Financial fair play in European club football: what is it all about?
Franck, Egon
Introduction
The new UEFA Club Licensing and Financial Fair Play Regulations
(FFP regulations) are an enhancement of the Club Licensing System
introduced at the start of the 2004/2005 football season (UEFA 2012). In
order to be admitted to UEFA's club competitions (Champions League
and Europa League), each club must fulfill a series of defined quality
standards falling into five principal categories: sporting,
infrastructure, personnel, legal, and financial. After elaborate
consultation with the stakeholders of football (representatives of
clubs, players, leagues, and national associations), UEFA has used the
implementation of the FFP regulations to introduce additional financial
requirements that will be monitored by a newly created body of
independent legal and financial experts, the Club Financial Control Body
(CFCB).
The reason for agreeing to implement additional financial
requirements was a shared perception that football clubs were sliding
into an ever-deepening financial crisis that ultimately could threaten
the long-term viability and sustainability of the entire system. Indeed,
the financial results of the clubs competing in European competitions
were worsening year after year despite the fact that football as an
industry was booming. According to the UEFA Benchmarking Report for the
financial year 2011, (1) the revenues of European top-division clubs had
grown by an average yearly rate of 5.6% in the preceding five years to
an impressive total of 13.2bn [euro], while for example the average
yearly growth rate of the whole economy in the Euro zone amounted to
only 0.5 %. Despite the strong growth in revenues, the aggregate net
losses reported by the European top division clubs in the financial year
2011 added up to 1.7bn [euro]. Compared to the financial year 2007,
aggregate net losses had almost tripled. An impressive 63% of European
top-division clubs reported operating losses in the financial year 2011.
The proportion of clubs, where auditors expressed concerns about whether
the club could still trade normally in 12 months' time, was 1 in 7.
The percentage of clubs with negative net equity facing a situation with
debts larger than reported assets amounted to 38%.
The introduction of the break-even requirement, which is without a
doubt the cornerstone of the new regulations, needs to be interpreted
against this background. This new rule, defined in Articles 58-63 (UEFA
2012), requests that clubs should live within their own means by and
large. More precisely, clubs are in compliance with the break-even
requirement if "relevant expenses" (2) do not exceed
"relevant income" (3) in the reporting periods combined to one
so called "monitoring period" (4) by more than the
"acceptable deviation" (5) of 5m [euro]. While there is some
leeway at the beginning, allowing the "acceptable deviation"
to exceed the 'normal' level of 5m [euro] up to a level of 45m
[euro], provided that equity participants and/or related parties are
willing to inject the respective funds, UEFA's plan is to gradually
reduce this "abnormal" injection in the longer run. (6)
A closer look at the notions of relevant income and relevant
expenses makes clear that benefactors can still inject unlimited sums of
money into football clubs, for example by investing in stadia, youth
academies, or community projects, since such expenditures do not count
as relevant expenses and therefore do not enter the break-even
calculation. However, benefactors are no longer able to rescue a club
for licensing purposes if the latter overinvested in salaries and
transfers with the result that relevant expenses exceed relevant income
by more than the total acceptable deviation.
Knowing ex ante the 'normal' acceptable deviation plus
the maximum 'external rescue package' taken into consideration
by UEFA for licensing purposes, football managers will have no more
options to soften their clubs' budget ex post. If they wish access
to European competitions, managers will have to run clubs based on
payrolls that allow them to stay within the hard limit drawn by their
football income and the "total" acceptable deviation defined
in the FFP regulations.
As every new regulatory measure, FFP has encountered substantial
critique. This critique falls into three different categories:
1. UEFA issued a regulation that forgoes potential benefits arising
from substantial injections of "external" money into football
payrolls (e.g., Madden, 2011).
2. UEFA issued a regulation that limits competition in the player
market and puts downward pressure on wages like a US salary cap, but
without compensating through benefits from increased competitive balance
(e.g., Peeters & Szymanski, 2012).
3. UEFA issued a regulation that will "ossify" or
"freeze" the hierarchy of European football, creating a
barrier to entry (e.g., Vopel, 2011; Sass, 2012).
It is the purpose of this paper to take these concerns as a
starting point for discussing the likely effects of the new regulations.
(7) As a by-product it will become obvious why and in which points the
concerns are unfounded.
An extended debate of criticism 1 is offered in the following
section. It turns out that limiting external money injections through
FFP does not simply translate into "less money for football
payrolls" but rather into "restoring efficient managerial
incentives." The time for repeated managerial moral hazards and
rent-seeking games in European football is over if FFP comes into
action. Football managers will have to concentrate on productive efforts
to develop the football business as a whole and in a sustainable way
instead of focusing on "payroll-gambling" in a sort of
"football casino." It is true that some external money will
not find a direct way into football payrolls any longer due to the
capped maximum rescue package of benefactors. However, as FFP restores
incentives for "good management" in football clubs, new
revenues will be generated, which in the end could allow the payment of
even higher salaries than in the current system.
Criticism 2 portrays FFP as a restrictive measure comparable to a
US salary cap. However, a closer look at the regulation later in this
paper shows that, contrary to a US salary cap, FFP formulates a very
"tolerant" restriction of competition, which would not even be
binding in any "normal" business environment. Downward
pressure on salaries is only a transient effect that makes sense in an
industry characterized by massive overspending. Moreover, US salary caps
are the wrong benchmark for assessing the potential of FFP to contribute
to more vibrant competition in the open European football system.
Criticism 3 claiming an ossification of the football hierarchy
through FFP obviously assumes that "small clubs" can only or
can better challenge "large clubs" in a system of unlimited
money injections. This assumption is challenged later in this paper.
There is no mechanism, which systematically allocates
"unlimited" money injections according to a pattern that makes
small clubs relatively more competitive. Instead, the existence of an
inverse mechanism, making sure that money comes to money, is much more
plausible. Breaking the money comes to money dynamics and increasing the
importance of "management quality" through FFP could be a more
reliable way to shake established football hierarchies.
Why Capped Money Injections Are Not Simply "Less Money For
Payrolls" But Rather "Incentives For Better Management"
Simply put, the question is: Why do the rules require that, by and
large, "all clubs should compete within the limit of the financial
resources they generate in football" instead of just requiring that
"all clubs should compete within the limit of the financial
resources they somehow generate"? (P. Madden, personal
communication). If a club manages to organize the external funds needed
for repeated bailouts, it will stay in operation despite chronically
overspending and the show simply goes on. Why should we care? At first
sight, money injections seem to be beneficial as they bring
"additional money" into the game, which--under certain
assumptions--raises the level of playing talent, makes consumers
happier, players wealthier, etc. (8) Unfortunately, unregulated money
injections do not simply translate into "more money for the
payroll," but they have the potential to adversely affect
managerial incentives and decision-making in football. To see why,
let's look at the two basic forces that shape the investment
incentives of clubs.
The Contest Logic of Football Competition
Football championship races are examples of a certain form of
economic competition, which is known as contest in the literature. (9)
Even if we assume rational behavior and profit-maximizing clubs,
contests may exhibit an interesting phenomenon of revenue dissipation
called overinvestment. (10) It has been shown that various factors
aggravate the problem of overinvestment in the football industry, for
example: (11)
* A stronger correlation between talent investment and winning
probability (a higher discriminatory power of the contest success
function)
* Simultaneous (as opposed to consecutive) investments
* An additional exogenous prize (e.g., UEFA Champions League
qualification)
* A system of promotion and relegation
* Increasing revenue differentials within a league (i.e., less
revenue sharing)
* Increasing revenue differentials between hierarchical leagues
As explained elsewhere (Franck, 2010), both increased
commercialization and the implemented format of competition in European
football have presumably positively impacted on these triggers, thus
increasing the incentives to gamble on sporting success and overinvest
in playing talent. Overinvestment and gambling on success are, to some
extent, 'normal' in this environment. They are
'normal' in the sense that even rational and profit-maximizing
clubs would engage in such dissipation of revenues.
However, the concept of overinvestment, which explains why even
profit-maximizing clubs would fail to maximize profits at the league
level, is not sufficient to understand the extreme dissipation of
revenues that has brought many clubs into a situation where the value of
their liabilities exceeds the value of their assets. (12) In other
words, the idea of an arms race is too weak to describe competition in
an industry that continues to operate in full swing despite the fact
that a substantial part of the participating competitors is technically
bankrupt. (13) The term "zombie race" seems to be more
appropriate in this context. Obviously, the transition from an arms race
to a zombie race requires that the normal threat of dissolution of the
club in case of insolvency is not functioning as a hard constraint. This
leads us to the second element of the story, the Soft Budget Constraints
(SBC) under which the majority of football clubs operate.
The Soft Budget Constraints of Football Clubs
The observation that football clubs do not face the same threat of
dissolution as firms in other industries when systematically failing to
balance their books is not new at all. Both sports economists and
journalists have dealt with the issue extensively. (14) The renowned
British sports journalist Simon Kuper brings it to the point when he
writes:
Clubs are immortal chiefly because creditors dare not pull the
plug. The club's brands are strong enough to cow banks and taxmen.
And so clubs can incur debt without fear ... Much of football's
debt will never be repaid. So it will be written off. Large chunks
will be nationalized ... (2009)
As Szymanski (2009) has stressed, the mechanism leading to the
result that "clubs can incur debt without fear" (Kuper, 2009)
is similar to the mechanism known as "too big to fail" from
the banking sector. To my knowledge, the first sports economist linking
football's permanent and inbuilt financial crisis to the theory of
Soft Budget Constraints (SBC) pioneered by Janos Kornai (1980a, 1980b,
1986) has been Wladimir Andreff (2007, 2011). Recently Storm (2012) and
Storm and Nielsen (2012) have also proposed to analyze football clubs as
special cases of the SBC phenomenon initially studied by Kornai in
post-socialist countries. (15)
Some form of "supporting organization" (Kornai, Maskin,
& Roland, 2003, p. 5) steps in with a sufficiently high probability
in case of a deficit of the football club and relieves the club from the
pressure to "cover its expenditures out of its initial endowment
and revenue" (Kornai, Maskin, & Roland, 2003, p. 4).
SBC theory deals with a rather complex chain of causality between
the following three factors (Kornai, Maskin, & Roland 2003, p.
15-16):
a. The political, social, and economic environment that generates
the background for the development of SBC expectations. (16)
b. The motives of the supporting organization within this
background to step in ex post and bail out the otherwise insolvent
organization (in our case, the club). While the motives of the latter to
ask for rescue are quite self-evident (almost trivial in the case of
profit-oriented organizations and still very straightforward in the case
of non-profit organizations, where remuneration, prestige, and power of
their leaders remains attached to organizational survival), (17) the
motives of supporting organizations can be very diverse.
c. The inefficiencies generated by the SBC syndrome.
The literature on the SBC syndrome is very rich, both in formal
models treating mostly the link between elements b and c in rather
restricted and specific fields of study, as well as in conceptual and
empirical investigations focusing more on element a and on the links
between a and b. (18) Storm (2012) deserves tribute for an insightful
adaptation of Kornai's SBC concept to the specific environment of
European football. His treatment of element a covers a wide range of
interesting and relevant topics in the political, social, and economic
environment that contributes to the development of SBC expectations
(Storm 2012, p. 23-30). However, elements b and c, that is, the motives
of supporting organizations, the typical set of SBC-induced
inefficiencies, and the mechanisms through which these are generated,
require a more detailed and comprehensive explanation (Storm 2012, p.
30-32). Thus, I would like to focus more on elements b and c in the
following analysis.
Two types of supporting organizations are typical for the football
industry: the state and private benefactors.
The State as Supporting Organization Softening the Budget
Constraints of Football Clubs Soft taxation, soft credit, and soft
administrative prices are examples of rescue measures taken by the state
in order to bail out football clubs. (19) A typical form of a soft
administrative price would be the use of a municipal stadium based on an
agreement that allows for ex post adjustments of the price once the
football club is in trouble. Soft credit occurs when the credit
contracts of state banks or state controlled banks with football clubs
are not enforced but instead routinely postponed and rescheduled.
Similarly, soft taxation refers to the toleration of tax debts by the
state tax office.
Currently, Spanish football clubs provide a prominent example for
the SBC syndrome generated by constant failure of the Spanish state to
enforce its tax laws. According to Van Rompuy (2012), Spanish football
clubs owed 750m [euro] in taxes and 600m [euro] in social security to
the Spanish state and therefore ultimately to the Spanish taxpayer as of
September 2012. (20) Faced with the allegation of treating football
clubs more favorably than taxpayers in times of austerity measures and
with the accusation of providing state aid and distorting competition in
European football, the Spanish government drew back from an initial plan
to give tax amnesty to football clubs. (21) Instead, an agreement with
the Spanish Professional Football League was reached in April 2012 to
regain control over tax payments. However, the new measures have to be
interpreted in the broader context of past measures that proved as
failures to enforce tax laws.
As early as 1984, a debt restructuring plan was agreed upon between
the Spanish government and a committee of club presidents that provided
for 2.5% of the revenues from the Spanish football betting pools to be
reserved as guarantee for outstanding taxes.
With the advent of competition in the betting industry, the state
pools collections went down and clubs simply piled up new debt. A second
debt-restructuring plan came in 1990 with a new law, the Spanish Sports
Act. Only Spanish clubs that had shown positive capital balances over
the playing seasons 1985/86 to 1898/90 were allowed to remain in
members' associations (Barcelona, Madrid, Bilbao, and Osasuna). The
rest of the clubs were transformed into sports joint-stock companies
with limited liability in the hope that professional business governance
structures would improve financial accountability. Moreover, the newly
formed sports jointstock companies were relieved from old tax debts by
passing these over to the league, which in turn received a share from
the football pools as compensation. As joint-stock companies, the clubs
also raised new capital on the market to cover their other debts.
Nevertheless, the overinvestment spiral continued, and the clubs began
piling up new tax debts immediately.
The new protocol signed on 25 April 2012 requires that from the
season 2014/15 onwards the clubs will have to set aside 35% of their
revenues from audiovisual rights sales as guarantee against tax and
social security obligations, which they are expected to settle by 2020.
(22) However, doubts persist that this new agreement will contribute to
the enforcement of tax laws in Spanish football. Firstly, Van Rompuy
(2012, p. 2) points to the fact that the first division in Spain only
generates one third of its revenues from broadcasting rights. Since
clubs are individual sellers, more than 50% of media revenue is
appropriated by Real Madrid and FC Barcelona, leaving a normal club at
approximately 15m [euro] per year. "In fact, it remains unclear how
the obligation to set aside 35% of revenue from selling broadcasting
rights will allow clubs to repay their tax debts" (Van Rompuy,
2012, p. 2). Secondly, the shadow of the past plays an important role in
shaping the future expectations of the clubs. The long history of
commitment failures to enforce the tax laws by the Spanish state cannot
be simply deleted. Van Rompuy gives an illustrative example:
The problem is that the leeway given by the Spanish tax authority
(in the past) has very much contributed to the problem of
overspending clubs. It is clear that the Spanish football clubs had
little incentive to prioritize tax repayment over other outgoings.
To give an example: the Scottish club Rangers was forced into
administration after running up 9 million [pounds sterling] in
unpaid taxes. In Spain, the enormous tax debt of 155 million proved
no barrier to Atletico Madrid to buy the top striker Falcao for a
club record deal of 40 million [euro] in August 2011. (2012, p. 2)
The conduct of the Spanish state in the past has created what
Komai, Maskin, and Roland (2003, p. 12) call an SBC mentality among
Spanish clubs. It is part of the collective experience of Spanish clubs
that the state bails them out of financial trouble by failing to insist
on payment of taxes and social security.
But why does the state behave as a supporting organization for
otherwise insolvent football clubs at all? What are the possible motives
for failing to collect taxes, rescheduling state bank loans,
renegotiating infrastructure prices, etc.? The following two motives
(23) seem particularly relevant:
a. Past softness makes bailouts in the present rational.
It is in the state's own interest to bail out the clubs
because it would lose previous investments (credits, uncollected taxes,
etc.) if the clubs went out of operation. (24) Pushing the clubs to
extinction by immediate strict enforcement of the tax laws would mean
having to write off a substantial part of the tax and social security
debts they have already accumulated, so the Spanish state defers calling
the clubs to full account until 2020 to minimize this risk. (25) Past
soft behavior makes it rational for the state to choose soft behavior in
the present, which unfortunately confirms the SBC expectations of the
clubs. In this sense the shadow of its own bailout past creates a
commitment problem for the Spanish state in the present.
b. Miscalculation of bailout costs by political decision-makers
with limited time-horizons. Even in the situation of a first bailout,
when there are no past investments to recoup, the shut-down of the club
is accompanied by collateral damage to the local economy, which a
rational state has to weigh against the bailout costs. (26) A lot of
elements may add up to collateral damage: For example, fans and
supporters would lose their joint object of identification and would
have to at least temporarily write off emotional and social capital
leading to a wave of unhappiness. Additionally, employees of the club
would lose their jobs, thus raising unemployment in the city; supplier
bills would not be paid, which might cause other bankruptcies; the
municipal stadium would lose its most important tenant; a valued leisure
opportunity would at least temporarily disappear, which might make
potential voters unhappy; the image of the city would deteriorate, which
might discourage investors, etc. The bailout package for the club
usually includes giving tax and social tax reliefs by writing off
respective claims or accepting long-term payables, extending credit
lines through a state controlled bank, providing infrastructure below
cost, bringing in new sponsor deals from the state-controlled or
-dependent utility sector at prices above fair value, or allowing a real
estate development project around the stadium combined with some sort of
facility relocation. In the case of a prominent local football club
supported by numerous fans, bailout tends to be the lesser of two evils
for the state.
Naturally, the managers of the club perfectly understand this
calculation that the state has to make and adapt their behavior
accordingly. Assume that the managers have two investment options.
First, they could act in a responsible manner by making a solid
investment in player talent and aspiring to a mid-table position in the
championship. Such investment behavior would generate only moderate
levels of enthusiasm and glamour, but would almost certainly lead to
balanced accounts. Second, the managers could expend much more on
players than in the first scenario in a gamble to achieve UEFA Champions
League qualification. This approach would generate much higher levels of
enthusiasm and glamour and, if successful, the additional revenues from
prize money, TV, attendances, etc. would lead to balanced accounts on
top of it. However, should the gamble go wrong, the revenues needed to
pay the salaries, transfers, social security taxes, etc. for the much
more expensive squad simply would not materialize. The normal
consequence of being unable to pay open bills is the opening of
insolvency proceedings. However, if it is clear that the local
government fears the collateral damage of a club bankruptcy more than
the cost of the required bailout package, managers can expect to be
rescued with high probability. As a consequence, gambling on success
becomes more attractive for football club managers that are insured
against failure by the state.
Unfortunately, this bailout game has the potential to become an
infinitely repeated game. For the club and its managers, similar
investment scenarios come up again every season. Therefore, in reality
the rescue project does not consist of a single bailout package but of a
geometric progression of bailout packages. Of course, the state could
rescue the club once and announce that there will be no more bailouts in
the future. However, will future politicians really be willing and able
to adhere to this old declaration when faced with a similar situation
during their term of office, where a bailout package appears less
painful than the collateral damage caused by club extinction?
Considering the political realities characterized by the limited
time-horizons of political decision-makers, the state is presumably
better portrayed as an agent with commitment difficulties into the
future.
The consequence of comparing the cost of an isolated bailout with
collateral damage instead of anticipating the entire progression of
future bailout packages is straightforward: Too many clubs will be
rescued too often by the state. Moreover, once the bailout activity gets
started, the soft commitment trap described in a kicks in additionally.
The next rescue intervention is, of course, again the only intervention
taken into consideration when weighing the costs against the benefits of
a bailout. But now it is even clearer that the state must rescue the
club because it would lose previous investments (rescheduled credits,
uncollected taxes, etc.) if the club went out of operation. Club
managers can rely with even higher probability on being bailed out and
cultivate what has been called a SBC mentality.
Private Benefactors as Supporting Organization Softening the Budget
Constraints of Football Clubs
According to the newest UEFA benchmarking report (UEFA, 2013, p.
117), the European top-division clubs reported a net non-profit-related
equity increase of 1.279bn [euro] in the financial year 2011. This
number gives an estimate of the ad hoc capital injections (new equity,
write-off of loans or revaluations) provided by first division club
owners in order to cover the losses and liquidity shortfalls of their
clubs. Private owners, dubbed "sugar daddies," who pay the
open bills of their clubs year after year, have become a typical
phenomenon in football outside Germany, where regulation still requires
that members' associations hold residual control (50% + 1 vote
rule) of all professional football teams. (27)
Well-known English Premier League examples of such benefactors are
Roman Abramovich, who had injected around 1bn [pounds sterling] into
Chelsea by 2012 (Conn, 2012a), when the club finally won the UEFA
Champions League, and Sheikh Mansour, who had already spent the same
amount in the four years up to 2012 at Manchester City (Conn, 2012b),
winner of the Premier League Championship in 2011/2012. In Italy,
Massimo Moratti spent 1bn [euro] by 2012 paying the open bills of Inter
Milan year after year, while Silvio Berlusconi had injected
approximately half of this sum at AC Milan (Iaria, 2012). As to the
total amount the 10 biggest benefactors had injected into Italy's
Serie A up to 2012, Iaria (2012) summarizes:
The exact total is 2.483 billion [euro]. That figure includes every
single financial contribution, be it a cash investment or revision of
financial situation that has been necessary to keep the clubs afloat. In
layman's terms: without that money, football in the
'Belpaese' would no longer exist. Moratti at Inter, Berlusconi
at Milan, Agnelli at Juventus, Garrone at Sampdoria, Della Valle at
Fiorentina, Preziosi at Genoa, Zamparini at Palermo, Pozzo at Udinese,
De Laurentiis at Napoli, Lotito at Lazio ...(Iaria, 2012)
Losing money in football can be rational for a sugar daddy once and
even on a repeated basis because bailout costs need to be weighed
against different positive spillovers generated through ownership of the
club. As analyzed in detail elsewhere, (28) benefactors running football
clubs may profit from the publicity and support provided to their other
businesses, from gains in legitimacy and public acceptance, from direct
access to the substantial cash transactions of a business characterized
by significant money laundering potential, from the prestige of owning
and controlling a high-class object of consumption, etc. As Iaria (2012)
comments on the benefactor role of Silvio Berlusconi at Milan:
"It's almost impossible to untwine football from his political
and business dealings."
Even if a high number of bailouts make sense economically for the
club owners after weighing the costs against the benefits from the
mentioned diverse spillovers, sugar daddies, too, can slide into the
soft commitment problem described above: Against a history of heavy
prior investment, club managers, players, and other employees will
assume that the owner will not just let his club go bankrupt in the case
of a new deficit.
Whether the bailouts are produced by entirely rational legitimacy
seekers, advertising purchasers, sportsman owners or money launderers or
by the same people additionally captured in a soft commitment trap,
their effect on club decision-makers is always the softening of the
budget constraints and the development of an SBC mentality.
Now, what is wrong with an SBC mentality?
Inefficiencies Resulting From the SBCs of Football Clubs
It surely makes a difference whether taxpayers (as in the Spanish
case) or private benefactors (as with Chelsea or Inter in the past) are
bailing out football clubs. As already mentioned, Atletico Madrid paid
40m [euro] in the transfer of Radamel Falcao while at the same time
failing to service a tax debt which was about three times higher. It
seems likely that many Spanish taxpayers contributed to this deal
against their own will by having to accept higher tax rates or simply
more financial risk.
In contrast, private actors generally do not make uninvolved
citizens liable for their football investments and should therefore be
free to spend their wealth as they wish. Or to quote Stefan
Szymanski's characterization of the situation in English football:
"... there has been a sorry procession of one failing businessman
after another--but why should the rest of us worry when they lose their
money?" (Szymanski, 2009).
However, concentrating on the question of whether public or private
money is used for bailouts diverts from the main problem: Bailouts
distort the incentives of decision-makers in football clubs. And in this
respect there is little difference between the bailouts of the state and
the bailouts of private sugar daddies.
Decreasing Price-Elasticity of Demand, Talent Shortage and the
Formation of a "Salary Bubble"
Expenditure on purchasing inputs is conditional on past, present
and future revenues generated by the sale of output, which again is
constrained by the demand for the firm's output. If, however, the
budget constraint of many firms is soft, their demand for inputs becomes
unconstrained (or at least unconstrained from the point of view of
financing). Run-away demand will appear. These firms feel that when they
cannot pay the bills, someone else will step in and bail them out.
Therefore there is no compulsory limit on demand for inputs, and
particularly, on investment. If the share of economic units with a soft
budget constraint and a tendency to run-away demand for inputs is large
enough to have a strong effect on total demand, the system becomes a
"shortage economy." (Kornai 1986, p. 11)
In the extreme case that a club has a perfectly soft budget
constraint, (29) its own price-elasticity of demand is zero, which means
that the vertical demand curve for player talent--the crucial input into
football production--is only determined by other variables and not by
the price (Kornai, 1986, p. 9). Given that winning is desirable for club
decision-makers and talent contributes to winning, the direct
consequence of the soft budget constraint is the formation of excess
demand for player talent, provided that the supply of talent is not
sufficiently elastic.
A closer look at the technology of football production reveals that
talent supply is highly inelastic by definition. The regulatory
framework determines the squad size of the teams that confront each
other on the pitch. Unlike in many other areas of production, where one
productive worker can be substituted by two or more less productive
workers without any problem, the coach cannot take out one player and
field two or more in his place. If he wishes to field a more successful
team, the coach can only substitute players through better (not more!)
players. Under such conditions talent refers only to the relative
quality of players: "Indeed, the most important input of
all--highly talented players--is in extremely limited supply. This is so
because the very definition of talented player is inescapably
relative--simply put, such a player is one who is better than most
others" (Frank & Bernanke, 2004, p. 113).
The supply of players that are better than most others is limited
by definition. In an industry where "slot restraints"
systematically block the possibility to substitute players like Messi or
Ronaldo through entire armies of normal footballers, this limit becomes
highly relevant. Using the terminology of Frank and Bernanke (2004, p.
113), talent, as the capacity of a player to be better than most others,
is a unique and essential input that creates the ultimate supply
bottleneck in football. Just as there is only one best player in the
world at any point in time the number of x players that are better than
all other players will be x at any point in time. (30) Thus, talent
supply, properly defined in the specific context of football production,
is highly inelastic. (31)
This means that if enough clubs have soft budget constraints and a
very low price-elasticity of demand for talent as a consequence, then
talent (in the sense of players with the capacity to be better than most
others) becomes extremely scarce and its price gets bid through the
roof. Football exhibits the characteristics of a "talent shortage
economy",32 where player costs reach levels that are totally
unsustainable without systematic new money injections. In other words:
Considering the relativity of talent in football production, soft budget
constraints create a genuine salary bubble.
Managerial Moral Hazard: Too Much Risk and Too Little Care
Runaway demand for talent is only one consequence of the declining
price-responsiveness of football clubs operating with SBC.
Risk-escalation is another:
The firm can start a project even though it may have the
subconscious suspicion that the cost will be more than planned and the
revenue less. In case of financial failure it will be bailed out. Under
such circumstances there is no self-restraint in investment intentions;
the demand is not counterbalanced by a "dead-serious"
consideration of revenues and ultimately of supply. (Kornai, 1986, p.
12)
Franck and Lang (2012) have formally shown that as soon as the
option to be bailed out with a certain probability is introduced, club
decision-makers are induced to take more risk in their investment
decisions. The emergence of such moral hazard behavior is not
surprising. Studies in other areas demonstrate that managers tend to
take excessive risks if they can expect to be bailed out ex post. A
prominent example is the "too big to fail" problem in the
finance sector (e.g. Stern & Feldman, 2004).
Moreover, the absence of what Kornai (1986) called
"dead-serious" considerations of revenues and supply can
induce managerial negligence. As the continuation of operations is not
at stake, decision-makers do not invest enough of their own time and
energy into sorting out bad projects and developing good projects.
"Money coming like manna" (Kornai, 1986, p. 12) induces waste
and lavishness.
Managerial Rent-Seeking: Weak Incentives to Innovate and to Develop
the Business Instead of taking care of the production and provision of a
competitive service, managers of SBC organizations concentrate on
winning the favor of benefactors.
Allocative efficiency cannot be achieved when input-output
combinations do not adjust to price-signals. Within the firm there is no
sufficiently strong stimulus to maximum efforts; weaker performance is
tolerated. The attention of the firm's leaders is distracted from
the shop floor and from the market to the offices of the bureaucracy
where they may apply for help in case of financial trouble. (Kornai.
1986, p. 10)
If such rent-seeking behavior is systematically rewarded in SBC
organizations, their managers invest less effort and energy in
developing the business by "improving quality, cutting costs,
introducing new products or new processes" (Kornai, 1986, p.10).
Productive efforts can easily be substituted by asking the sugar daddy
to compensate for unfavorable developments. In a dynamic perspective SBC
organizations will be less innovative and their managers less
entrepreneurial.
The Systemic Effect of "Unlimited" Money Injections Into
Payrolls: Crowding Out of Incentives For "Good Management"
Obviously, those clubs that do not have soft budget constraints
find themselves victims of the salary bubble produced by the clubs with
soft budget constraints. Trying to maintain their existing level of
playing strength by keeping their share of star players would require
spending significantly more in the player market. At first sight this
could generate a strong incentive to further increase efficiency through
better management in order to remain competitive on the pitch.
However, if the margin to further increase efficiency through
better management becomes too small compared to the buying power
originating from money injections of benefactors at their competitors,
these clubs will have to accept sporting decline or have to change sides
and start gambling on success by investing more aggressively. Since
there is no doubt at all that sporting decline generates disutility for
decision-makers and fans of the club alike, the soft budget constraints
of some clubs clearly intensify the incentives for other clubs to
overspend as soon as the external money injections have reached a
magnitude that makes all reasonable efforts to increase efficiency
through better management look ridiculous. In this sense unlimited money
injections and really soft budget constraints have a tendency to crowd
out incentives for good management and to propagate throughout the
entire league. (33)
In the end, managerial moral hazard and rent-seeking tend to become
infinitely repeated games in a league where the expectation of being
bailed out has become part of collective experience. The potential arms
race mutates into a zombie race, where an entire league operates on the
verge of insolvency, chronically expending more than its earnings, but
being systematically rescued by external money injections year after
year. (34)
The Role of FFP in This Context: Hardening the Budget Constraints
of Clubs Against this background, FFP can be seen as an instrument for
moving from a state of affairs with very soft budget constraints to a
state of affairs with harder budget constraints in the football
industry. What can be said against this regulatory strategy?
To begin with, critics may counter that only genuine insolvencies
of football clubs, the Schumpeterian "creative gale of
destruction," could introduce truly hard budget constraints and
restore efficient managerial incentives in the football industry. (35)
UEFA, in contrast, embarks on a regulation that tries to avoid
insolvencies altogether by encouraging clubs to live within their means
and develop sustainable business models.
My answer would be that UEFA has gone as far as it can go with FFP
in hardening the budget constraints of football clubs. First, the
pre-FFP situation of European football cannot count at all as a
Schumpeterian world cleaned by a creative gale of destruction. Instead
it is populated by a large number of technically insolvent clubs, which
continue to operate as zombies. The pre-FFP reality is the SBC-syndrome
and not Schumpeterian capitalism. Second, UEFA is not a national
government with the competence to issue and implement insolvency
legislation in a specific country in which a certain club playing in
European competitions operates. Third, and most importantly, it does not
make sense to regulate football in order that it becomes a truly
Schumpeterian world cleaned by a creative gale of destruction.
Peculiarities like the associative character of competition in sports
and the mutual interdependence of sports clubs (Rottenberg, 1956; Neale,
1964) mean that the shutdown of a club has the potential to produce
substantial negative externalities. (36) The failure of the insolvent
club to complete the season harms the integrity of the interlinked
league competition[s]) and has negative reputational (and financial)
spillovers on uninvolved participants, unpaid financial obligations to
other clubs from player transfers may lead to contagion, etc. Because
the implementation of the Schumpeterian creative gale of destruction in
an industry where competitors are substantially interlinked through
joint production comes at the price of negative externalities, UEFA
should not pursue this regulatory strategy even if it could (which is
not the case, for the reasons given above). (37)
The presumably most important and accepted criticism against the
new regulation can be expressed as follows. In the past (before FFP) the
absorption of club losses by the owner at the end of the year was a
common measure to keep football clubs afloat. Because FFP caps the
payroll injections of benefactors, there is a general suspicion that
substantial amounts of money will simply be missing in the football
business. At first sight a downward development could be initiated
because less money could translate into "less quality on the
pitch," lower salaries, unhappier consumers, etc. (38)
However, the translation of capped payroll injections into less
money for football is far less obvious than generally assumed. A
substantial part of what has been called the absorption of losses by the
owner in the past will simply become a fair market value transaction in
the future. Quite often owners of football clubs are diversified
entities engaged in different businesses. For example, Bayer Leverkusen
AG, the German chemicals company, is the 100% owner of Bayer 04
Leverkusen Fussball GmbH, which operates the Bayer Leverkusen
professional football squad. The question to be answered is: How much
would the Bayer Leverkusen AG have to invest in PR activities per year
in order to achieve a similar level of brand awareness as produced by
the Bayer football team? The corporation Bayer could continue to absorb
losses of this level at its subsidiary club under FFP by simply
concluding a sponsorship agreement and paying the fair market value
sponsorship fee. In the past many diversified football club owners
simply did not bother to conclude formal sponsorship agreements because
they were free to inject money ex post and absorb losses in exchange for
the publicity received for their other businesses. Thus, it is not true
that all the money previously injected by owners into payrolls will be
missing in the future. Owners will simply adapt to FFP and write fair
market value sponsorship contracts in the future. However, in contrast
to the ex post absorption of losses common in the past, sponsorship
deals have to be concluded ex ante. Because managers of football clubs
have complete knowledge of the sponsorship revenues, which are a
component of relevant income, they have no reason at all to develop any
kind of soft budget constraint expectations. In other words, unlike the
traditional ex post absorption of losses, fair market value sponsorship
agreements do not create soft budget constraint expectations with all
the incentive problems associated to them.
In sum, FFP will neither lead to a situation where owner money
injections into football are impossible, as investment outside payrolls
remains entirely unregulated, nor to a situation where all former money
injections into payrolls disappear, as presumably most of them can be
executed as normal sponsorships in the future. Only payroll injections
that constitute contributions above the fair market value of a good or
serv ice exchanged between the club and the owner/related party will not
be counted under FFP. If, for example, Bayer AG would pay more to its
subsidiary club in a sponsoring agreement than a comparable amount of
exposure/image transfer costs in the free market, it would obviously
inflate relevant income, allowing the club to operate at a higher level
of relevant expenses before getting into conflict with the break-even
rule. Ceteris paribus the club would compete with higher playing
strength than otherwise identical competitors without benefactors. By
capping such inflated owner payments into payrolls above the fair market
value of exchanged goods/services, it cannot be excluded that FFP
prevents some money to flow into football in the future. (39) However,
there are several compensating effects overlooked in the literature so
far:
a. Money that would otherwise have been immediately expended on
players may be instead invested in stadia, infrastructure, community
projects, and youth academies, where budgets remain unconstrained under
FFP, thus generating sustainable relevant income for football clubs
through valuable young players, increased attendances, and new
sponsorships in the future.
b. A lot more money will be generated internally through the
football business if managers that face hard budget constraints stop
playing infinite moral hazard and rent-seeking games and simply do a
good job, concentrating on productive efforts, taking adequate risks in
their factor and product markets, etc.
c. Finally, normal investment will come (or come back) into
football, if the zombie race can be stopped and football clubs cease to
be money traps.
How Restrictive Is FFP In Normal Business Contexts, And Are Salary
Caps The Right Benchmark?
Peeters and Szymanski (2012) present an interesting paper in which
they interpret FFP as a vertical restraint. (40) Based on results from a
structural model, they argue that FFP brings downward pressure on wages
just like a US salary cap does. However, FFP fails to deliver the
compensating benefit usually claimed for a US salary cap: higher
competitive balance.
A. Why FFP Is a Very Tolerant Restriction of Competition, If At All
Can we really interpret FFP as a restriction of competition
comparable to a US salary cap? Even if it is correct that FFP brings
downward pressure to salaries in the current financial situation of
European club football, we still have to ask the following question: In
what sense does FFP restrict competition measured against a
'normal' business context?
Simply put, FFP says to owners of football clubs: "Don't
spend more on your payroll than your football revenues plus a deficit of
5m [euro] plus a maximum of 40m [euro] injectable from your own fortune
in every monitoring period!" If we would tell, for example, the
owner of a brewery or a construction company that he may spend all his
revenues plus a deficit of 5m [euro] plus 40m [euro] from his own
fortune as compensation for his employees, would this be perceived as a
restriction of competition? Does proper or genuine competition require
that businesses spend more on their payroll than their earnings plus an
acceptable deviation plus a still possible maximum amount injected by
the owner? Are all the firms and businesses in other industries that
break even or even make profits examples of restricted competition? FFP
formulates a rule that seems quite reasonable for every business out
there. Compared to US salary caps, which restrict payroll expenditures
at around 50% of league revenues, FFP seems to be a very tolerant
restriction of competition, one that would not be binding in any normal
business context. (41)
Because the football zombie race cannot be compared to a normal
business context at the moment, I fully agree with Peeters and Szymanski
(2012) that FFP will be binding for some football clubs and therefore
put downward pressure on salaries. But this is only a temporary
phenomenon. If FFP works in the direction described previously in this
paper, restoring incentives for good management in football clubs, then
new revenues will be generated, which in the end could allow the payment
of even higher salaries than in the current system.
B. Why Salary Caps Are the Wrong Benchmark
Because US salary caps define a uniform maximum level of payroll
expenditure for all teams in a league, they allegedly improve
competitive balance and increase the attractiveness of the competition.
Thus, US salary caps have a benefit, which may offset the
anti-competitive intervention in the player market. Peeters and
Szymanski (2012, p.7) are entirely right that the break-even rule does
not define a uniform maximum level of payroll expenditure for all teams
in a league. Therefore, the benefit claimed for US salary caps, more
even competition through uniform maximum payrolls, cannot be attributed
to FFP.
This diagnosis raises two questions: Should UEFA better introduce a
salary cap instead of FFP? Could it be the case that by comparing FFP
with salary caps the potential of FFP to generate more suspense in the
open European football model is not fully recognized or perhaps even
misconceived?
Due to its obvious connection to the ossification of hierarchy
critique, the second question will be treated extensively later in this
paper. Taking up the first question, it seems somewhat surprising that
so far not a single football league in Europe has voluntarily followed
the American example and voted for absolute salary caps. Assuming that
not all the stakeholders of football in all European countries can have
been simply ignorant, two alternative answers come to mind: Either
European football is based on more complex mechanisms of suspense
generation than the US leagues or competitive balance regulation via
absolute salary caps is simply not possible to implement in the European
system. A closer look reveals that both could be true. (42)
Many concepts to give meaning and add value to single games
Only in the closed-shop US leagues, staging the same teams year
after year is competitive balance in the narrow sense of "closeness
between perennial competitors" the sole concept that gives meaning
and adds value to single games. In contrast, the open European system
has many concepts that give meaning to single games. The suspense of the
championship race in every league of the entire system is supplemented
by the suspense generated by other "crucial fights" (achieving
promotion, avoiding relegation, qualifying for the UEFA Champions League
or UEFA Europa League, etc.). While in May 2013 the international world
of football was preoccupied with the German final of the UEFA Champions
League at Wembley between Bayern Munchen and Borussia Dortmund, the
German stadia and media were staging the last scenes of the drama
"Abstiegskampf," the fight against relegation, in which every
single game was deciding the fate of teams, coaches and players. No
single fan in these sold-out "games of fate" and no single TV
viewer cared at all about the closeness between the desperately fighting
underdogs and the champion Bayern Munchen.
Endogenous competitive balance through filtering needs a certain
level of imbalance as "input"
Bayern Munchen may have been stronger than other teams in the
Bundesliga's last season, but as a result it has the chance and
duty to compare with more competitive teams from the other national
European leagues like Arsenal, Manchester United, or Barcelona in the
UEFA Champions League this season. At the same time, teams like
Dusseldorf and Furth, which did not prove competitive in the first
division last season, have to play against weaker teams in the second
division this season. Sending Bayern to the Champions League and
relegating Dusseldorf and Furth to the second division makes sure that
all of them will play games against better matched competitors in the
future. Such games against competitors of comparable strength are an
endogenous result of the filtering system central to European football.
They do not have to be created by additional regulation like in the US
case. In other words, because European football is designed as a
"multi-level filtering device," it can not only deal with
competitive imbalance, it even needs a certain level of competitive
imbalance in order to perform its filtering function. The filtering
function is at the core of the European football show, offering a whole
range of crucial fights to the spectator.
League redesign would be necessary before absolute salary cap
regulation could be effective
European club competitions are played by teams that simultaneously
compete for the league championship in their extremely heterogeneous
national markets. Whereas the total revenues of the clubs competing in
the Premier League reached a level of 2.7bn [euro] in 2011, the clubs
competing in the Estonian League earned perhaps a thousandth of this
sum. If UEFA would pursue a strategy of implementing a US-style absolute
salary
cap in European club competitions in order to increase competitive
balance, what would be the right level: the level ensuring close
competition among the clubs of the Estonian national league, or the
level securing competitive balance in the Premier League? While the
level suitable for close competition in the Estonian league would
presumably drive the rest of Europe to break away from UEFA and organize
alternative competitions, the level suitable for close competition in
the Premier league would go entirely unnoticed in most of Europe and
have no effect whatsoever on the closeness of competitions in the
respective national leagues. Or should each national league, instead of
UEFA, cap salaries at a level reflecting its specific domestic revenue
potential? In this case, European competitions would take place among
teams officially capped at different salary levels reflecting different
domestic regulations. This is not only detrimental to the attraction of
European competition, but it also raises various incentive problems. For
example, if teams win prize money that they are not able to spend on
players in the future because of their domestic regulations, why should
they even participate?
The idea of absolute salary cap regulation applied to all
participating clubs presupposes either a single-league setting in a
common product market (the US model) or a series of rather homogeneous
leagues operating in different product markets but with comparable
revenue potential. Both concepts--the creation of a closed European
league of top clubs and the transformation of heterogeneous national
leagues into regional leagues of comparable market size--have been
discussed extensively in the literature (e.g., Hoehn & Szymanski,
2001), but have never been transformed into practice. As long as the
European top clubs prefer to play European competitions and national
championships simultaneously instead of entirely breaking away to form a
US-style European league, and as long as the smaller national
federations do not join efforts to create larger regional leagues,
European competitive balance regulation via absolute salary caps is not
feasible.
Quite obviously, salary caps are an American solution for an
American problem. Neither are they applicable in the open European
football model, nor are they the right benchmark for assessing the
potential of FFP to generate more suspense in the open European football
model, as is further shown later in this paper.
The Danger Of Ossification--Why Money Comes To Money Without FFP
And Why Restoring Incentives For Good Management Is Essential For
Shaking Football Hierarchies.
Since even the richest club benefactor will have to compete based
on payrolls largely financed through income generated in the football
market after the introduction of FFP, he will no longer be able to
challenge all the bigger clubs in the football hierarchy by simply
spending more money on players, despite having the personal financial
means to do so. The idea that FFP might therefore entrench the dominance
of already big clubs has become quite popular both in sports economics
(43) and in the media. (44)
Obviously, this ossification of hierarchy argument assumes that
small clubs can only or can better challenge big clubs in a system of
unlimited money injections. However, this seems unlikely for two
reasons: Firstly, there is no mechanism, which systematically allocates
payroll injections according to a pattern that makes small clubs
relatively more competitive. In reality, it is much more plausible that
a sort of inverse mechanism is at play, making sure that money comes to
money. Secondly, it becomes even more doubtful that unlimited money
injections are an instrument for shaking established football
hierarchies, once the incentives for good management are properly taken
into consideration.
A. Why Money Comes To Money Without FFP
We should recall first that FPP only caps inflated owner payments
above the fair market value of goods/services exchanged with the club. A
sponsoring agreement, where the owner pays a fair market price in
exchange for the exposure/image transfer generated by the team for his
other businesses, is in line with the regulations. In order to be
affected by FFP, the owner must obviously be willing to inject more
money into payrolls than the publicity generated through the success of
his team. Such benefactor-owners pay for success per se. In other words,
those owners that will be restrained by the new regulation in their
usual spending behavior are by definition more than just
publicity-seekers, they are genuine success-seekers. (45)
Second, it is widely accepted that the behavior of European
football clubs is best described as "win maximization subject to a
zero profit budget constraint" (Garcia del-Barro & Szymanski,
2006, p. 16). While this view has been developed and elaborated based on
theoretical models (e.g., Kesenne, 1996, 2000) first, Garcia-del-Barro
and Szymanski (2006) provided supporting empirical evidence using data
on the performance of football clubs in Spain and England. Put simply,
this objective function suggests that European football clubs tend to
spend their entire revenues in order to be as successful as possible on
the pitch. Moreover, it suggests that the clubs will welcome and invest
in additional wins every other increase in spending power originating
from external sources.
Which is the likely result of a matching process between
success-seeking benefactors and win-maximizing clubs? In league
competition, favorites (clubs with big market potential) will not wish
to lose against "supported underdogs" (clubs from smaller
markets but with benefactor payroll injections). Therefore, they will
increasingly adapt their governance structures and open their doors to
benefactors. Since success-seeking benefactors by definition will try to
spend their money where winning probabilities are highest and
win-maximizing clubs by definition prefer the largest payroll-injection,
in the end the benefactors with the deepest pockets get allocated to the
clubs with the largest market potential (the favorites), making them
even more dominant. Therefore, in equilibrium unlimited payroll
injections very likely contribute to the ossification of the football
hierarchy. (46)
Against this background, FFP reduces the gap between favorites and
underdogs by forcing all clubs to operate within their market potential
instead of allowing favorites to boost their salaries with the largest
subventions given to them by the richest benefactors chasing after
sportive success. Compared to a US salary cap FFP may not define a
uniform payroll ceiling for all clubs, but it contributes to more
intense competition by breaking the money comes to money equilibrium,
where in the end the deepest pockets would get attached to the clubs
with the largest market potential.
B. Why Restoring Incentives for Good Management is Essential for
Shaking Football Hierarchies
Moreover, by breaking the described money comes to money dynamics,
FFP brings the football hierarchy closer together again. As a
consequence the relative importance of good management for sporting
success increases. A well-managed medium sized club, like Borussia
Dortmund, can seriously hope to at least temporarily outperform a big
market club, like Bayern Munchen, whenever the latter is poorly managed
and/or unlucky. There would be less hope for Dortmund to beat Bayern
based on better management if the usual advantage of a bigger market for
Bayern would be systematically amplified through the additional
advantage of a bigger benefactor for
Bayern.
By preventing the deepest pockets from inflating the payrolls of
the clubs already situated in the largest markets, FFP revitalizes the
importance of management quality as an avenue for achieving sporting
success. European football will profit from the contest in management
quality. This contest will strengthen a source of variance in the
football hierarchy, which has been at least partially buried in the
times and leagues where pleasing benefactors came first.
Conclusion
Analyses of regulation that do not look at how regulation affects
managerial decision-making miss the main point of regulation. Who would,
for example, look at banking regulation without considering its effects
on the incentives of bank managers to engage in moral hazard and
rent-seeking? This is what banking regulation is all about. The same
standard should be applied when analyzing the likely effects of football
regulation.
This paper has tried to analyze how managers and decision-makers in
football clubs will presumably react to the harder budget constraints
introduced through FFP. The critics of FFP focus on the "missing
money" from capped benefactor injections into payrolls and predict
a downturn and an ossification of the football industry. But can we
seriously forecast the level of future player salaries and the intensity
of competition without considering the effects of changed managerial
incentives? I do not think so.
After the introduction of FFP, managers will have to run clubs
based on budgets that stay within the hard limit drawn by their football
income and the acceptable deviation defined in the FFP regulations. By
introducing hard budget constraints, FFP restores the incentives for
"good management" in an industry that has degenerated to a
zombie race with an ever-increasing number of technically bankrupt
participants, which rely on getting rescued by state subventions and/or
private money injections year after year. While it is not even a
declared objective of FFP to increase competitive balance, it is
nevertheless the case that FFP prevents further entrenchment in the
football industry. In other words, FFP not only protects systemic
financial stability but it does so with a positive side effect for the
preservation of suspense in the open European football system.
References
Andreff, W. (2007). French football: A financial crisis rooted in
weak governance. Journal of Sports Economics, 8, 652-61.
Andreff, W. (2011). Some comparative economics of the organization
of sports: Competition and regulation in North American vs. European
professional team sports leagues. The European Journal of Comparative
Economics, 8, 3-27.
Baroncelli, A., & Lago, U. (2006). Italian football. Journal of
Sports Economics, 7, 13-28.
Bairner, R. (2012). How PSG's 200m [euro] spending spree
compares to Abramovich's Chelsea & Abu Dhabi's Manchester
City. Retrieved from
http://www.goal.com/en/news/1717/editorial/2012/07/19/3248341/how-psgs-200m- spending-spree-compares-to-abramovichs- chelsea-abu
Budzinski, O. (2012). The institutional framework for doing sports
business: principles of EU competition policy in sports markets.
International Journal of Sport Management and Marketing, 11, 44-72.
Budzinski, O., & Muller, A. (2013). Finanzregulierung und
international Wettbewerbsfahigkeit: der Fall Deutsche Bundesliga.
[Financial regulation and international competitiveness: the case of
German Bundesliga.] (Diskussionspapier No. 82.) Illmenau University of
Technology.
Dascal, O. (2013, March 29). Financial fair play--UEFA should
seriously consider an alternative to FFP. SOCCERISSUE. Retrieved from
http://www.soccerissue.com/2013/03/29/uefashould-seriously-consider-an-alternative- to-ffp/
Drut, B., & Raballand, G. (2012). Why does financial regulation
matter for European professional football clubs? International Journal
of Sport Management and Marketing, 11, 73-88.
Conn, D. (2012a), Chelsea wanted to break even but they are
breaking the bank first. Retrieved from
http://www.guardian.co.uk/football/david-conn-inside-sport-blog/2012/aug/31/ chelsea-breaking-bank-transfer-deadline#history-link-box
Conn, D. (2012b). Manchester City: a tale of love and money.
Retrieved from http://www.guardian.co.uk/football/2012/may/18/fall-and-rise-manchester-city
Dewatripont, M., & Maskin, E. (1995). Credit and efficiency in
centralized and decentralized economies. The Review of Economic Studies,
62, 541-555.
Dewatripont, M., Maskin, E., & Roland, G. (2000). Soft budget
constraints and transition. In E. Maskin & A. Simonovits (Eds.),
Planning, shortage and transformation (essays in honor of Janos Kornai)
(pp. 143-156). MIT Press.
Dietl, H., Franck, E., & Lang, M. (2008). Overinvestment in
team sports leagues: A contest theory model. Scottish Journal of
Political Economy, 55, 353-368.
Franck, E. (2010). Private firm, public corporation or
member's association-Governance structures in European football.
International Journal of Sport Finance, 5, 108-127.
Franck, E., & Lang, M. (2012). Theoretical analysis of the
influence of money injections on risk taking in football clubs. Scottish
Journal of Political Economy. Paper submitted for publication. Retrieved
from http://econpapers.repec.org/Zpaper/isowpaper/0160.htm
Franck, E., & Muller, J.C. (2000). Problemstruktur,
Eskalationsvoraussetzungen und Eskalationsfordernde Bedingungen
sogenannter Rattenrennen. [Problem structure, escalation prerequisites
and escalation promoting conditions of the so-called rat race].
Zeitschrift fur betriebswirtschaftliche Forschung, 52, 3-26.
Frank, R.H., & Bernanke, B.S. (2004). Principles of
microeconomics. (2nd ed.). McGraw-Hill.
Garcia-del-Barro, P., & Szymanski, S. (2009). Goal! Profit
maximization versus win maximization in soccer. Review of Industrial
Organization, 34, 45-68.
Hoehn, T., & Szymanski, S. (2001). The Americanization of
European football. Economic Policy, 14, 203-240.
Iaria, M. (2012). How to spend 2.5 billion [euro] and be happy and
dissatisfied. Retrieved from
http://english.gazzetta.it/Football/15-10-2012/how-to-spend-e25-billion-and-be-happyand-dissatisfied-912915713057.shtml
Kesenne, S. (1996). League management in professional team sports
with win maximizing clubs. European Journal for Sport Management, 2,
14-22.
Kesenne, S. (2000). Revenue sharing and competitive balance in
professional team sports. Journal of Sports Economics, 1, 56-65.
Kornai, J. (1980a). Economics of shortage. Amsterdam:
North-Holland.
Kornai, J. (1980b). Hard and soft budget constraint. Acta
Oeconomica, 25, 231-245.
Kornai, J. (1986). The soft budget constraint. Kyklos, 39, 3-30.
Kornai, J., Maskin, E., & Roland, G. (2003). Understanding the
soft budget constraint. Journal of Economic Literature, 41, 1095-1136.
Kuper, S. (2009). Football abandons the fantasy that it is a
business. Retrieved from
http://www.ft.com/intl/cms/s/2/fd77a01c-aa07-11de-a3ce00144feabdc0.html#axzz2GRMm CmGD
Kuper, S., & Szymanski, S. (2009). Soccernomics: Why England
loses, why Germany and Brazil win, and why the US, Japan, Australia,
Turkey-and even Iraq-are destined to become the kings of the
world's most popular sport. New York, NY: Nation Books.
Lago, U., Simmons, R., & Szymanski, S. (2006). The financial
crisis in European football: An introduction. Journal of Sports
Economics, 7, 3-12.
Lazear, E., Rosen, S. (1981). Rank-order tournaments as optimum
labor contracts. Journal of Political Economy, 89, 841-864.
Madden, P. (2011). Welfare economics of "financial fair
play" in a sports league with benefactor owners. Journal of Sports
Economics. Paper submitted for publication.
Muller, J. C., Lammert, J., & Hovemann, G. (2012). The
financial fair play regulations of UEFA: An adequate concept to ensure
the long-term viability and sustainability of European club football?
International Journal of Sports Finance, 7, 117-140.
Nalebuff, B., & Stiglitz, J. E. (1983). Prizes and incentives:
Towards a general theory of compensation and competition. The Bell
Journal of Economics, 14, 21-43.
Neale, W. C. (1964). The peculiar economics of professional sports,
The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 78, 1-14.
Maskin, E. (1996). Theories of the soft budget-constraint. Japan
& the World Economy, 8, 125133.
Pawlowski, T. (2013). Testing the uncertainty of outcome hypothesis
in European professional football: A stated preference approach. Journal
of Sports Economics. Paper submitted for publication. doi:
10.1177/1527002513496011.
Peeters, T., Szymanski, S. (2012). Vertical restraints in soccer:
Financial fair play and the English Premier League. (Working Paper).
University of Antwerp.
Rottenberg, S. (1956). The baseball player's labor market.
Journal of Political Economy, 64, 242258.
Sass, M. (2012). Long-term competitive balance under UEFA financial
fair play regulations. (Working Paper No. 5/2012). Otto von Guericke
University of Magdeburg.
Stern, G. H., & Feldman, R. J. (2004). Too big to fail: The
hazards of bank bailouts. Washington, DC: Brookings Institution Press.
Storm, R. K. (2012). The need for regulating professional soccer in
Europe: A soft budget constraint argument. Sport, Business and
Management: An International Journal, 2, 21-38.
Storm, R. K., & Nielsen, K. (2012). Soft budget constraints in
professional football. European Sport Management Quarterly, 12, 183-201.
Szymanski, S. (2009, August 12). The moral hazard of
football's net gains. The Times.
Szymanski, S. (2010). The financial crisis and English football:
The dog that will not bark. International Journal of Sport Finance, 5,
28-40.
Thompson, E. (2013, June 20). Further legal challenge to FFP by
Striani and Dupont. Financial Fair Play-Latest News. Retrieved from
http://www.financialfairplay.co.uk/latest-news/further-legal-challenge-to-ffp-by- striani-and-dupont
Tullock, G. (1980). Efficient rent-seeking. In J. Buchanan, R.
Tollison, & G. Tullock, (Eds.), Toward a theory of the rent-seeking
society (pp. 97-112). College Station, TX: Texas A&M University
Press.
UEFA (2012). UEFA Club Licensing and Financial Fair Play
Regulations, Edition 2012. Retrieved from
http://www.uefa.com/MultimediaFiles/Download/Tech/uefaorg/General/
01/80/54/10/1805410_D0WNL0AD.pdf
UEFA (2013). The European Club Licensing Benchmarking Report
Financial Year 2011. Retrieved from
http://www.uefa.com/MultimediaFiles/Download/Tech/uefaorg/General/
01/91/61/84/1916184_DOWNLOAD.pdf
Van Rompuy, B. (2012). Plan to relieve the Spanish football club
tax debts. Retrieved from
http://footballperspectives.org/plan-relieve-spanish-football-club-tax-debts
Vopel, H. (2011). Do we really need financial fair play in European
club football? An Economic Analysis, CESIfo DICE Report.
Egon Franck
University of Zurich
Endnotes
(1) See UEFA (2013) for the following numbers and very detailed
additional information.
(2) Article 58 (2) clarifies the notion of relevant expenses as
follows: "Relevant expenses is defined as cost of sales, employee
benefits expenses and other operating expenses, plus either amortisation
or costs of acquiring player registrations, finance costs and dividends.
It does not include depreciation/impairment of tangible fixed assets,
amortisation/impairment of intangible fixed assets (other than player
registrations), expenditure on youth development activities, expenditure
on community development activities, any other non-monetary items,
finance costs directly attributable to the construction of tangible
fixed assets, tax expenses or certain expenses from non-football
operations"
(3) Article 58 (1) clarifies the notion of relevant income as
follows: "Relevant income is defined as revenue from gate receipts,
broadcasting rights, sponsorship and advertising, commercial activities
and other operating income, plus either profit on disposal of player
registrations or income from disposal of player registrations, excess
proceeds on disposal of tangible fixed assets and finance income. It
does not include any non-monetary items or certain income from
non-football operations"
(4) The "monitoring period" assessed for the license
season 2013/14 covers the reporting period ending 2013 and the reporting
period ending 2012. From then onwards the three previous reporting
periods will be assessed for every new license season. For example, in
the 2014/15 license season the assessment will be performed based on the
three reporting periods ending 2014, 2013, and 2012.
(5) The notion of "acceptable deviation" is defined in
Article 61.
(6) Article 61(2) of the FFP regulations (UEFA 2012) explains that
the total acceptable deviation is fixed at 30 m [euro] for the
monitoring period assessed in the license seasons 2015/16, 2016/17 and
2017/18. A lower amount to be decided in due course by the UEFA
Executive Committee will be binding for the monitoring periods assessed
in later years.
(7) In this article the likely effects of FFP are discussed without
raising the difficult question of enforcement. I am well aware of the
fact that many commentators are also criticizing FFP on the grounds that
UEFA will not be successful in preventing circumvention of the
break-even requirement, pointing to the possibilities arising for
example from inflated sponsorship deals, third party ownership of
players etc. It seems reasonable to assess this open question after the
first experiences with the application of the break-even requirement in
2014.
(8) Madden (2011) has presented an article where he shows, based on
a theoretical model, that the prohibition of money injections has
negative welfare consequences for the league, because of its adverse
effects on team qualities.
(9) See Tullock (1980), Lazear and Rosen (1981) or Nalebuff and
Stiglitz (1983) for first approaches in contest theory.
(10) See for example Franck and Muller (2000), Dietl, Franck, and
Lang (2008) and Muller, Lammert, and Hovemann (2012) for the analysis of
overinvestment phenomena in sports leagues.
(11) See Dietl, Franck, and Lang (2008) for these results and their
theoretical derivation.
(12) As mentioned in the introduction the percentage of clubs with
negative net equity facing a situation with debts larger than reported
assets is 38% (see UEFA 2013).
(13) For example, as of January 2013, Deportivo La Coruna became
the eighth club in the Spanish first division to file for bankruptcy
protection.
(14) See for example Szymanski (2010), Kuper (2009), Kuper and
Szymanski (2009), Baroncelli and Lago (2006), Lago, Simmons, and
Szymanski (2006).
(15) Budzinski and Muller (2012) also deal with--among many other
things--the issue of repeated bailouts in their paper about financial
regulation and international competitiveness seen from the perspective
of the German Bundesliga.
(16) In Kornai's classical treatments (Kornai 1980a, 1986) the
post-socialist transition created specific conditions that nurtured the
emergence of a SBC mentality.
(17) See Kornai, Masin, and Roland (2003, p. 7) for more details.
(18) For excellent overviews see Kornai, Maskin, and Roland (2003),
Maskin (1996), Dewatripont, Maskin, and Roland (2000), etc.
(19) See Kornai (1986, p. 5-6) for a more detailed account of the
possible measures of state intervention.
(20) There is some uncertainty concerning the correct numbers. As
far as I can see the "lower bound" has been announced by the
Spanish State Secretariat for Sport in February 2014. According to this
announcement the aggregate tax and social security debts of clubs at the
end of the 2012/13 season amounted to "only" 750m [euro].
(21) See Van Rompuy (2012) for this and for all the following
details of the Spanish situation.
(22) 1 am still following Van Rompuy (2012) for all details.
(23) In addition to these rather general motives highlighting
different aspects of state commitment difficulties, Kornai, Maskin, and
Roland (2003, p. 9-10) also explore more specific motives for bailouts,
which cannot be ruled out categorically but might apply in single cases.
They range from "crony" relationships based on bribery or
political pressure to reputational and paternalistic concerns in
situations where the club is perceived as a "lower-level unit"
of the same "organization". For example, if the club is
operated to a large extent by the city or the region, as is still the
case in many post-socialist settings, state officials may both feel
responsible for it and at the same time fear to lose public standing in
case of a club collapse.
(24) See Kornai, Maskin, and Roland (2003, p. 8) for this argument
presented in a general context.
(25) A famous model by Dewatripont and Maskin (1995) elaborates
this idea that "softness" develops out of investing in order
to save past investment.
(26) The story told below follows quite closely the logic of the
"too big to fail" problem in banking, which has been explained
to me by my colleague Urs Birchler in his inaugural lecture at the
University of Zurich.
(27) However, even in the Bundesliga there are historical
exceptions from this regulation, namely Bayer Leverkusen and VfL
Wolfsburg, who have always been sub-organizations of the corporations
Bayer and Volkswagen.
(28) See Franck (2010) for an in-depth treatment of this issue.
(29) Bairner (2012) compared the spending of Chelsea, Manchester
City, and Paris Saint-Germain in the first 14 months after the
respective new owner took control. The numbers (283,6m [euro] for Roman
Abramovich, 234,3m [euro] for Sheikh Mansour and 212,6m [euro] for the
Qatar Investment Authority) are indicative of a perfectly soft budget
constraint.
(30) Here we abstract from the fact that some talent indicators are
exclusively observable for the current team, which may give rise to
problems of asymmetric information. Moreover, the impact of a player on
team performance could differ with the team as a consequence of joint
production. Thus, a player can be more valuable for one team than for
another team. Despite some uncertainty added through these factors,
players like Ronaldo, Messi, or Ribery (nominees for the Ballon
d'Or 2013) have obviously disclosed their superior abilities to
many observers of their weekly performances on the pitch and would be
considered as "high contributors" in most clubs.
(31) I don't dare to use the term "perfectly
inelastic" for the following reason: For the sake of simplicity
let's only call the five best players of the world talented. Assume
the five best players of the world are A, B, C, D, and E. If salaries in
the entire world football industry go up by 10% overnight, these players
remain the same and the number of the five best players of the world
remains five. No new talent in the sense of the five best players of the
world enters the market. However, the interpretation changes if we
segment the football industry along national borders. Assume that
salaries only go up by 10% in England. Assume that so far only two of
the five best players of the world played for English clubs (A and C).
As a result of the salary increase in England one more player from this
group moves from Spain to England (B). Seen from the perspective of the
English League (which now has three of the five best players of the
world, A, B, and C) supply of talent is elastic despite the fact that
the five best players of the world are still five and even the same
five. Paul Madden and Brian Quinn have attracted my attention to this
simple and important truth. However, since we analyze a regulation
addressing clubs that par ticipate in European competitions, the
adequate "jurisdiction" seems to be Europe for me. If regular
Champions League competitors like Barcelona, Madrid, Chelsea,
Manchester, etc. bid for the five best players of the world, new talent
only enters the market if one of the five best players in the world
doesn't already play in Europe and if a European club succeeds in
hiring him. Occasionally it can be the case that a player comes as a
"top star" to Europe, like recently Neymar. Therefore, I think
that it is safe to say that talent supply is not perfectly but highly
inelastic seen from the "jurisdiction" of the European
competitions addressed by FFP.
(32) It is irrelevant that "less talented" or
"untalented" players might offer their services in the market
"for nothing". Demand concentrates on the inelastic number of
"star players" at any point in time.
(33) As my colleague and friend Umberto Lago expressed in direct
communication with me: "If you do not regulate the industry it does
not mean that you can have different management models competing for
success, because "pleasing the sugar daddy," like weed, kills
(or makes life too difficult for) competing management models."
(34) One might argue that this state of affairs has already been
reached in the entire European football industry, given that 63% of the
European top-division clubs report operational losses and 38% of these
clubs face a situation with debts larger than reported assets in the
financial year 2011 (see UEFA (2013), p. 15, 101). However, there are
significant national differences regarding the aggregated annual profits
and losses and debt levels of first division clubs, as Drut and
Raballand (2012) show in their paper. They explain these differences as
a reflection of more or less tight national systems of financial
regulation in football. German and French first division clubs have been
less prone to fall into the spiral of overspending because--to use the
terminology of this paper--their regulators imposed much harder budget
constraints on them. According to Drut and Raballand (2012), they have
paid the price of a sporting disadvantage.
(35) If I recall the details correctly, it was Stefan Szymanski who
confronted me with this argument at a roundtable discussion in
Barcelona.
(36) See for example Muller, Lammert, and Hovemann (2012), p.
121-122, Budzinski and Muller (2013), p. 12-13, Lago, Simmons, and
Szymanski (2006).
(37) See also Budzinski and Muller (2013), p. 12-13, for a critical
discussion of "adequate" regulation in situations where
insolvencies lead to negative externalities.
(38) Such downward development is modeled by Madden (2011):
Provided that talent supply is sufficiently elastic, "less
money" translates into lower team qualities, unhappier consumers,
etc. In the end everybody is worse off.
(39) Let's bear in mind that even such "inflated"
owner payments into payrolls are still allowed up to a level of 45m
[euro] in the current monitoring period.
(40) Although the qualification of FFP as a vertical restraint is
very doubtful, I will not take up thisdiscussion here. Budzinski (2012)
gives an in-depth analysis of the framework employed by the European
Commission to classify competitive interventions of sports governing
bodies as horizontal or vertical restraints. It seems to me that the
framework, which has been, for example, employed in the broadcasting
rights cases, can easily be applied to FFP with quite similar results.
(41) UEFA's regulatory interventions are of course always
limited by the threat that clubs vote for exit and create an alternative
American style "European Super-Soccer League." However, it
seems very unlikely that FFP should initiate this kind of movement.
Those owners who want to break away because they cannot inject more than
45m [euro] from their private fortune into payrollsin the monitoring
period have no reason at all to dream of some sort of European soccer
NFL. For good economic reasons, which are explained below (securing
competitive balance as the sole concept that gives meaning to games),
all existing US closed shop leagues operate with much more restrictive
payroll regulations.
(42) I am aware of the existence of very elaborate competitive
balance discussion in the field of sports economics (see Pawlowski
(2013) for a recent state-of-the-art treatment). It is not my intention
at all to embark on this discussion. The point of departure for me is
the widespread expectation that UEFA FFP "should do something"
about competitive balance (see e.g. Vopel 2011).
(43) See e.g., Sass (2012), Vopel (2011, 2013).
(44) See e.g., Thompson (2013), Daskal (2013).
(45) Apparently, it is possible to construct various rational
explanations for genuine success-seeking. At a very basic level, it
suffices to assume the existence of wealthy individuals with a
preference for success in international football. If we imagine a very
rich man dreaming to win the Champions League with his football club
more than anything else, willingness to buy success on the pitch follows
by assumption.
(46) Obviously, not all doors at European football clubs have been
opened for benefactor-owners so far. Some well-run "big market
clubs" have presumably not yet felt intense enough competition from
sugar daddy supported clubs. In the meanwhile benefactors have walked
through the "first open doors" at the "biggest
clubs" available for them on the market for corporate control.
Clearly, competitive pressures have increased for clubs like Madrid,
ManU, Barcelona, Arsenal and Bayern that so far do not rely on the
support of sugar daddy owners. However, the supporters of unrestrained
payroll injections should recognize that this is only a transitory stage
before all doors of the European "big market clubs" will
become wide-open to benefactors. Success-seeking benefactors will be
happy to walk through the doors in Madrid, Barcelona, Munich, etc., once
they are open to them. And why should Madrid, Barcelona, Munich, etc.
not open their doors for benefactors and instead accept to constantly
loose against clubs that from their perspective are "supported
underdogs"? The failure of FFP would certainly accelerate this
transition towards "open doors for benefactors." After the
transition the deepest pockets will back the clubs from the
"biggest markets," entrenching their dominance.
Egon Franck is a professor of strategic management and business
policy in the Department of Business Administration. His current
research interests focus on the strategies and governance structures of
sport organizations.
Author's Note
I was surprised by the wave of feedback that I received in a few
weeks over the summer 2013 in response to the first draft of this paper.
I would like to thank Wladimir Andreff, Brian Quinn, Umberto Lago, Paul
Madden, Tim Pawlowski, Raphael Flepp, Markus Lang, Jan Pieper and Marc
Brechot for their valued input. Jaume Garcia Villar invited me to
Barcelona, where I had the opportunity to discuss the main arguments of
this paper with Stefan Szymanski and Placido Rodriguez Guerrero at a
roundtable organized under the auspices of the Fundacio Ernest Lluch.
Petros Mavroidis and Miguel Poiares Maduro invited me to the European
University Institute in Florence, where I had the chance to discuss some
of the ideas presented in this paper in the context of the High-Level
Policy Seminar "The Governance of European Football: Looking
backwards, Looking forward." The European Sport Economics
Association (ESEA) invited me to the annual meeting 2013 in Esbjerg,
where I had the honor to present this paper as keynote lecture. Paul
Madden invited me to present my thoughts in the Special Session
"The Economics of "Financial Fair Play" (FFP) in European
Soccer" at the Annual Conference of The Royal Economic Society in
Manchester 2014. I wish to thank the organizers and participants of
these important events, knowing very well that not all of them share all
my interpretations of Financial Fair Play.