An examination of the effects of the recent economic crisis on Major League Baseball attendance demand.
Hong, Sungil ; Mondello, Michael ; Coates, Dennis 等
An Examination of the Effects of the Recent Economic Crisis on
Major League Baseball Attendance Demand
Major League Baseball (MLB) attendance in 2009 was about 6.77%
below what it was in 2008 (30,338 per game for 2009 compared to 32,543
for 2008) (Brown, 2009), and 2008 was down slightly compared to 2007.
The drop between 2008 and 2009 was the largest single-season loss in
attendance since 1952, excluding years involving a work stoppage
(Nightengale, 2009). More specifically, 22 of the 30 clubs experienced a
decline in attendance, including four teams' attendance decreasing
more than 20%. The Florida Marlins, Kansas City Royals, and Texas
Rangers were the only teams able to boast 10% or greater increases in
attendance (Brown, 2009).
The surprisingly large drop in attendance may be attributable to
the recent economic crisis, the beginning of which was set at December
2007 by the National Bureau of Economic Research. In fact, MLB announced
that "because of the economy, this year's (2009) total is 6.6
percent less than last year's total, but is actually only 5.2
percent lower when accounting for the reduced capacities of the two new
ballparks in New York" (MLB.com, 2009, n. p.). It is certainly a
possibility that the state of the economy in 2009 led to reduced
attendance. Widespread unemployment and reduced incomes mean tighter
budget constraints causing consumers to alter their spending patterns.
Consumers may reduce the quantity of sporting events attended in
response to the economic crisis both because their financial status is
precarious and for psychological reasons. The psychological impact of
the crisis may lead to a decrease in expenditures regardless of the
consumers' actual financial status (Katona, 1974). This first
contribution of this paper is that it empirically assesses the impact of
the recent economic crisis on the largest single-season drop in
attendance in MLB history between the 2008 and 2009 seasons. The key
problem in this study is how best to represent the economic conditions
in our analysis. The ideal economic indicators would vary daily and by
city, but such data do not exist. The second contribution of this paper
is to utilize "coincident indicators," produced by the Federal
Reserve Bank of Philadelphia, reflecting the macroeconomic health of a
given state in each month. These indicators reflect an improvement over
the literature in which income per capita for a specific year is used to
capture the role of consumer income in the determination of ticket
demand.
The first section of the paper discusses what economic indicators
should be used and why they are useful in measuring the effects of the
recent economic crisis on MLB attendance demand. In the second section,
the attendance demand model is presented along with descriptions of
other explanatory variables. Finally, the last section discusses the
empirical results, conclusions, and recommendations for future research.
Economic indicators
The Great Depression inspired economists to search for ways to
detect or predict economic cycles (Conference Board, 2001). As an
initial effort of gauging economic cycles, Arthur Burns and Wesley
Mitchell of the National Bureau of Economic Research (NBER) developed a
list of leading, coincident, and lagging indicators of economic activity
in the United States as part of the NBER research program on business
cycles (Stock & Watson, 1989).
Of the leading, lagging, or coincident indicators, the most useful
for the study of baseball attendance is the index of coincident
indicators. More specifically, the composite index of coincident
indicators is designed to measure current economic conditions; that is,
the coincident indicators provide a description of the actual
circumstances that consumers face at a point in time. Of these three
composite indexes of economic indicators, Crone (1994) claimed the
composite index of coincident indicators is the most important index for
dating business cycles. He stated that 18 of 22 business-cycle turning
points in the U.S. economy over a period of 45 years closely
corresponded with the index of coincident indicators, indicating an
excellent benchmark for assessing the current pace of economic activity
(Yamarone, 2004). Therefore, the composite index of coincident
indicators is the best of the business cycle indicators to use as a
determinant of attendance demand.
Composite index of coincident indicators
Two different coincident indexes have been released by the U.S.
Department of Commerce and some regional U.S. Federal Reserve Banks. The
index released by the Commerce Department (now published by the
Conference Board) consists of four monthly data series--1) the number of
jobs in nonagricultural establishments, 2) personal incomes, less
transfer payments, adjusted for inflation, 3) the index of industrial
production, and 4) manufacturing and trade sales adjusted for inflation
(Crone, 1994). The Commerce Department's index is calculated based
on month-to-month percent changes for each of these four series. The
changes are standardized based on the long-run average absolute monthly
change in the series; "this preliminary index is adjusted to grow
over time at the same rate as real gross national product and is set to
100 in 1982" (Crone, 1994, p. 21). However, there is a primary
issue about the methods used by the Commerce Department--the index is
not derived from a formal mathematic or statistical model (Stock &
Watson, 1989). More specifically, the same weight is assigned to each
indicator in forming the composite index. It is unlikely that each
indicator equally reflects the overall state of the economy (Crone,
1994).
In contrast with the traditional Commerce Department methodology,
several procedures have been proposed to aid in the dating of recessions
and expansions by using techniques based on econometric and time series
analysis (Crone, 1994). Stock and Watson (1991) developed a
probabilistic state space model based on time-series econometric
techniques to estimate a latent process; this estimation is used as a
coincident indicator of the economic activity. Their approach was based
on the common movements across several economic data series best
measuring the business cycles. Unlike the Commerce Department
methodology, their methodology assigned the different weights determined
by the degree of common movement in the indicators (Crone, 1994).
The Stock and Watson national index used the same data series as
the Department of Commerce except for the number of nonagricultural
jobs. Employee hours in nonagricultural jobs were used since economic
output depends not only on how long they work but also on how many
people are working (Crone, 1994). Their national index tracks the
official business cycles closer than the method used by the Department
of Commerce. However, the Stock and Watson index is not available at the
state level and is, therefore, a poor means for measuring the regional
economy (Crone & Clayton-Matthews, 2005). Accordingly, Crone and his
colleagues of the Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia developed a new
coincident index for each of the 50 states in order to describe recent
economic trends at the state level.
The coincident indexes for the 50 states comprise four state-level
indicators to summarize current economic conditions in a single
statistic. The four state-level variables in each coincident index are
1) nonagricultural payroll employment, 2) unemployment rate, 3) average
hours worked in manufacturing, and 4) real wage and salary disbursements
(Crone & Clayton-Matthews, 2005). Nonagricultural payroll employment
is intended to reflect actual changes in hiring and firing for the
individual states by month. This is considered the most reliable
employment series published for all the states.
The unemployment rate produced by the Bureau of Labor Statistics
utilizes the current population survey, the payroll employment survey,
state population estimates, and unemployment claims. While Stock and
Watson's national index and the Conference Board's index
include industrial production, the coincident index for the 50 states
uses average hours worked in manufacturing in its place due to the
unavailability of a comparable measure of industrial output at the state
level (Crone & Clayton-Matthew, 2005). Finally, while the Bureau of
Economic Analysis releases personal income and its components at the
state level on a quarterly basis, the major component of personal
income, real wage and salary disbursements, is included in the state
index. The quarterly wage and salary disbursements produced by the BEA
are adjusted by lagging the structure in the measurement equation for
this variable to obtain the monthly data (Crone & Clayton-Matthew,
2005).
Usefulness of the composite index of coincident indicators for the
50 states
Consumer income is a determinant of demand and is commonly
accounted for in the literature on attendance demand by income per
capita measured at the metropolitan level. One problem with income per
capita at the metropolitan level is that it is an annually reported
variable so that it will not vary over the seasons. Moreover, as a
measure of the financial situation of fans, income also may be lacking
as it is only one of many alternative factors reflecting those
circumstances. However, the use of a single economic indicator may lead
to a different estimation of economic conditions because the indicators
do not move together perfectly. Indeed, individual indicators may
provide contradictory evidence on economic conditions (Crone, 1994).
In the literature, income is often found not to be a significant
determinant of attendance, possibly because of the lack of variation
over the league's season or because it is not a good measure of the
purchasing power and economic circumstances of the fans (e.g.,
Alexander, 2001; Coates & Harrison, 2005; Coates & Humphreys,
2005, 2007; Coffin, 1996; Garcia & Rodriguez, 2002; Lemke, Leonard,
& Tlhokwane, 2010; McEvoy, Nagel, DeSchriver, & Brown, 2005;
Meehan, Nelson, & Richardson, 2007; Morse, Shapiro, McEvoy, &
Rascher, 2008). As alternative measures, several attendance demand
studies used consumption spending (Bird, 1982) and the unemployment rate
(Dobson & Goddard, 1985; Jennett, 1984; Leadley & Zygmont,
2005), resulting in mixed results.
The coincident indexes have an advantage over income per capita and
other alternative approaches because they vary by month within the
season and they combine information from several indicators so they can
better reflect the current economic conditions. One limitation of the
coincident indexes is they cover an entire state rather than a
metropolitan area. Consequently, if the economic circumstances of the
city from which a team draws its fans do not correspond well to the
circumstances of the entire state, then the coincident indicator may be
a poor variable to capture the influence of income on demand.
In spite of the usefulness of the composite index of coincident
indicators, little empirical research on consumer demand has utilized
this index as an alternative measure of economic conditions. There are
several tourism studies that have used leading indicators, which are
widely used to judge or predict the future state of the economy, as
explanatory variables in order to forecast tourism demand (e.g., Cho,
2001; Turner, Kulendran, & Fernado, 1997; Wander & Erden, 1979).
However, we have found no demand studies that use coincident indicators
for this purpose. Thus, we believe this study is a first attempt at
adopting the coincident index for the investigation of consumer demand.
The Attendance Model
Attendance demand, like all demand, has well-known theoretical
determinants. Among these determinants are income of the consumers,
prices of tickets and of other goods and services, and preferences. The
difficulty in estimating the demand equation is how to control for these
theoretically relevant factors with the existing data. For example, it
is difficult to control for preferences because there is no clearly
defined or observable way to measure them. Additionally, in the case of
sports attendance, ticket sales data are aggregated to the game or
season level for a sport club, rather than linked to individual
consumers. Consequently, aggregate rather than individual variables are
used to proxy for correlates of individual characteristics that are
themselves only proxies for tastes and preferences. In the context of
individual game attendance, none of these aggregate variables will vary
meaningfully and are not collected with sufficient frequency even if
they did. Additionally, in the sports context, fan loyalty is important,
and while it likely varies from season to season, its variability from
game to game within the season is likely to be small. For these reasons,
city or team fixed effects are used to capture the influence of these
game-to-game time-invariant factors. Consequently, our regression model
incorporates the current economic condition indicator as well as the
most widely used demand determinants as follows:
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]
where i indicates team, j indexes games, and t indexes the season,
[beta]s are parameters to be estimated, [delta] represents the fixed
effect parameter for each team, and [mu] is the error term. The
variables used in the analysis are described below.
Data
Data were collected for every regular season game for the 29 MLB
teams based in the United States. The composite index of coincident
indicators is not available for the Toronto Blue Jays. The sample
contains 4,696 games during the two seasons, but two of these are
dropped because they were played in Japan. Multiple resources were used
to collect the data such as Baseball-Reference.com, ESPN.com, and the
Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia's website. Descriptive
statistics for the variables used in the regression equation are
presented in Table 1. Home attendance as a percentage of stadium
capacity was 71.33% on average, with a standard deviation of 22.44. The
mean of the coincident index for the states where the teams are located
was 159.36 with a standard deviation of 17.99. The index declines over
the sample period for all of the states, though to varying degrees.
Figure 1 displays the index for each state for each month. Arizona, home
to the Arizona Diamondbacks, had the highest of the composite index of
economic indicators, while Michigan (home of the Detroit Tigers) had the
lowest index. Michigan's index changed the most, New York's
changed the least.
[FIGURE 1 OMITTED]
Dependent variable (AttenPct)
Because stadiums have widely varying seating capacities, we use
each MLB team's game-by-game attendance as a percentage of stadium
capacity as our dependent variable. It is common in the literature to
use stadium capacity as an explanatory variable in the attendance
equation, but our approach means we do not need to do that as a control
for stadium size. Moreover, seating capacity is not rightly a
determinant of demand, but rather a supply variable, so its inclusion in
a demand equation is problematic (Demmert, 1973). Thus, several studies
used attendance percentage as the dependent variable (e.g., Fizel &
Bennett, 1989; Fort & Rosenman, 1999; Kaempfer & Pacey, 1986;
Schollaert & Smith, 1987; Welki & Zlaptoper, 1999). Moreover, as
reported in Table 2, the majority of the estimated coefficients when
using attendance percentage and attendance level as dependent variables
are similar in sign and level of statistical significance. Whether the
dependent variable is actual attendance or the share of capacity, the
value is limited on the up side. Attendance cannot exceed capacity, and
the percentage of capacity cannot exceed 100%. In fact, during the 2008
and 2009 seasons, a total of 524 out of 4696 games were sold out,
representing approximately 12.6% of our sample. Consequently, we
estimate the model using a censored regression technique. The existence
of censored observations constrained by stadium capacity results in
parameter estimates that are biased and inconsistent (Meehan et al.,
2007) leading us to use censored regression to estimate the model.
Explanatory variables
Economic conditions (Econcon). The coincident index of economic
indicators for the 50 states released by Federal Reserve Bank of
Philadelphia is used to reflect economic conditions during each month of
the 2008 and 2009 seasons. There may be an issue for teams such as the
Phillies, Mets, and Yankees, whose territories cover multiple states.
Thus, we performed pairwise correlations for the coincident index for
the state pairs, using the data from 2006 to the present. All of the
correlations are positive and statistically significant and most are in
the .9 and above range. Consequently, we feel comfortable linking a team
to the coincident index of economic indicators for the state in which
its stadium is located. Because of the unavailability of the index for
Washington, D.C., the index for the state of Maryland was coded for the
Washington Nationals.
Rottenberg (1956) hypothesized that attendance will be affected by
the quality of the home team and the uncertainty of the outcome of the
game. These variables can be measured in several ways. Our variables are
described below:
Game uncertainty (HomeWin and OppWin). Winning percentages of the
home and visiting teams prior to the game are used to capture game
uncertainty of outcome in this study. Coates and Humphreys (2010) used
these winning percentages as indicators of the game uncertainty of the
outcome, along with betting line information in the National Football
League (NFL). As Coates and Humphreys (2010) mentioned, these winning
percentages also capture the quality of the teams.
Rottenberg (1956) suggested attendance would be greatest at games
between evenly matched teams, all else constant. However, evidence from
Forrest, et al. (2005), Buraimo and Simmons (2008), and Coates and
Humphreys (2010) who use betting line information to measure the
expected closeness of games, in Football Association games in England
and the National Football League, respectively, found home attendance
rises as the home team becomes a greater favorite.
Playoff uncertainty (monthsGameBehind). The measure of the playoff
uncertainty assumes that when a game is significant in determining
promotion or relegation, or for participation in the playoffs or a
wildcard race, then fans are more attracted to the game, resulting in
higher attendance (Borland & Macdonald, 2003). In the literature,
the playoff uncertainty is widely measured by games behind the division
leader in contention for playoff qualification (Baade & Tiehen,
1990; Butler, 2002; Canes, 1974; Demmert, 1973; Domazlicky & Kerr,
1990; Hill et al., 1982; Meehan et al., 2007; Noll, 1974; Schmidt &
Berri, 2004; Simmons, 2006; Soebbing, 2008). However, one critical issue
in this measure is the disability of identifying the time period
defining contention for playoff qualifications. Thus, in this study, the
month dummy variables are included and then the interaction of the month
and the number of games behind the division leader was added. Without
the month dummy variables, the interaction variable is likely picking up
mostly the month effect, especially early in the season.
Team performance (PlayoffApp). It is reasonable that fans'
expectations for the coming year and the decision to buy season tickets
could depend on the last season's performance. To reflect these
fans' expectations, a number of attendance studies used last
season's appearance in the playoffs (Coates & Harrison, 2005;
Coates & Humphreys, 2005; Meehan et al., 2007; Noll, 1974; Rivers
& Deschriver, 2002). This variable is measured as a dummy variable
for whether the home team appeared in the playoffs in the last season.
Interleague Play (Interleague). Since its inception in 1997,
interleague play has contributed to an increase in the MLB attendance.
According to Brown (2009), interleague play has drawn an average of
33,260 fans per game, compared to the intraleague average of 29,706 fans
per game during the same span. This figure indicated that interleague
play attracted 12.0 percent more fans than intraleague games. Therefore,
a number of attendance demand studies have included the effect of
interleague matchups (Boyd & Krebiel, 2006; Butler, 2002; Meehan et
al., 2007). A dummy variable was used to measure the effect of
interleague play on attendance by coding 1 if the home team played
against another league's team and 0 otherwise.
New stadium (Novelty). A large body of attendance research has
demonstrated a positive effect of a new stadium on attendance (e.g.,
Borland & McDonald, 2003; Coates & Humphreys, 2005; McEvoy et
al., 2005; Noll, 1974; Zygmont & Leadley, 2006). During the 2008 and
2009 seasons, the Washington Nationals played at a new stadium both
years, and the New York Yankees and Mets played at a new stadium in
2009. To capture the novelty effect, the analysis included a dummy
variable that takes value 1 when playing at the new stadium and 0
otherwise.
Star player (HomeStar and OppStar). Team composition plays a
fundamental role in facilitating fan support (Brandes, Frank, &
Nuesch, 2008). Recent studies on attendance demand clearly indicated
that star players contribute to driving attendance demand (Berri &
Schmdit, 2006). To assess the impact of popularity of star players on
attendance, the number of previous season All-Stars until mid-season of
the current year, and current season All-Stars for the second half of
the season were coded for both home and visiting teams.
Schedule (Weekend, Opening and Holidays). To control for when the
game is played, we included weekend, opening day, and holiday (Memorial
Day, Independence Day, and Labor Day) game dummy variables. These
dummies were used to control for possible unusually high attendance
driven by special circumstances.
Average ticket price (AvgTicket). Ticket (or admission) price has
been used in almost all attendance demand models in MLB (Coates &
Humphreys, 2007). Consistent with demand theory, it is assumed that as
price increases game attendance should decrease. Thus, it is expected
that the coefficient on the ticket price variable will be negative and
significant. Additionally, there has been an argument whether attendance
demand is price elastic or inelastic in the literature. Most recent
research has confirmed that teams set ticket prices in the inelastic
portion of attendance demand, possibly due to other revenue sources such
as concessions, local broadcasting, and parking (Coates & Humphreys,
2007; Fort, 2004, Marburger, 1997; Krautmann & Berri, 2007;
Zimbalist, 1992). Thus, it is expected that the absolute value of ticket
price elasticity is less than 1.
Limitations of the analysis
The data we have used in the analysis is not ideal. Many variables
are problematic. Here we describe three limitations of the analysis
owing to data issues that have not previously been mentioned.
Ticket prices in attendance demand studies are problematic. The
best measure would link the ticket price paid by the marginal ticket
buyer. Instead, available ticket price variables are the average ticket
price calculated either by dividing ticket revenue by tickets sold or by
constructing a weighted average of ticket prices by the proportion of
seats available at that price. Variable ticket pricing by day of the
week or opponent has become more common and is prevalent in our data. We
are not aware of any game-by-game ticket price data for all the clubs in
Major League Baseball, and even if that data existed it would suffer
from being an average. Consequently, while our ticket price variable is
not ideal, we believe it is a reasonable approximation of the relevant
price.
A second limitation is related to playoff contention. We include
games behind the division leader and that variable interacted with the
month dummy variables. But games behind the division leader may be less
important in our time period than it was for studies conducted before
the advent of the wildcard in baseball playoffs. We have considered
games behind in the wild card race and believe that games behind the
division leader addresses this issue adequately. In both the 2008 and
2009 seasons, and in both the American and the National Leagues, the
wild card winner had a better record at the end of the season than at
least one of the division winners. Moreover, in three of four cases, the
team in second in the wild card race was farther behind the wild card
leader than behind their division leader at the end of the season.
The third limitation is the lack of weather data in the model. Past
attendance models have measured the effect of weather on daily
attendance, but we have not included that in the current analysis. Two
approaches are common in the attendance demand studies. The first
approach is concerned with the temperature for the day of the game. For
example, as continuous variables, the average of the daily low and high
temperature (Meehan et al., 2007) and the temperature reported during
the game (Bruggink & Eaton, 1996; Paul, Paul, & Yelencsics,
2008) were used. Meanwhile, Butler (2002) used two dummy variables; one
is a dummy variable equal to 1 if game temperature was less than
55[degrees] F; the other is a dummy variable equal to 1 if game
temperature was greater than 94[degrees]F. The second approach concerns
rain. Meehan et al. (2007) used the number of inches of rain for a given
day, while DeSchriver (2007) and Butler (2002) included a dummy variable
to indicate whether the game was played during rainy weather conditions.
These different approaches to measurement of weather conditions have
generated contradictory results. Researchers should therefore address
more accurate methods that can be employed to assess the impact of
weather conditions. However, omitting weather should not alter our
results regarding the coincident indicator, because it is highly
unlikely that daily weather and monthly coincident indicator are highly
correlated.
Empirical Results and Discussion
Table 2 reports regression results from the censored regression
analysis with the team fixed effects. The censored regression model was
found to be significant with a log likelihood statistic of -16851.31.
The coefficient on the coincident indicator variable Econ is
significant and positive, as expected. This clearly indicates that
healthier economic conditions are associated with higher attendance.
Thus, the decrease in the composite index between 2008 and 2009,
representing the recent economic downturn throughout the whole economy,
influenced a decrease in attendance between the 2008 and the 2009
seasons. The estimated regression coefficient of 0.38 appears small.
However, at the mean values of attendance percentage and Econ, the
coefficient estimate implies an elasticity of 0.85. In other words, a
one percent increase in Econ, the coincident indicator, implies a 0.85
percent increase in attendance. For the period of our data, the average
decline in Econ is over 7.7%, suggesting a rough impact of the economic
decline on attendance from the start of 2008 until the end of 2009 of
about 6.5%, very nearly the 6.77% actual decline mentioned in the
introduction.
The following variables were used to capture the importance of
competitive balance and the uncertainty of outcome hypotheses. For game
uncertainty, the coefficients on the home (HomeWin) and visiting
team's (OppWin) current winning percentage to date variables are
statistically significant and positive. This result supports the idea
that fans are eager to see good teams play, regardless of whether it is
the visiting team (Coates & Humphreys, 2010). Thus, fans consider
the quality of both home and visiting teams for attendance. For playoff
uncertainty, the coefficients on the playoff uncertainty variables
before the month of July (MarchGameBehind, AprGameBehind, MayGameBehind,
JunGameBehind) were found to be insignificant while these variables for
the months of July, August, September and October (JulyGameBehind,
AugGameBehind, SepGameBehind, OctGameBehind) were significant and
negative. This has two important implications. One defines when fans
start to recognize playoff contention and the other is when the effect
of the division leader on attendance is more prominent than other
months. Indeed, the results are inconsistent with Noll's (1974)
judgment on when the contention, or race, for playoff spots begins.
Specifically, he judged the playoff contention as if the second-place
team averaged five games or fewer behind the leader between August 1 and
the end of the season. However, it should be noted that he did not
provide statistical justification why the playoff contention starts from
the month of August, rather it was based on his personal impressions.
The significant negative coefficients on the month dummy variables
indicated average attendance is lower in other months relative to
average attendance at games in March, the omitted month in the
regression. There were very few games played in March, 15 out of 4,696,
and two of those were played in Japan. These March games are, of course,
"Opening Day" games for the home teams and, therefore, have
unusually high attendance. To control this abnormal attendance, the
opening day dummy was included, resulting in the very strong impact on
attendance. It is, therefore, not surprising that average attendance in
other months is lower than in March. More importantly, consider the
pattern in the coefficients on the month dummy variables. As the weather
heats up through spring and into summer, and kids get out of school,
average attendance is rising--the month coefficients increase (-2.10 in
April, 2.46 in May, 3.94 in June, 10.70 in July)--until July. Average
attendance starts to decline again through August and September, until
it jumps up substantially in October. Not much should be made of this
increase in October, however, as there are only 56 games played in
October in the data compared to between 700 and 825 games each month
from April through September.
Surprisingly, the PlayoffApp had a negative impact on attendance.
The negative impact of the PlayoffApp may be explained with two features
of the teams that appeared in the 2007 and 2008 playoffs. One feature is
that several teams that appeared in previous playoffs showed poor
performance in that year. For example, the Cleveland Indians and the
Colorado Rockies appeared in the 2007 playoffs but performed poorly in
the 2008 season, resulting in a decrease in attendance. The Chicago
White Sox and the Milwaukee Brewers appeared in the 2008 playoffs and
also performed poorly in the 2009 season, resulting in a decrease in
attendance. If one includes interactions between the playoff appearance
dummy and the month of the season dummies (excluding an October
interaction), those interactions are each individually statistically
significant, and negative, while the playoff appearance dummy is
positive and statistically significant. (These results are available
upon request.) This relates to a second possible explanation for the
negative coefficient on the playoff appearance variable; several
teams' continued dominance may result in fans losing interest,
particularly early in the season. Eckard (2001) found a significant
decrease in attendance when a team is on a run of dominance. Thus, the
appearances of several dominant teams in the 2007 and/or 2008 playoffs,
such as the New York Yankees, the Los Angeles Angels, the Chicago Cubs,
the Boston Red Sox, and the Los Angeles Dodgers may generate the
possible loss of fan interest, or not produce additional interest in the
team, resulting in lower early season attendance. The estimated
coefficients on the playoff appearance month interactions suggest that
interest, in the form of attendance, rises slowly throughout the season
for the teams that repeatedly contend for the playoffs.
The estimated coefficients on the all-star variables for home
(HomeStar) and visiting teams (OppStar) were significant and positive.
What this result reveals is that home spectators are interested in
seeing both the home teams' and visiting teams' star players.
Visiting teams' star players' scarcity value (produced by less
opportunity of seeing them) is one possible explanation for the positive
association with attendance. Berri and Schmidt (2006) document the
impact of star players from the visiting team on attendance in the NBA.
The novelty effect was positive and statistically significant
despite only three teams playing at a new stadium during the time span
used. The coefficients on the weekend, the holidays and the interleague
variables were also significant and strongly positive, as expected.
These results are consistent with findings of previous attendance
studies.
Finally, the AvgTicket was found to be negative and statistically
significant. The negative sign on this variable indicated that higher
ticket prices were associated with lower attendance, as implied by
demand theory. Of the 29 MLB teams used in the analysis, eight teams
(the Arizona Diamondbacks, Baltimore Orioles, Cincinnati Reds, Cleveland
Indians, Los Angeles Dodgers, Oakland Athletics, Pittsburgh Pirates, and
San Diego Padres) lowered seasonal average ticket prices in the 2009
season. However, the lowered ticket prices in the 2009 season did not
seem to help boost attendance among the eight teams, as reflected by
each team's decline in attendance (i.e., the Arizona Diamondbacks:
-9.6%; Baltimore Orioles: -3%; Cincinnati Reds: -9.1%; Cleveland
Indians: -10.7%; Los Angeles Dodgers: 0.7%; Oakland Athletics: -8.5%;
Pittsburgh Pirates: -1.6%, and San Diego Padres: -14.7%).
The estimated absolute value of ticket price elasticity (.04 <
1) supports previous findings of ticket pricing in the inelastic portion
of the demand (Coates & Humphreys, 2007). In other words, MLB teams
could change ticket prices in response to a change in demand reflected
in attendance (Narayan & Smyth, 2003). As Coates and Humphreys
(2007) mentioned, this is due to "the inter-related pricing
decision on tickets, concessions, and other related goods made by
revenue maximizing monopolists in the NBA and MLB" (p. 169).
Conclusion
Using 4,696 games during the 2008 and 2009 seasons, the main focus
of the proposed study was to investigate the effect of the recent
economic crisis on attendance in MLB. Additionally, we included a
variety of standard explanatory variables based on attendance demand
theory to isolate the influence of the general economic circumstances,
represented by the coincident indicator, on game-by-game attendance. In
this section, the findings and the contributions of this paper are
reviewed.
First, our findings with respect to the control variables are
consistent with theoretical expectations. Ticket price exerts a negative
and statistically significant effect on game attendance. Better teams,
based on winning percentage to date, draw better, whether they are home
or visitors. Teams with more star players draw better than teams with
few stars. Interleague games draw better than intraleague games, and
Opening Day, holidays, and weekend games draw better than weekday games.
Second, as problematic as it may be, the games behind variables
provide an interesting implication pertaining to the time period
defining contention for playoff qualification. Indeed, previous research
only demonstrated fans lose their interests as a team is getting farther
behind the division leader. However, the negative and significant
playoff uncertainty variables for July, August, September and October
seem to indicate that fans start to recognize playoff contention in
July. It is possible that the present findings are partly attributable
to the increased media coverage of MLB playoff races that begins after
the All-Star Game.
Finally, this study suggests a previously unused measure of the
economic conditions, the composite index of coincident indicators, to
control for the influence of income on ticket demand. Indeed, most
research on attendance demand has used annual per capita income despite
its lack of variation over the season, with mixed results. To overcome
the limitations of per capita income, this study first applies the
composite index of coincident indicators as a measure of buying power
and economic circumstances. The empirical evidence indicates the recent
economic crisis contributed to a decline in MLB attendance over the
period 2008 through 2009; the implication of our results is that
deteriorating economic circumstances explain a decline of about 6.5%
compared to the reported decline of 6.77%. The success of the composite
index of coincident indicators in explaining the impact of the recent
economic crisis on attendance in MLB suggests the indicator is a viable
proxy for income in game attendance demand studies. As a practical
matter, the findings here provide information that can help team
marketers schedule events and promotions and set prices throughout the
season.
References
Alexander, D. L. (2001). Major League Baseball monopoly pricing and
profit-maximizing behavior. Journal of Sports Economics, 2(4), 341-355.
Baade, R. A., &Tiehen, L. J. (1990). An analysis of Major
League Baseball attendance, 1969-1987. Journal of Sport and Social
Issues, 14(1), 14-32.
Berri, D. J., & Schmidt, M. B. (2006). On the road with the
national basketball association's superstar externality. Journal of
Sports Economics, 7(4), 347-358.
Bird, P. J. (1982). The demand for league football. Applied
Economics, 14(6), 637-649.
Borland, J., & MacDonald, R. (2003). Demand for sport. Oxford
Review of Economic Policy, 19(4), 478-502.
Boyd, C. T., & Krehbiel, C. T. (2006). An analysis of the
effects of specific promotion types on attendance at Major League
Baseball games. Mid-American Journal of Business, 21(2), 21-32.
Brandes, L., Franck, E., & Nuesch, S. (2008). Local heroes and
superstars: An empirical analysis of star attraction in German soccer.
Journal of Sports Economics, 9(3), 266-286.
Brown, M. (2009). Inside the numbers: Final 2009 MLB regular season
attendance. Retrieved from
http://www.bizofbaseball.com/index.php?option=com_content&view=article&id= 3592:inside-the-numbers-final-2009-mlb-regular-season-attendance&catid=56:ticketwatch&Itemid=136
Bruggink, T. H., & Eaton, J. W. (1996). Rebuilding attendance
in Major League Baseball: The demand for individual games. In J. Fizel,
E. Gustafson & L. Hadley (Eds.), Baseball economics: Current
research (pp. 9-31). Westport, CT: Praeger.
Buraimo, B., & Simmons, R. (2008). Do sports fans really value
uncertainty of outcome? Evidence from the English Premier League.
International Journal of Sport Finance, 3, 146155.
Butler, M. R. (2002). Interleague play and baseball attendance.
Journal of Sports Economics, 3(4), 320-334.
Canes, M. E. (1974). The social benefits of restrictions on team
quality. In R. G. Noll (Ed.), Government and the sports business (pp.
81-113). Washington, DC: Brookings Institution.
Cho, V. (2001).Tourism forecasting and its relationship with
leading economic indicators. Journal of Hospitality & Tourism
Research, 25, 399-420.
Coates, D., & Harrison, T. (2005).Baseball strikes and the
demand for attendance. Journal of Sports Economics, 6(3), 282-302.
Coates, D., & Humphreys, B. R. (2005). Novelty effects of new
facilities on attendance at professional sporting events. Contemporary
Economic Policy, 23(3), 436-455.
Coates, D., & Humphreys, B. R. (2007). Ticket prices,
concessions and attendance at professional sporting events.
International Journal of Sport Finance, 2, 161-170.
Coates, D., & Humphreys, B. R. (2010). Week to week attendance
and competitive balance in the National Football League. International
Journal of Sport Finance, 5(4), 239-252.
Coffin, D. A. (1996). If you build it, will they come? Attendance
and new stadium construction. In J. L. Fizel, E. Gustafson, & L.
Hadley (Eds.), Baseball economics: Current research (pp. 3346).
Westport, CT: Praeger.
Conference Board. (2001). Business cycle indicators handbook. New
York, NY: The Conference Board.
Crone, T. M. (1994). New indexes track the state of the states.
Business Review, January/February, 19-31.
Crone, T. M., & Clayton-Matthews, A. (2005). Consistent
economic indexes for the 50 states. Review of Economics and Statistics,
87(4), 593-603.
Demmert, H. G. (1973). The economics of professional team sports.
Lexington, MA: Lexington Books.
DeSchriver, T. D. (2007). Much Adieu about Freddy: Freddy Adu and
attendance in Major League Soccer. Journal of Sport Management, 21(3),
438-451.
Dobson, S. M., & Goddard, J. A. (1995). The demand for
professional league football in England and Wales, 1925-92. The
Statistician, 259-277.
Domazlicky, B., R., & Kerr, P., M. (1990). Baseball attendance
and the designated hitter. American Economic Review, 34, 62-68.
Eckard, E. W. (2001). Baseball's Blue Ribbon economic report:
Solutions in search of a problem. Journal of Sports Economics, 2(3),
213-227.
Fizel, J. L., & Bennett, R. W. (1989). The impact of college
football telecasts on college football attendance. Social Science
Quarterly,70(4), 980-988.
Forrest, D., Simmons, R., & Buraimo, B. (2005). Outcome
uncertainty and the couch potato audience. Scottish Journal of Political
Economy, 52(4), 641-661.
Fort, R. (2004). Inelastic sports pricing. Managerial and Decision
Economics, 25(2), 87-94.
Fort, R., & Rosenman, R. (1999). Sports economics: Current
research. In E. G. J. Fizel, & L. Hadley (Ed.), Streak management
(pp. 119-134). Westport, CT: Praeger Publishers.
Garcia, J., & Rodriguez, P. (2002). The determinants of
football match attendance revisited. Journal of Sports Economics, 3(1),
18-38.
Hill, J. R., Madura, J., & Zuber, R. A. (1982). The short run
demand for Major League Baseball. Atlantic Economic Journal, 10, 31-35.
Jennett, N. (1984). Attendances, uncertainty of outcome and policy
in Scottish League Football. Scottish Journal of Political Economy,
31(2), 176-198.
Kaempfer, W. H., & Pacey, P. L. (1986).Televising college
football: The complementarity of attendance and viewing. Social Science
Quarterly, 67(1), 176-185.
Katona, G. (1974). Psychology and consumer economics. The Journal
of Consumer Research, 1(1), 1-8.
Krautmann, A., & Berri, D. (2007).Can we find it at the
concessions? Understanding price elasticity in professional sports.
Journal of Sports Economics, 8, 183-191.
Leadley, J. C., & Zygmont, Z. X. (2005). When is the honeymoon
over? National Basketball Association attendance 1971-2000. Journal of
Sports Economics, 6(2), 203-221.
Lemke, R. J., Leonard, M., & Tlhokwane, K. (2010). Estimating
attendance at Major League Baseball games for the 2007 season. Journal
of Sports Economics, 11(3), 316-348.
Marburger, D. R. (1997). Optimal ticket pricing for performance
goods. Managerial and Decision Economics, 18(5), 375-381.
McEvoy, C. D., Nagel, M. S., DeSchriver, T. D., & Brown, M. T.
(2005). Facility age and attendance in Major League Baseball. Sport
Management Review, 8(1), 19-41.
Meehan, J. W., Jr., Nelson, R. A., & Richardson, T. V. (2007).
Competitive balance and game attendance in Major League Baseball.
Journal of Sports Economics, 8(6), 563-580.
MLB.com. (2009, n. p.). MLB finishes 2009 season with fifth highest
attendance ever. Retrieved from
http://mlb.mlb.com/news/press_releases/pressrelease.jsp?ymd=20091006&content_id =7371722&vkey=pr_mlb&fext=.jsp&c_id
Morse, A. L., Shapiro, S. L., McEvoy, C. D., & Rascher, D. A.
(2008). The effects of roster turnover on demand in the National
Basketball Association. International Journal of Sport Finance, 3, 8-18.
Nightengale, B. (2009, September 30). Decline at gate a challenge
for undeterred commissioner Selig. USA Today. Retrieved from
http://www.usatoday.com/sports/baseball/2009-09-29mlb-attendance_N.htm
Noll, R. (1974). Attendance and price setting. In R. Noll (Ed.),
Government and the sports business (pp. 115-157). Washington, DC:
Brookings Institute.
Paul, R. J., Paul, K. K., & Yelencsics, K. (2008). Good day,
sunshine: Attendance for the Florida state league. Southern Business
& Economic Journal, 31(1/2), 63-74.
Rivers, D. H., & Deschriver, T. D. (2002). Star players,
payroll distribution, and Major League Baseball attendance. Sport
Marketing Quarterly, 11, 164-173.
Rottenberg, S. (1956). The baseball players' labor market. The
Journal of Political Economy, 64(3), 242-258.
Schmidt, M. B., & Berri, D. J. (2004). The impact of labor
strikes on consumer demand: An application to professional sports.
American Economic Review, 94(1), 344-357.
Schollaert, P. T., & Smith, D. H. (1987). Team racial
composition and sports attendance. The Sociological Quarterly, 28(1),
71-87.
Simmons, R. (2006). The demand for spectator sports. In W. Andreff
& S. Szymanski (Eds.), Handbook on the economics of sport (pp.
77-89). Cheltenham, UK: Edward Elgar Publishing Limited.
Soebbing, B. P. (2008). Competitive balance and attendance in Major
League Baseball: An empirical test of the uncertainty of outcome
hypothesis. International Journal of Sport Finance, 3, 119-216.
Stock, J. H., & Watson, M. W. (1989). New indexes of coincident
and leading economic indicators. NBER macroeconomics annual, 4, 351-394.
Stock, J. H., & Watson, M.W. (1991). A probability model of the
coincident economic indicators. In K. Lahiri & G. H. Moore (Eds.),
Leading economic indicators: New approaches and forecasting records (pp.
63-85). New York, NY: Cambridge University Press.
Turner, L. W., Kulendran, N., & Fernando, H. (1997). Univariate
modelling using periodic and non-periodic analysis: inbound tourism to
Japan, Australia and New Zealand compared. Tourism Economics, 3(1),
39-56.
Welki, A. M., & Zlatoper, T. J. (1999). U.S. professional
football game-day attendance. Atlantic Economic Journal, 27(3), 285-298.
Yamarone, R. (2004). The trader's guide to key economic
indicators. Princeton, NJ: Bloomberg Press.
Zimbalist, A. (1992). Salaries and performance: Beyond the Scully
model. In P. Sommers (Ed.), Diamonds are forever: The business of
baseball (pp. 109-133). Washington, DC: Brookings Institution.
Zygmont, Z. X., & Leadley, J. C. (2006). When is the honeymoon
over? National Hockey League attendance, 1970-2003. Canadian Public
Policy, 32(2), 213-232.
Sungil Hong [1], Michael Mondello [2], and Dennis Coates [3]
[1] Hong Kong Baptist University
[2] University of South Florida
[3] University of Maryland, Baltimore County
Sungil Hong is an assistant professor in the Department of Physical
Education. His current research focuses on attendance demand and
innovation diffusion in professional sports.
Michael Mondello teaches finance and analytics the MBA sport and
entertainment management program at the University of South Florida. His
research interest focuses on financial/economic issues related to sports
organizations including competitive balance, economic impact analysis,
contingent valuation, ticket pricing, and stadium financing.
Dennis Coates is a professor of economics at UMBC. His published
work has ranged from topics relating to voting behavior of legislators
to the economic effects of stadiums and professional sports franchises.
Table 1. Descriptive statistics for the variables to predict MLB
attendance demand during the 2008 and 2009 seasons (N = 4694)
Variable Mean SD Minimum Maximum
AttendancePct 71.33 22.44 21.00 100.00
Econcon 159.36 18.00 112.86 226.08
Interleague 0.10 0.30 0.00 1.00
HomeWin 49.98 9.79 0.00 100.00
OppWin 50.11 10.01 0.00 100.00
PlayoffApp 0.29 0.46 0.00 1.00
HomeAllstar 2.25 1.47 1.00 8.00
OppAllstar 2.18 1.43 1.00 8.00
Weekend 0.48 0.50 0.00 1.00
Holidays 0.02 0.13 0.00 1.00
Opening 0.01 0.11 0.00 1.00
AvgTicket 26.10 10.20 14.31 72.97
Novelty 0.05 0.22 0.00 1.00
MarchGameBehind 0.00 0.04 -0.50 1.50
April 0.15 0.36 0.00 1.00
AprGameBehind 0.29 1.17 -6.50 9.50
May 0.18 0.38 0.00 1.00
MayGamebehind 0.59 2.14 -8.50 14.00
June 0.16 0.37 0.00 1.00
JunGamebehind 0.81 2.86 -9.50 18.50
July 0.16 0.37 0.00 1.00
JulyGamebehind 0.90 3.45 -10.00 27.00
August 0.17 0.38 0.00 1.00
AugGamebehind 1.42 5.12 -18.00 31.50
September 0.16 0.37 0.00 1.00
SepGamebehind 1.75 6.21 -21.00 41.00
October 0.01 0.11 0.00 1.00
OctGamebehind 0.11 1.64 -8.50 40.00
Table 2. Summary of Regression Analysis for
Variables Predicting MLB Attendance
Variables Attendance Percentage (DV) Attendance (DV)
[beta] Stnd. t-stat P-value [beta] Stnd.
Error Error
Econcon 0.38 0.04 10.56 0.00 193.79 15.67
Interleague 8.06 0.84 9.57 0.00 3619.01 369.39
HomeWin 0.13 0.04 3.56 0.00 57.69 16.17
OppWin 0.13 0.02 5.79 0.00 57.67 9.98
PlayoffApp -3.62 0.75 -4.83 0.00 -1492.43 328.01
HomeAllstar 0.68 0.22 3.14 0.00 288.82 95.22
OppAllstar 2.02 0.14 14.14 0.00 911.20 62.46
Weekend 13.88 0.40 34.92 0.00 6124.33 174.34
Holidays 6.72 1.57 4.28 0.00 3258.88 688.00
Opening 44.91 2.37 18.99 0.00 19942.94 1033.45
AvgTicket -0.12 0.05 -2.29 0.02 -42.44 23.75
Novelty 6.54 1.33 4.90 0.00 -3712.05 585.93
MarchGame 6.93 6.99 0.99 0.32 1751.13 3097.72
Behind
April -2.10 5.56 -0.38 0.71 -2075.44 2427.84
AprGame 0.23 0.26 0.90 0.37 67.23 112.34
Behind
May 2.46 5.62 0.44 0.66 -32.52 2455.83
MayGame -0.08 0.13 -0.58 0.56 -57.36 58.45
behind
June 3.94 5.65 0.70 0.49 568.11 2470.33
JunGame -0.05 0.10 -0.45 0.65 -40.30 45.20
behind
July 10.70 5.64 1.90 0.06 3833.84 2463.29
JulyGame -0.18 0.08 -2.15 0.03 -126.80 35.80
behind
August 10.27 5.63 1.82 0.07 3617.53 2461.05
AugGame -0.22 0.06 -3.85 0.00 -126.37 24.90
behind
September 7.23 5.64 1.28 0.20 2390.24 2463.64
SepGame -0.33 0.05 -6.86 0.00 -171.53 21.02
behind
October 16.26 6.17 2.63 0.01 7222.95 2703.40
OctGame -0.88 0.16 -5.41 0.00 -457.46 71.95
behind
Variables Attendance (DV)
t-stat P-value
Econcon 12.37 0.00
Interleague 9.80 0.00
HomeWin 3.57 0.00
OppWin 5.78 0.00
PlayoffApp -4.55 0.00
HomeAllstar 3.03 0.00
OppAllstar 14.59 0.00
Weekend 35.13 0.00
Holidays 4.74 0.00
Opening 19.30 0.00
AvgTicket -1.79 0.07
Novelty -6.34 0.00
MarchGame 0.57 0.57
Behind
April -0.85 0.39
AprGame 0.60 0.55
Behind
May -0.01 0.99
MayGame -0.98 0.33
behind
June 0.23 0.82
JunGame -0.89 0.37
behind
July 1.56 0.12
JulyGame -3.54 0.00
behind
August 1.47 0.14
AugGame -5.07 0.00
behind
September 0.97 0.33
SepGame -8.16 0.00
behind
October 2.67 0.01
OctGame -6.36 0.00
behind
The model also includes home team dummy variables.