0.87 (smaller sample), respectively. For the share of Green party votes, the respective percentage points of vote share at the mean of the percent of favorable votes are 0.74 (larger sample) and 1.08 percentage points (smaller sample). All of the elasticities are relatively small, indicating that favorable votes are only weakly responsive to the explanatory variables in this first set of models.

Table 4 reports models selected using the AICC. Each model was forced to include the potential host variable, and to select the best model from all the other possible combinations of the explanatory variables. The included regional dummies also come from the best fitting model according to the smallest corrected AIC value. Which variables are individually significant is similar across Tables 2 and 4. Coefficient estimates are also similar. It is not surprising then that the elasticity estimates are also quite similar.

Table 5 reports results of estimating the model on observations only from a given region and the corresponding elasticities. In effect, this allows every coefficient in the model to differ from region to region. Unfortunately, the city of Garmisch Partenkirchen is not included as it is a single observation. Moreover, none of the regions has many observations, with Traunstein the most with 35. As before, there are no tax variables for the separate neighborhoods of Munich so the search for the best Munich model based on the corrected AIC does not include taxes. The models for Traunstein and Berchtesgadener Land include all the variables.

The Munich regression is interesting for several reasons. First, potential host is not significant. This is likely explained by the fact that there is only one neighborhood within Munich that might have hosted any Winter Olympic events. The second interesting aspect of the Munich regression is that the percent of the working population, the share of males, and the Conservative share have a significant positive effect, but have been insignificant before. The support of younger people and males is in line with previous research (Walton et al., 2008). The Social Democrat share is also significant. It had been negative and significant at the 10% level when Munich was entered as a single observation in Table 2, but now it is significant at the 5% level and positive. The elasticities of yes percentage with respect to these variables are among the largest, with the male share elasticity close to one.

Regressions for Traunstein and Berchtesgadener Land are also interesting. In each case, being a potential host raises the likelihood of a favorable vote. Also, the higher the proportion of Leftist Party votes in the previous parliamentary election, the smaller the share of favorable votes. The elasticity for Leftist share is similarly small for Berchtesgadener Land as for Munich, both of which are about half the elasticity of Leftist share in Traunstein, which is also quite small. Oddly, a greater proportion of males in Berchtesgadener Land induces a smaller proportion of voters favoring the bid, while a larger proportion of males elsewhere, in Munich or Traunstein, raises the proportion favoring it. The elasticity for Traunstein is 1.91, while for Bechtesgadener Land it is -1.65. These elasticities are quite large, suggesting a 10% increase in the male population raises the yes vote percentage by 19% in Traunstein and lowers it by 16% in Berchtesgadener Land. The share of the vote captured by the Green Party in the most recent parliamentary election is negatively related to support for the bid in Traunstein. It is interesting that Green share was significant in Table 2 in both models, but is only significant in the Traunstein model in Table 5. Also, only in Traunstein, higher sales tax revenues per capita raise the percentage of votes favoring the bid, but higher business taxes net of reallocations per capita lower the percentage of favorable votes. Yes-vote share is inelastic with respect to either type of tax.

Conclusion

The purpose of this study was to evaluate the determinants of the percent of yes votes in a referendum on whether the city of Munich and the state of Bavaria should bid to host the 2022 Winter Olympic Games. Referenda on hosting mega-events are a recent phenomenon, and ours is the first empirical analysis of such a vote of which we are aware. A previous bid attempt had failed in part because the IOC observed opposition based on ecological concerns among the population. Consequently, the supporters of a bid sought a referendum to document the local backing for a bid. The political parties in power in the state of Bavaria and the city of Munich, the CSU (Conservative) and the SPD (Social Democrat), supported the bid. Despite this, the referendum failed, not receiving a majority of the votes in any of the four voting districts, even Garmisch-Partenkirchen where a petition had passed in support of a bid only three years earlier. Thus, the size of specific opposition parties is important to voting outcomes. Our results show that likely host communities tended to be more supportive of the bid. In communities with greater Green Party and Leftist Party support, both of which opposed the bid, voters were less likely to cast votes for the bid. There is also evidence that communities with greater unemployment were more supportive of the bid, while communities with a high number of hotel beds per capita were less supportive.

There are lessons for other potential bidders in the results. The findings indicate what factors are considered critical to the local population when it comes to such voting decisions. Local politicians and bidding committees could use this information to better understand the local population and to improve their support for hosting Olympic Games and other major sporting events. First, the positive effect of potential host on the percent of yes votes suggests that winning support for the bid to host the Winter Olympics is more likely the greater the dispersal among the communities of possibly hosting an event. Second, the strength of the influence of the share of the population at working age and the male population in the analysis by region suggests that Olympic promoters should target people over 65 years and females to build support for the events. Third, the negative effect of hotel beds indicates that the local population is concerned with a potential crowding out of regular tourists during the Games--a concern that should be addressed by the promoters of the bid. Finally, the consistent strength of the unemployment variable indicates that bid supporters are right to emphasize the employment possibilities linked with the bid.

The present research has some limitations that may guide future research. It is based on a relatively small sample size, although additional observations for neighborhoods in Munich were already added. Yet, the sample size is naturally restricted to those communities involved in the referendum. Moreover, the study is limited to the secondary data that are available at the community level or neighborhood level in Munich. Future research may examine voting behavior in referenda beyond the community level, for example, by surveying citizens in the respective regions. In this context it would be interesting to examine what role potential financial burdens of bidding for Olympic Games and hosting Olympic Games that are imposed by the IOC play in the decision-making process of citizens.

Dennis Coates is a professor of economics at the University of Maryland, Baltimore County, and an international researcher at HSE-Perm, Russian Federation. His research interests include sport economics and political economy.

Pamela Wicker is a senior lecturer at the German Sport University Cologne. Her research interests include economics of sport consumption, spectator sport economics, and non-profit economics.

References

Abendzeitung Munchen. (2013). Grune gegen Olympiabewerbung--"Sind wir denn Deppen?". Retrieved from http://www.abendzeitung-muenchen.de/inhalt.winterspiele-2022-inmuenchen-gruene-gegen-olympia- bewerbung-sind-wir-denn-deppen.d17e56c9-b116-4c03-b785-118204f4f40f.html

Ahlfeldt, G., & Maennig, W. (2012). Voting on a NIMBY facility: Proximity cost of an "iconic" stadium. Urban Affairs Review, 48, 205-237.

Atkinson, G., Mourato, S., Szymanski, S., & Ozdemiroglu, E. (2008). Are we willing to pay enough to 'back the bid'? Valuing the intangible impacts of London's bid to host the 2012 Summer Olympic Games. Urban Studies, 45, 419-444.

Baade, R. A., Baumann, R. W., & Matheson, V. A. (2010). Slippery slope? Assessing the economic impact of the 2002 Winter Olympic Games in Salt Lake City, Utah. Region et Developpement, 31, 81-91.

Baade, R. A., & Matheson, V. A. (2000). An assessment of the economic impact of the American football championship, the Superbowl, on host communities. Reflets et Perspectives de la Vie Economique, 39(2/3), 35-46.

Brown, C., & Paul, D. M. (1999). Local organized interests and the 1996 Cincinnati sports stadia tax referendum. Journal of Sport & Social Issues, 23, 218-237.

Coates, D., & Humphreys, B. R. (2003). The effect of professional sports on earnings and employment in the services and retail sectors in US cities. Regional Science and Urban Economics, 33, 175-198.

Coates, D., & Humphreys, B. R. (2006). Proximity benefits and voting on stadium and arena subsidies. Journal of Urban Economics, 59, 285-299.

Chou, C., Hsieh, S. F., & Tseng, H. P. (2014). The crowding-out effects of Chinese tourists on inbound tourism in Taiwan. Tourism Economics, 20, 1235-1251.

Daniels, M. J., Norman, W. C., & Henry, M. S. (2004). Estimating income effects of a sport tourism event. Annals of Tourism Research, 31, 180-199.

DOSB. (2013a). Bayerns Innenminister fur Olympia 2022 in Munchen. Retrieved from http://www.dosb.de/de/olympia/olympische-news/detail/news/bayerischer_innenminister_fuer_olympia_2022_in_muenchen/

DOSB. (2013b). Munchen 2022: Christian Ude widerspricht den Kritikern. Retrieved from http://www.dosb.de/de/olympia/olympische-news/detail/news/-83aa84424d/

Downward, P., & Rasciute, S. (2015). Exploring the covariates of sport participation for health: An analysis of males and females in England. Journal of Sports Sciences, 33, 67-76.

Feddersen, A., & Maennig, W. (2013). Employment effects of the Olympic Games in Atlanta 1996 reconsidered. International Journal of Sport Finance, 8, 95-111.

Federal Statistical Office. (2014). Regionalstatistik. Retrieved from https://www.regionalstatistik.de/genesis/online

Feld, L. P. (1997). Exit, voice, and income taxes. European Journal of Political Economy, 13, 455-478.

Feld, L. P., & Kirchgassner, G. (2001). Does direct democracy reduce public debt? Evidence from Swiss municipalities. Public Choice, 109, 347-370.

Focus. (2013). Kabinett unterstutzt Olympiabewerbung. Retrieved from http://www.focus.de/regional/muenchen/kabinett-kabinett-unterstuetzt-olympiabewerb ung_aid_1135852.html

Fort, R. (1997). Direct democracy and the stadium mess. In R. G. Noll & A. Zimbalist (Eds.), Sports, jobs and taxes: The economic impact of sports teams and stadiums (pp. 146-177). Washington, DC: The Brookings Institution Press.

Franck, R. (2005). Why did a majority of French voters reject the European Constitution? European Journal of Political Economy, 21, 1071-1076.

Gratton, C., Dobson, N., & Shibli, S. (2000). The economic importance of major sports events: A case-study of six events. Managing Leisure, 5, 17-28.

Hersh, P. (2015). Could vote kill Boston Olympic bid? Chicago Tribune. Retrieved from http://www.chicagotribune.com/sports/international/chi-could-vote-kill-boston-olympicbid-20150120-story.html

Hotchkiss, J. L., Moore, R. E., & Zobey, S. M. (2003). Impact of 1996 Summer Olympic Games on employment and wages in Georgia. Southern Economic Journal, 69, 691-704.

Jasina, J., & Rotthoff, K. W. (2008). The impact of a professional sports franchise on county employment and wages. International Journal of Sport Finance, 3, 210-227.

Kesenne, S. (2005). Do we need an economic impact study or a cost-benefit analysis of a sports event? European Sport Management Quarterly, 5, 133-142.

Mackay, D. (2013). Munich sets date for referendum on whether to bid for 2022 Winter Olympics and Paralympics. Retrieved from http://www.insidethegames.biz/olympics/winterolympics/2022/1014547-munich-sets- date-for-referendum-on-whether-to-bid-for-2022- winter-olympics-and-paralympics

Munich. (2013). Burgerentscheid "Bewerbung um Olympische und Paralympische Winterspiele 2022" am 10.11.2013. Retrieved from http://www.muenchen.de/rathaus/Stadtpolitik/ Wahlergebnisse/Buerger_Volksentscheide/Winterspiele_2022.html

n-tv. (2014). Winterspiele 2022 in Oslo? Parlament streitet um Olympia-Bewerbung. Retrieved from http://www.n-tv.de/sport/olympia/Parlament-streitet-um-Olympia-Bewerbung-article12771196.html

Peeters, T., Matheson, V. A., & Szymanski, S. (2014). Tourism and the 2010 World Cup: Lessons for developing countries. Journal of African Economies, 23, 290-320.

Porter, P. K., & Fletcher, D. (2008). The economic impact of the Olympic Games: Ex ante predictions and ex post reality. Journal of Sport Management, 22, 470-486.

Spiegel Online. (2013). Olympia-Bewerbung 2022: Biathlon und Langlauf sollen in Ruhpolding stattfinden. Retrieved from http://www.spiegel.de/sport/wintersport/olympia-bewerbung2022-biathlon-und-langlauf- in-ruhpolding-a-921866.html

Spilling, O. R. (1999). Long-term impacts of mega-events: The case of Lillehammer 1994. In C. Jeanrenaud (Ed.), The economic impact of sport events (pp. 135-166). Neuchatel: Editions CIES.

Statistical Office Munich. (2014a). Arbeitsmarkt. Retrieved from http://www.muenchen.de/ rathaus/Stadtinfos/Statistik/Arbeitsmarkt.html

Statistical Office Munich. (2014b). Bevolkerungsbestand. Retrieved from http://www.muenchen. de/rathaus/Stadtinfos/Statistik/Bev-lkerung/Bev-lkerungsbestand.html

Statistical Office Munich. (2014c). Wirtschaft. Retrieved from http://www.muenchen.de/ rathaus/Stadtinfos/Statistik/Wirtschaft.html

Tagesanzeiger. (2013). Den Bundnern wird systematisch Angst gemacht. Retrieved from http://www.tagesanzeiger.ch/schweiz/standard/Den-Buendnern-wird-systematisch- Angstgemacht/story/27754249?dossier_id=1620

Walton, H., Longo, A., & Dawson, P. (2008). A contingent valuation of the 2012 London Olympic Games. Journal of Sports Economics, 9, 304-317.

Washington Post. (2014). Krakow withdraws 2022 Olympic bid after residents vote 'no'. Retrieved from http://www.washingtonpost.com/blogs/early-lead/wp/2014/05/27/krakow-withdraws2022-olympic-bid-after- residents-vote-no/

Endnote

(1) At the suggestion of a referee, separate models were estimated that include only one group of variables, political, socio-economic, or regional, as well as the potential host dummy. These results are available upon request

Dennis Coates [1,2] and Pamela Wicker [3]

[1] University of Maryland, Baltimore County

[2] National Research University, Higher School of Economics

[3] German Sport University Cologne
Table 1. Descriptive Statistics

                             Obs.    Mean    Std.    Minimum  Maximum
                                             Dev.

Variables                        25 Munich neighborhoods separate
                                           observations

Percent of favorable votes    76    44.106   6.552   24.740   57.370
Potential host (1 = yes)      76    0.053    0.225   0.000     1.000
Conservative share            76    44.735   9.639   23.780   62.069
Social Democrat share         76    19.127   9.841   4.987    38.230
Green share                   76    14.201   6.310   4.894    38.004
Liberal share                 76    4.706    2.289   0.911    10.110
Leftist share                 76    2.268    1.020   0.342     4.859
Hotel beds per capita         76    0.126    0.227   0.000     1.320
Percent age 18 to 64          76    63.689   4.667   55.888   79.400
Proportion male               76    0.492    0.013   0.457     0.517
Unemployed per capita         76    0.018    0.007   0.007     0.037

                                      Munich one observation

Percent of favorable votes    52    42.364   6.889   24.740   57.370
Potential host (1 = yes)      52    0.077    0.269   0.000     1.000
Conservative share            52    48.612   8.186   36.053   62.069
Social Democrat share         52    13.061   4.383   4.987    32.127
Green share                   52    15.065   6.940   4.894    38.004
Liberal share                 52    4.353    2.425   0.911     9.310
Leftist share                 52    2.212    1.167   0.342     4.859
Hotel beds per capita         52    0.163    0.263   0.000     1.320
Percent age 18 to 64          52    61.500   2.158   55.888   67.534
Proportion male               52    0.492    0.013   0.457     0.517
Unemployed per capita         52    0.014    0.005   0.007     0.027
Income tax per capita         52    0.367    0.057   0.247     0.597
Sales tax per capita          52    0.029    0.020   0.005     0.102
Business tax minus            52    0.328    0.338   0.001     0.037
  reallocation per capita
Farm property tax per         52    0.012    0.008   0.000     0.037
  capita
Real property tax per         52    0.111    0.051   0.051    0.3111
  capita

Table 2. Determinants of the Percent of Favorable Votes

Variables                            (1)                 (2)
                                  25 Munich          1 Munich Obs.
                                Neighborhoods

Potential host                 7.134 * (0.073)      11.09 *** (0.001)
Conservative share             0.00417 (0.981)        -0.159 (0.339)
Social Democrat share          -0.292 (0.263)        -0.478 * (0.099)
Green share                   -0.491 ** (0.010)     -0.646 *** (0.005)
Liberal share                   0.328 (0.358)         0.278 (0.612)
Leftist share                -3.305 *** (0.003)     -3.541 *** (0.003)
Hotel beds                    -6.748 ** (0.024)       -5.357 (0.288)
Percent age 18 to 64            0.214 (0.275)         -0.290 (0.653)
Male share                     -8.101 (0.853)         0.297 (0.998)
Unemployed per capita         322.7 ** (0.022)        377.6 (0.255)
City of Garmisch             -14.71 *** (0.008)       -3.470 (0.700)
  Partenkirche
Traunstein                     -3.375 (0.385)         11.58 (0.191)
Berchtesgadener Land           -5.860 (0.107)         10.78 (0.270)
Income tax per capita                                 24.22 (0.334)
Sales tax per capita                                  155.9 (0.130)
Business tax minus                                    -4.571 (0.178)
  reallocation per capita
Farm property tax per                                 185.8 (0.116)
  capita
Real property tax per                                 -33.65 (0.400)
  capita

Constant                       50.46 * (0.073)        63.80 (0.367)
Observations                         76                     52
R-squared                           0.695                 0.741
(a) F_political                    14.001                 4.871
Prob>F                              0.000                 0.002
(b) F_socio-economic                1.854                 0.944
Prob>F                              0.130                 0.451
(c) F_region                        4.416                 3.266
Prob>F                              0.007                 0.033
(d) F_tax                                                 1.232
Prob>F                                                    0.316

Note: *** p < 0.01; ** p < 0.05; * p < 0.1; robust
p-values in parentheses.

Table 3. Elasticities

                                 (1)             (2)
Variables                     25 Munich     1 Munich Obs.
                            Neighborhoods

Potential host                 0.007 *        0.016 ***
                               (0.050)         (0.001)
Conservative share              0.004          -0.183
                               (0.981)         (0.340)
Social Democrat share          -0.125         -0.149 *
                               (0.263)         (0.098)
Green share                   -0.168 **      -0.245 ***
                               (0.012)         (0.005)
Liberal share                   0.036           0.030
                               (0.359)         (0.612)
Leftist share                -0.179 ***      -0.198 ***
                               (0.004)         (0.003)
Hotel beds                    -0.020 **        -0.021
                               (0.029)         (0.291)
Percent age 18 to 64            0.313          -0.429
                               (0.275)         (0.653)
Male share                     -0.092           0.004
                               (0.853)         (0.998)
Unemployed per capita         0.128 **          0.126
                               (0.022)         (0.257)
City of Garmisch             -0.004 ***        -0.001
  Partenkirchen                (0.008)         (0.700)
Traunstein                     -0.039           0.196
                               (0.384)         (0.194)
Berchtesgadener Land           -0.026           0.069
                               (0.109)         (0.270)
Income tax per capita                           0.214
                                               (0.336)
Sales tax per capita                            0.105
                                               (0.124)
Business tax minus                             -0.036
  reallocation per capita                      (0.179)
Farm property tax per                           0.054
  capita                                       (0.115)
Real property tax per                          -0.089
  capita                                       (0.400)
Observations                     76              52

Note: *** p < 0.01; ** p < 0.05; * p < 0.1;
p-values in parentheses

Table 4. Best Fit and Elasticities--AICC

                             (1)             (1)
Variables                 25 Munich       25 Munich
                        Neighborhoods   Neighborhoods
                                        (Elasticities)

Potential host             6.918 *         0.007 **
                           (0.063)         (0.044)
Leftist share            -3.355 ***       -0.181 ***
                           (0.000)         (0.000)
Green share              -0.409 ***       -0.139 ***
                           (0.001)         (0.001)
Munich                      1.286           0.009
                           (0.471)         (0.470)
Hotel beds                -4.484 *         -0.013 *
                           (0.077)         (0.087)
Unemployed per capita     196.907 *        0.078 *
                           (0.092)         (0.090)
Berchtesgadener Land      -3.094 **       -0.013 **
                           (0.034)         (0.039)
City of Garmisch         -10.438 ***      -0.003 ***
Partenkirchen              (0.003)         (0.003)
Traunstein
Male share
Constant                 54.573 ***
                           (0.000)

Observations                 76               76
R-squared                   0.680

                             (2)             (2)
Variables               1 Munich Obs.   1 Munich Obs.
                                        (Elasticities)

Potential host             5.657 *         0.008 **
                           (0.050)         (0.040)
Leftist share            -2.899 ***       -0.161 ***
                           (0.001)         (0.001)
Green share              -0.379 ***       -0.143 ***
                           (0.007)         (0.009)
Munich
Hotel beds
Unemployed per capita      329.600          0.110
                           (0.199)         (0.197)
Berchtesgadener Land
City of Garmisch
Partenkirchen
Traunstein                 3.531 *         0.059 *
                           (0.057)         (0.053)
Male share                 76.483           0.901
                           (0.230)         (0.232)
Constant                    9.414
                           (0.781)
Observations                 52               52
R-squared                   0.596

Note: *** p < 0.01; ** p < 0.05; * p < 0.1; (robust)
p-values in parentheses.

Table 5. Regions Best Fit and Elasticities--AICC

                             (1)            (1)
Variables                   Munich         Munich
                                       (Elasticities)

Potential host              -0.026         -0.001
                           (0.182)        (0.183)
Percent age 18 to 64      0.021 ***      0.760 ***
                           (0.000)        (0.000)
Male share                3.641 ***      0.938 ***
                           (0.003)        (0.003)
Conservative share        0.031 ***      0.574 ***
                           (0.000)        (0.000)
Hotel beds                -0.425 **      -0.011 **
                           (0.029)        (0.029)
Social Democrat share      0.013 **       0.222 **
                           (0.018)        (0.018)
Leftist share             -0.086 **      -0.109 **
                           (0.016)        (0.017)
Sales tax per capita
Business tax minus
  rellocation per capita
Green share
Constant                  -4.642 ***
                           (0.000)
Observations                  25             25
R-squared                   0.953

                              (2)            (2)
Variables                  raunstein      Traunstein
                                        (Elasticities)

Potential host             0.414 ***      0.005 ***
                            (0.000)        (0.000)
Percent age 18 to 64

Male share                 6.581 **        1.911 **
                            (0.012)        (0.013)
Conservative share

Hotel beds                -0.366 ***      -0.030 ***
                            (0.000)        (0.001)
Social Democrat share

Leftist share             -0.125 ***      -0.206 ***
                            (0.000)        (0.000)
Sales tax per capita       8.848 ***      0.140 ***
                            (0.001)        (0.001)
Business tax minus        -0.365 ***      -0.075 ***
  rellocation per capita    (0.001)        (0.001)
Green share               -0.020 ***      -0.219 ***
                            (0.003)        (0.004)
Constant                   -3.012 **
                            (0.026)
Observations                  35              35
R-squared                    0.707

                              (3)             (3)
Variables                  Berchtes-       Berchtes-
                          gadener Land    gadener Land
                                         (Elasticities)

Potential host             0.460 ***       0.013 ***
                            (0.000)         (0.000)
Percent age 18 to 64
Male share                 -6.116 ***      -1.649 ***
                            (0.003)         (0.003)
Conservative share
Hotel beds
Social Democrat share
Leftist share              -0.135 ***      -0.093 ***
                            (0.004)         (0.004)
Sales tax per capita
Business tax minus
  rellocation per capita
Green share
Constant                   2.975 ***
                            (0.003)
Observations                   15              15
R-squared                    0.836

Note: *** p < 0.01; ** p < 0.05; * p < 0.1; (robust)
p-values in parentheses.
联系我们|关于我们|网站声明
国家哲学社会科学文献中心版权所有