首页    期刊浏览 2024年11月24日 星期日
登录注册

文章基本信息

  • 标题:Bettor biases and the home-underdog bias in the NFL.
  • 作者:Humphreys, Brad R. ; Paul, Rodney J. ; Weinbach, Andrew P.
  • 期刊名称:International Journal of Sport Finance
  • 印刷版ISSN:1558-6235
  • 出版年度:2013
  • 期号:November
  • 语种:English
  • 出版社:Fitness Information Technology Inc.
  • 摘要:Although a balanced book is not explicitly posited by Dare and Dennis (2011), descriptions of their findings as reflecting the overall actions of bettors, their lack of any explicit discussion of sports book behavior, and their statement that "both the sides and totals betting lines are determined by market participants, they should reflect market expectations and forces" (p. 661) suggest that their findings be interpreted as stemming from the traditional balanced-book model.
  • 关键词:Gambling systems;Sports clubs

Bettor biases and the home-underdog bias in the NFL.


Humphreys, Brad R. ; Paul, Rodney J. ; Weinbach, Andrew P. 等


In a recent article, Dare and Dennis (2011) explore the nature of the home-underdog bias in NFL betting markets. They conclude that the home-underdog bias exists due to bettors consistently underestimating the scoring ability of home underdogs, but properly estimating the scoring ability of away favorites. Their findings depend critically on two underlying assumptions: first, prices set in the NFL betting market, the point spread and the total, are set simultaneously and reflect bettors forecasting the final score of the game, which informs their wagering decisions; second, the presence of a balanced book on the part of the sports book reflecting that prices are set to clear the market by equalizing betting on either side of the point spread and totals propositions.

Although a balanced book is not explicitly posited by Dare and Dennis (2011), descriptions of their findings as reflecting the overall actions of bettors, their lack of any explicit discussion of sports book behavior, and their statement that "both the sides and totals betting lines are determined by market participants, they should reflect market expectations and forces" (p. 661) suggest that their findings be interpreted as stemming from the traditional balanced-book model.

As noted by Dare and Dennis (2011), research on sports betting markets in North American team sports has identified what Woodland and Woodland (1994, 2003, 2001) termed a "reverse-favorite longshot" bias in baseball and hockey, where bets on better teams tend to produce larger negative returns than bets on weaker teams. (1) This bias has been attributed to the actions of bookmakers seeking to balance betting action in order to generate positive returns without (or with less) risk. If bettors systematically overestimate the favorite (stronger) team's abilities, or simply prefer to bet on stronger teams, a bookmaker that sets a line as a forecast will likely experience imbalanced betting, and adjust the line to reflect the flow of bets. Sports bettor biases therefore should tend to move prices and make bets on better teams relatively more expensive, driving down returns to bets on those teams.

The term favorite-longshot bias was originally used by psychologists Griffith (1949) and McGlothlin (1956) to describe the tendency for long-odds horses in parimutuel wagering markets to produce lower (larger negative) returns than short-odds horses. It should be noted that in parimutuel betting markets, odds are automatically driven by betting volume, so biases are a direct consequence of bettor actions. In North American team sports betting, where it is commonly assumed that bookmakers similarly try to balance the flow of betting action, research suggests that fans tend to over-bet the strongest teams in baseball and hockey (Woodland & Woodland, 1994, 2003, 2001). Dare and Holland (2004) and Golec and Tamarkin (1991) find that the strongest teams appear to be overbet in National Football League point spread betting markets. Dare and McDonald (1996) found that the model used by Golec and Tamarkin (1991) was biased and resulted in inappropriate findings of market efficiency in that study and developed an alternative model specification for testing the joint null hypothesis of informational efficiency in wagering markets. Dare and McDonald (1996) found little to no evidence against market efficiency in betting markets for NFL and college football regular season games.

In this paper, we replicate the Dare and Dennis (2011) results for the years following the end of their sample, 2005-2011. Although the mean forecast errors generated in this later sample are positive for both away favorites and home underdogs, as they are in the original Dare and Dennis (2011) sample from 1981-2004, testing for statistical significance of the mean forecast errors reveals the opposite result of Dare and Dennis (2011). Specifically, under their assumptions, in the 2005-2011 period, it appears that bettors underestimated the scoring ability of away favorites, but properly estimated the scoring ability of home underdogs.

These findings cast doubt on the assumptions and conclusions of Dare and Dennis (2011) about the source of the home-underdog bias. With this in mind, we offer an alternative theory of the source of the home-underdog bias that can explain why it appears to have diminished over time. Using detailed data on betting percentages from www.sportsinsights.com, we show that the balanced-book hypothesis does not hold in this context. Sports books appear to allow large imbalances in betting volume ("take a large position" in this market) in cases where imbalances are driven by highly predictable bettor tendencies, such as bettor preferences for betting on the biggest favorites (best teams) and bets on the over (bets that the total score will be above the posted total), as opposed to the under (bets that the combined score will be below the posted total). Bettors tend to place more wagers on favorites, with that percentage increasing with the point spread, and also have a tendency to bet more on away favorites than home favorites, with away favorites routinely attracting 70% or more of the bets on a game.

In addition, we show that there is a clear relationship between the percentage of bets on a team and the recent success of that team; that is, good teams tend to attract more bets than weak teams. The best teams in the NFL consistently attract the highest proportion of bets game after game and season after season. Also, over the period 20052011, all 32 teams in the NFL attracted a higher percentage of bets as the away team than they attracted as the home team. Even with these clear biases, in the period studied (2005-2011) the point spread appears to be set as a forecast of game outcomes, as simple wagering strategies of betting against these biases do not generate profits or reject market efficiency.

Given these findings, we hypothesize that the home-underdog bias is actually a function of simple bettor preferences for betting on the best teams in the point spread market and high scoring in the totals market. Bettors, behaving as fans rather than savvy and profit-seeking investors, enjoy placing wagers on the best teams in the NFL as these are the teams they most enjoy watching. The best teams in the league become the biggest favorites in games and have enough talent to overcome the implicit home-field advantage and become away favorites. In the situation where the best teams are away favorites, bettors appear to enjoy wagering on these teams at a "discount" as the prices (point spreads) are lower than when these same teams are at home.

Assuming that tastes and preferences of bettors have not changed over time, that bettors have always enjoyed wagering on the best teams and on the over (perhaps because fans derive greater consumption value from these bets when watching games), it begs this question: Why are there are differences in estimates of the mean forecast errors in games in the Dare and Dennis (2011) sample and the more recent sample used in this study? In addition, why was wagering on home underdogs apparently much more profitable in the earlier sample than in the later sample?

One possible explanation lies in the pricing strategy of sports books, which may have changed over time. We hypothesize that increased competition in the marketplace and the widespread availability of information through the use of technology have reduced the incentive for sports books to shade the line in the direction of the more popular side of the wagering proposition when the sports book believes the imbalance is merely fan-bias driven. This can explain why bookmakers appear to tolerate large and predictable betting imbalances in the market and still set a price that essentially acts as a forecast of game outcomes. In this case it is the knowledge of the bookmaker that generates a forecast of game outcomes, even as the bets made by the general public are influenced by their preferences and biases. Sports books may have changed their pricing strategy solely due to increased competition or because of the increased prevalence and actions of informed bettors. Wiseguys, as informed bettors are known, also benefit from technology as decreasing costs of obtaining information about teams, players, and games work to their benefit. If sports books price as a response to a small group of informed bettors, better access to information may allow for greater possible exploitation of biased point spreads or totals on the part of wiseguys, leading to sports books that more effectively price as an unbiased forecast of game outcomes.

This paper begins by describing the Dare and Dennis (2011) model and estimates their model using data from recent NFL games over the period 2005-2011. The next section uses detailed data on betting percentages to illustrate behavioral biases of bettors toward favorites and overs in a variety of settings. The subsequent section tests for market efficiency and examines profitability in betting against the clear behavioral biases in this market. The final section discusses the results in terms of changes in the betting market over time, including new technology and increased competition, and concludes the paper.

Mean Forecasts Errors and the Dare and Dennis (2011) Model

To begin, we estimate the Dare and Dennis (2011) (2) model using data from recent NFL seasons. The model used by Dare and Dennis (2011) assumes that the point spread ("side") and total for each game are jointly set in the betting market for NFL football. Their assumption implies that the prices in these betting markets are simultaneously set and are determined, specifically, by bettors basing their bets on forecasts of an expected final score of the game. Therefore, the side and total are linked in this market.

Under the assumptions of Dare and Dennis (2011), bettors form an expected score of the home team and the away team and then bet accordingly. Their model is as follows:
E([S.sub.H]) = Expected Score of Home Team
E([S.sub.A]) = Expected Score of Away Team
(CSL) = -(E([S.sub.H]) - E([S.sub.A]))        [Closing Line]
(CTL) = E([S.sub.H]) + E([S.sub.A])           [Closing Total]
E([S.sub.A]) = (CTL + CSL)/2
E([S.sub.H]) = E([S.sub.A]) - CSL
[FE.sub.H] = [S.sub.H] - E([S.sub.H])         [Forecast Error Home]
[FE.sub.A] = [S.sub.A] - E([S.sub.A])         [Forecast Error Away]


The closing point spread is formed by taking the negative of the difference between the expected home score and expected away score (home favorites are denoted with a negative value). The closing total is the sum of the expected scores. From here, algebraic manipulation generates the expected home and away scores, which then allows for the calculation of the forecast errors for the home and away teams by taking the difference between actual and expected scores.

Dare and Dennis (2011) used this model to calculate mean forecast errors for a sample of NFL games from 1981 to 2004. They found that all characteristics of teams analyzed (favorites, underdogs, home teams, away teams, home favorites, away underdogs, away favorites, home underdogs) generate positive mean forecast errors, implying that bettors systematically underestimate the scoring of all teams in the NFL. Specifically, for the focus of their study, Dare and Dennis (2011) find statistically significant evidence that bettors underestimate the scoring of home underdogs, but also find that bettors properly estimate the scoring of away favorites (although the mean forecast error is positive, it is not statistically significant). Dare and Dennis (2011) conclude that the home-underdog bias is a function of bettors underestimating the scoring of home underdogs, making findings of profitable strategies based on betting home underdogs truly a function of a public bias against home underdogs.

Although statistically correct given their data sample, we dispute the assumptions underlying the Dare and Dennis (2011) model. First, we do not believe the vast majority of bettors behave as sophisticated investors. In other words, we do not believe that most bettors estimate the final score of the game in question and make their bets accordingly. Casual observation of bettor behavior suggests that the majority of bettors do not use statistical models to generate estimates of final scores and determine bets. Instead, bets appear to be made based on "feel" or intuition as bettors believe that one team will blowout the other team, or due to both teams scoring many points in previous games, the game will be a "shoot-out," leading bettors to place large number of bets on favorites and overs.

Although we do not believe that many bettors actually form specific estimates of the exact final score before placing wagers, if the assumptions of Dare and Dennis (2011) are correct, bettors should place a similar number of wagers in both the sides and totals market. Under the assumption that bettors estimate expected scores for both teams, bettors should be willing to place wagers on both the side and total propositions suggested by their expected scores. This is simply not observed in NFL betting markets (or in other sports) as the amount of money bet in the point spread market consistently far exceeds that in the totals market. Point spread wagers are extremely popular with bettors, while totals bets are not nearly as popular. Also, mean forecast errors generated for all groupings of teams (favorites, underdogs, home teams, away teams, etc.) are uniformly positive, implying that bettors underestimate the scoring of every team in the NFL. This is inconsistent with findings that simple strategies of betting the under in the totals market for games with the highest totals has been found to reject the null hypothesis of market efficiency and also reject the null of no profitability (Paul & Weinbach, 2002). In addition, casual observation suggests that overs are much more popular bets than unders; this has been borne out in studies of betting percentages (Paul & Weinbach, 2008, 2011), where bets on the over have been shown to be clearly preferred to bets on the under.

The primary assumption underlying the Dare and Dennis (2011) model that we question, however, is the implicit assumption that sports books strictly adhere to the balanced-book model. Dare and Dennis (2011) assume that point spreads and totals are set by the actions of bettors. Sports books are assumed to set prices in an attempt to attract even betting action on each side of the proposition. If bettors prefer one side of the proposition to the other, prices are assumed to move in the direction of the betting action as sports books attempt to minimize risk by attempting to balance the overall betting dollars by inducing later bettors to take the other side of the proposition. For example, if team A is a 7-point favorite and the betting volume is heavily skewed toward bets on team A, the balance-book model predicts that bookmakers would increase the line, making team A an even heavier favorite, in an attempt to induce bettors to bet on team B to cover.

The balanced-book model was challenged by Levitt (2005). Levitt used data from a betting tournament based on NFL games to demonstrate that bettors prefer favorites to underdogs, particularly road favorites compared to home underdogs. Levitt reported that sports books shade the line toward road favorites, resulting in higher returns to wagering on home underdogs. Although Levitt used data from a betting tournament, which may not reflect the incentives and decisions in actual betting markets, the fact that bets on favorites (particularly road favorites) are more popular than bets on underdogs has been shown to exist in actual betting markets (Paul & Weinbach, 2008, 2011) where betting percentages from actual sports books show a clear preference for favorites and overs; the predictions of the balanced-book model appear to be inconsistent with betting volume in on NFL games and in other sports.

If sports books are not pricing according to the balanced-book model and are willing to take positions on individual games, the conclusions of Dare and Dennis (2011) can be questioned as closing prices in the betting market reflect decisions made by bookmakers (in addition to any informed bettors in the market to whom sports book managers may respond) and not the preferences of the majority of bettors. If the sports books price as a forecast of game outcomes, as suggested by Paul and Weinbach (2008), the market prices may leave no profit opportunities, despite the presence of clear behavioral biases on the part of bettors. The closing lines and totals may therefore reflect the actions of bookmakers (and/or the actions of a small group of informed bettors), and not necessarily be driven by the actions of overall bettors in the market.

To illustrate the potential problems with the assumptions underlying the Dare and Dennis (2011) model, we first estimate their model using data from the most recent seasons in the NFL. Their sample of data was taken from the sports book at the Stardust Casino in Las Vegas from the 1981-82 to 2004-05 NFL seasons. We begin our initial sample in 2005-06 and include each NFL season through 2011-12 with data gathered from www.covers.com.

Using the exact model from Dare and Dennis (2011), shown in the previous section, we calculate mean forecast errors (the difference between the expected and actual game outcomes) using data from the 2005-06 to 2011-12 seasons for a number of identifiable game characteristics. The results are shown in Table 1.

Like the results in Dare and Dennis (2011), all mean forecast errors from this sample are positive. In terms of the home-underdog bias, the results from 2005-06 to 201112 reveal the opposite outcome compared to the earlier sample period. The null hypothesis that the mean forecast error is zero can be rejected for away favorites, but cannot be rejected for home underdogs. Therefore, the results from the later sample, under the assumptions of Dare and Dennis (2011), show that bettors now underestimate the scoring ability of away favorites, but correctly estimate the scoring ability of home underdogs. Therefore, the home-underdog bias would be more properly called the away-favorite bias.

Our data goes back to the 1985-86 season. Breaking this sample into 5-year intervals (6 years for the most recent period), we examine how the model of Dare and Dennis performed over these subsamples, focusing on the groupings of away favorites and home underdogs with t-stats in parentheses and are presented in Table 2 below.

As can be seen from Table 2, there are considerable differences across the five-year periods, especially for away favorites. During the first 5-year subsample (1985-1989), the mean forecast error was negative, meaning that bettors overestimated the scoring ability of away favorites. In all of the other subsamples, the mean forecast error was positive, implying that bettors underestimated the scoring ability of away favorites to some degree, including by a statistically significant margin in the most recent subsample. The results for home underdogs show more consistency across the subsamples as the mean forecast error was positive in all periods shown, but the factor likely driving the overall results reported in Dare and Dennis (2011) was during the late 1990s (1995-1999). Based on the Dare and Dennis (2011) assumptions, breaking the sample into subperiods reveals that there could have been a change in the preferences of bettors for away favorites over the years, in addition to varying degrees of underestimation of scoring of both away favorites and home underdogs.

One explanation for this pattern of results is that bettors are fickle and their tastes and preferences change over time. If we assume that tastes and preferences do not change over time (Stigler & Becker, 1977), however, there could be another explanation for this pattern of results. If bookmakers have changed the nature of their pricing decisions over time, similar results could be found without the tastes, preferences, and expectations of bettors changing. We find the conclusion that bettors underestimate the scoring of both away favorites and home underdogs (or any category of teams shown in Table 1) to be dubious given results that unders have outperformed overs in the totals betting market in the NFL (Paul & Weinbach, 2002) and many other sports. If bettors truly underestimated scoring by both teams, the under should be a much more popular bet than the over, which previous research has shown not to be the case (Paul & Weinbach, 2008, 2011). Therefore, we believe there are other explanations for the home-underdog bias that are consistent with constant preferences. The next section explores these possibilities by analyzing more detailed betting market data.

Betting Percentages and the Home-Underdog Bias

Data from www.sportsinsights.com show detailed information on betting percentages on the favorite and underdog (in addition to the over and under) for each NFL game from 2005 to 2011. These betting percentages are based on the number of bets placed on each side in the wagering proposition, not on dollars wagered. Although the actual amount of money bet is not known, the betting percentages in the Sports Insights data has been demonstrated to be very similar to the data available on www.sportsbook.com, which reports the percentage of dollars bet (see Paul & Weinbach, 2011, for details). Other anecdotal evidence of imbalances in dollars bet on either side of propositions exists. During the 2012 NFL season, comments by sports book operators and industry experts in the media remarked on the lopsided betting on the Monday Night Football game between the Green Bay Packers and Seattle Seahawks early in the season, where a poor call at the end of the game not only changed who won the game, but also changed which team covered the point spread. Accounts of the wagering action on the game noted a heavy betting imbalance toward Green Bay, who ultimately lost the game and whose bettors lost their bets, with the reported percentages (generally around 70%) in line with forecasts of betting percentages for similar games in Paul and Weinbach (2008, 2011). We assume that the percentage of bets placed on either side is highly correlated with the percentage of dollars bet and treat them as equivalent. Humphreys, Paul, and Weinbach (2010) discuss the relationship between bets placed and dollars bet.

Under the balanced-book model, the amount bet on either side of a proposition should tend to be even on average, without systematic and predictable patterns. The model predicts that the betting volume should be equal on average because bookmakers set prices and adjust them periodically to achieve balanced betting on each side of wagering propositions. This balanced betting eliminates their risk and allows the sports book to earn a certain return equal to the vigorish (commission) on losing bets. Previous tests of the balanced-book model in the NFL soundly reject the null hypothesis of a balanced book (Levitt, 2005; Paul & Weinbach, 2008; 2011). Table 3 summarizes the betting percentages for all NFL games, games with home favorites, and games with away favorites in terms of the percentage of bets on the home team, away team, the over, and the under for the Sports Insights data over the period 2005-2011.

Table 3 reveals rather straightforward patterns in betting volume. Bettors slightly prefer to bet the away team to the home team. Depending on whether the home team or away team is favored changes the side bettors prefer. Bettors slightly prefer home favorites by a 57%-43% margin, but have an extreme preference for away favorites by a 71%-29% margin. We hypothesize that this actually has very little to do with preferences for betting on teams on the road or at home, but has everything to do with the relative quality of teams in the league. The teams that are performing the best and have a history of success are much more likely to be home favorites and the best-of-the-best teams have enough of a talent advantage on their opponent to overcome the implicit home field advantage and become away favorites. The patterns in the betting percentages on Table 3 simply reflect that bettors prefer to wager on the best teams, just like they prefer to attend games when teams are performing well and to watch games on TV between the best teams. The over/under bets reveal (across all specifications) that bettors prefer the over to the under by a 65%-35% margin. This shows that bettors prefer to wager on high scoring games, not defensive struggles. The behavioral explanation that bettors behave like fans and enjoy wagering on the best teams and like to watch (and place bets on) scoring is simple, straightforward, and, we believe, intuitively appealing.

To further illustrate this point, we present simple regression results with the percentage bet on the favorite (in the sides market) and the over (in the totals market) as the dependent variables in two regression equations. The independent variables are an intercept, the absolute value of the point spread, and a dummy for a team being an away favorite in the sides regression and an intercept and the total in the totals market regression. Under the balanced-book model, the intercept should equal 0.5 and the other variables should not be statistically significant. We estimate these regression models using OLS. Results are presented on Table 4 below. Statistical significance is noted with * -notation (*** -significance at the 1% level) and t-statistics are shown in parentheses below the parameter estimates.

[FIGURE 1 OMITTED]

[FIGURE 2 OMITTED]

The regression results reveal that bettors appear to prefer away favorites by a large margin, with the simple designation of a team as an away favorite leading to a 16%+ increase in the percentage bet on that team. In addition, the bigger the favorite, the greater the percentage of bets on the team, with each additional point of the point spread leading to a 1.3% increase in the percentage bet on that team. Given that the best teams are the teams who earn the designation of away favorites and are likely to be biggest favorites on the board (both in home games and away games), it is clear that bettors prefer the best teams when they place wagers. Also, they clearly prefer to bet the over in games with higher totals, as the percentage bet on the over rises with each point of the total (by nearly one percentage point). The preferences of bettors are easily identified, and there is no strong evidence or logical justification that would suggest that the sports books should be expected to be balanced when these preferences are so easily identifiable.

[FIGURE 3 OMITTED]

Another way to present the results is to simply plot the relationship between the percentage bet on a team and the team winning percentage. Obviously, this unconditional approach does not capture all of the information that a point spread on a game would, but it clearly illustrates how team quality affects the percentage bet on the team. Each of the three following figures show the percentage bet on the team on the vertical axis and the straight-up win percentage of the team on the horizontal axis. The first figure is for all games, the second figure is for home teams, and the third figure is the away team.

In all three figures, it is quite clear that the percentage bet on a team increases with the winning percentage of the team. Under the balanced-book hypothesis, this simply cannot be the case because the point spread is assumed to be set to attract equal amounts of money on each side of the proposition. In each figure, the most successful teams on the field attract the highest percentage of bets in the wagering market.

One last simple example to demonstrate that bettors prefer to wager on the best teams can be illustrated by calculating average betting percentages by team. Again, under the balanced-book hypothesis, the point spread will be set and changed based on bet volume to balance the betting action. Any individual team should not accumulate a majority of bets. A simple calculation of the average percentage bet by team shows a clear hierarchy, where the best teams in recent years are also the ones who are the most popular to bet. Table 5 shows the betting percentage by team in the NFL for the sample period. Listed are the average percentage bet on the team as an away team, the average percentage bet on the team as a home team, the difference (in percentages) of home compared to away, the average point spread as an away team, the average point spread as a home team, and the difference between the average home point spread and average away point spread.

Table 5 shows that the best teams over the past six years have also received the most bets. Perennial playoff teams, conference champions, and Super Bowl winners populate the top teams who receive the backing of the betting public. Teams with the most well-known quarterbacks, a key position both for the game and for the fans, the New England Patriots (Tom Brady) and the Indianapolis Colts (Peyton Manning until his injury in 2011), top the list. (3) Other successful teams like the Pittsburgh Steelers and New York Giants also rank near the top of the list. The teams at the bottom of the distribution in terms of fan interest in betting include teams that have not had much success through most of the seven-year sample period. The Oakland Raiders, Houston Texans, and Detroit Lions, who were rather poor teams until recently, attracted the fewest bets.

Another point that can easily be seen in Table 5 is that teams attract a higher percentage of the bets in games when they are the away team, rather than the home team. Each of the 32 teams attracted a higher average percentage of the bets when they were the visiting team. Teams are bigger underdogs or smaller favorites on the road due to the home field advantage (see the last three columns of Table 5), which is commonly estimated as three points. Bettors appear to be more willing to wager on a team when they are the away team, perhaps due to the fact that the point spread appears more favorable when a team is on the road. This result is consistent with the idea that bettors do not believe the home field advantage is worth as much as the point spreads imply, or somehow fail to recognize the full potential advantage of being the home team.

Bettor Biases, Sports Book Pricing, and Market Efficiency

The previous section suggests the presence of behavioral biases in betting on NFL games. The betting percentage data reveal that this bias is not an underestimation of the scoring ability of home underdogs, as suggested by Dare and Dennis (2011), but a more straightforward behavioral bias: fans prefer to wager on the best teams in the league. The bigger the favorite, particularly when the favorite is the away team, the higher the percentage of bets that accumulates on that team. The best teams in the league are the teams who are favorites on the road and are the biggest home favorites. In addition, fans prefer to wager on games with a possibility of more scoring in the totals market and bet more on away teams in general, who may view these as opportunities to bet on a team at a discount, if fans do not fully appreciate the value of the home field advantage included in to the point spread.

A key question in this analysis: Do any of these biases result in profitable betting strategies for those willing to wager against public opinion? If bettors can earn profits by taking positions against the betting public, specifically by wagering on home underdogs and/or underdogs in general, this would imply that the behavioral bias is affecting the pricing of games and market inefficiencies may exist. Table 6 below illustrates that this is not the case. Table 6 shows the win-loss-push records and win percentages resulting from simple strategies of betting favorites and underdogs for games with home favorites, games with road favorites, and all games. In addition, the results for the totals market are shown in terms of over and under wagers.

None of the win percentages from these simple strategies win enough to overcome the bookmaker's commission. Sports books use a wager $11 to win $10 rule, implying that bettors must win more than 52.38% of wagers to earn profits. (4) Although bettors have a clear bias toward road favorites, favorites in general, and the over, these biases do not appear to be priced into the market, as favorites and underdogs (overs and unders) each win about 50% of the time, with contrarian strategies earning negative returns.

It does not appear that sports books set prices based on the expected actions of biased bettors. While sports books may adjust prices in response to betting imbalances, bettors are shown to exhibit obvious and predictable tendencies and sports books appear to set a price as a forecast of game outcomes, despite predictable imbalanced betting activity from the betting public. This was observed in previous studies of NFL betting percentages in the wagering market (Paul & Weinbach, 2008, 2011) and is seen in this setting as well. In the time period analyzed, the assumption that the prices set by sports books are a simple reaction to the decisions made by bettors does not appear to be valid, nor does a strategy of shading the point spread in the direction of the more popular team (e.g., Levitt, 2004). Rather, it appears that the sports book sets point spreads and totals as forecasts of game outcomes (perhaps as a response to the actions of a small group of informed bettors), allowing the betting imbalances to persist over time.

Discussion and Conclusions

The results above suggest the presence of significant bettor biases in the NFL betting market that are both persistent and predictable. Bettors behave much like fans; they tend to place wagers on the best teams and on the outcome of a high total score (the over). A preference for betting on the best teams manifests itself as a preference for favorites overall (with bigger favorites attracting even a higher percentage of the betting action) and for road favorites in particular. The best teams in the league are typically the only teams able to overcome an opponent's home field advantage and become listed as favorites when they are the away team. In addition, it appears that bettors underestimate the impact of the home field advantage, as every team in the league received a higher percentage of bets as an away team than they did as a home team. The home-underdog bias is a straightforward combination of fans preferring the best teams (and higher scoring) and a systematic undervaluation of the impact of home field.

Although the home-underdog bias was shown to be profitable in the past, recent studies (including this one) do not find profitability from wagering on home underdogs. In our analysis of data from the 2005-2011 NFL seasons, home underdogs actually underperformed, winning only 48.35% of their games against the point spread, despite the huge betting bias toward road favorites. This is likely due to the balanced-book model not describing bookmaker's decisions. If sports books allow betting imbalances, but price as a forecast of game outcomes, the null hypothesis of efficient markets will not be rejected, despite clear behavioral biases in the market, as shown in this study.

Given past successes of wagering strategies based on betting home underdogs and the overall findings of Dare and Dennis (2011), it is possible that a key element in this market has changed over time. Assuming constant tastes and preferences (Stigler & Becker, 1977), meaning that, in general, bettors (like fans) have always preferred to bet on the best teams and high-scoring games, we consider the possibility that the pricing strategies of sports books have changed over time. Due to relative price changes in the market, it is possible that sports books priced differently in the past (especially 1970s through part of the 1990s) than they do today. If this is the case, profitable strategies may have existed in the past but have changed due to the nature of sports book pricing.

There may be good reason to believe that sports books have changed how they set and move point spreads over time, due largely to advances in technology, increased access to information, and increased competition in the betting market. The dramatic decline in the cost of historical and current information, driven by the adoption of the internet and the reduction in costs of data storage and retrieval, as well as hardware and software, make it easier for bettors and sports books to access and analyze information. It is now quick and easy for an individual to back-test betting strategies, learn information about teams and players, and know the opinions of a number of expert prognosticators each weekend. Some of the imbalances in betting flows may actually be fueled or accelerated by disproportionate coverage from online, radio, and television sources that may drive the actions of uninformed bettors.

While technology has improved the information available to sports book managers, it has also improved the information available to informed bettors. If informed bettors have either become more numerous or their forecasting accuracy has increased, this also naturally drives sports books to price as an optimal forecast of game outcomes due to the actions of this small group of bettors. Under this scenario, the preferences of a large group of uninformed bettors in a betting market could generate clear behavioral biases toward the best teams and the over, and closing point spreads and totals that are still unbiased forecasts of game outcomes.

An additional important factor driving this change in sports book behavior is increased competition in the betting market. In the 1990s, online sports books became a major competitor for both legal sports betting in Nevada (and around the world) and local illegal sports books in the U.S. Increased competition, as theory would predict, would lead prices (point spreads and totals) to converge. In addition, increased competition likely made it less attractive for an individual sports book to systematically exploit known bettor biases, such as those for away favorites and overs.

To illustrate this point, suppose in a hypothetical market all sports books shade point spreads toward away favorites. In the absence of competition or through strong collusion between a small number of sports books, this could be possible. As competition increases, however, the incentive to set a lower point spread on the away favorite (more in line with game outcome expectations) becomes quite tempting and perhaps a profit-maximizing strategy. If betting the away favorites (best teams) is popular with bettors, offering a slightly lower price than other bookmakers would increase betting volume for an individual sports book. This competition could be expected to pressure other sports books to follow suit. The resulting prices would then converge across sports books and would also gravitate toward becoming an unbiased forecast of game outcomes. Behavioral biases may persist but be hidden by sports books whose lines tended to gravitate toward unbiased forecasts of game outcomes.

Similarly, suppose that all sports books set point spreads as forecasts of game outcomes. A single sports book may attempt to shade the point spread by raising the price on away favorites. Even if this sports book has some market power with bettors who may not stray from their regular bookmaker, it is possible that the new inflated line causes some regular customers to frequent other sports books or attracts enough attention to become lopsided on the underdog at an inflated line. If the line move is large enough so that a bet on the contrarian position has a greater than 52.38% chance of winning, it could attract bets from informed bettors (or even other sports book managers) to take advantage of the inflated line. Deterring bettors who place wagers with a negative expected value and attracting bettors who wish to make a wager that may offer a smaller negative expected value or even positive expected value is likely not a good bookmaker strategy for the long run.

Overall, the reduced cost of information and communication applies greater pressure toward equilibrium in this market where sports books have a strong tendency to offer prices that are essentially forecasts of game outcomes, though behavioral biases are widespread and persistent, and tests of market efficiency cannot be rejected. In the past, due to the higher costs of technology and information, and a lack of competition, sports books could more easily shade lines in obviously biased situations and restrict the actions of informed bettors by enforcing betting limits ("booking to face"), so that these strategies could be profit maximizing. Some basic strategies, such as wagering on a subset of home underdogs or unders, could have been profitable for a disciplined and diligent bettor, though such a bettor would likely be constrained to posted house betting limits on these wagers. Since sports books reserve the right to reject any wager from any person for any reason, these strategies would constantly be at risk of being shut out of the market if their actions upset the sports book manager. The ability to limit the influence of individuals in the marketplace allowed point spreads to move in the direction of the underlying biases of bettors. This would explain the findings of earlier studies that identified contrarian strategies that yielded positive returns.

Given increased competition (spurred by innovations in technology), however, where contrarian strategies may once have been possible, it has apparently become increasingly difficult to produce a strategy that could produce a rejection of the null hypothesis of market efficiency. While the common assumption in financial markets is that this "market correction" must be a result of market participants (investors or bettors) learning and changing their behavior, the driving force behind this change is likely the evolution of pricing strategies of sports books within the market due to increased competition and possible response to a small group of informed bettors. While this distinction may not matter to some, for they are observationally equivalent, we believe that it is noteworthy that there appears to be and likely always has been a strong component of consumption and behavioral biases behind sports betting markets. Although sports books risk losing money on any individual game or day, as opposed to the assumptions of the balanced-book hypothesis where they earn their commission without risk on each game, the sports book still earns its commission on losing bets in the long-run by offering prices that evenly distribute wins between favorites and underdogs (or overs and unders). This is likely a long-run profit maximizing strategy as well, as the recreational bettors do not lose their money as quickly (under the balanced-book model, if betting lines become inflated on popular teams, the sports book would collect a commission, but the recreational bettors would be generating net transfers to "informed traders" on the other side). This may keep more bettors placing wagers week after week and season after season, instead of having their bankrolls depleted early, decreasing the likelihood of placing wagers in future weeks, months, and seasons. In the end, betting is a zero-sum game, with real transactions costs that must be recovered by the sports book. The average return earned by bettors must therefore be negative in the long run.

This explanation is consistent with earlier findings of market inefficiency and current findings supporting market efficiency without the need for bettors' tastes and preferences to change, or requiring new market participants to enter to exploit sports book prices and bring the market back to efficient prices. Most bettors can wager as a form of consumption rather than investment, with clear and predictable preferences for betting on the best teams and scoring, yet prices in these markets still remain unbiased forecasts of game outcomes. In this simple financial market, strong behavioral biases exist, yet prices are such that they provide unbiased forecasts of game outcomes due to the incentives of the market makers (sports books), increased competition for their services, and the actions of a small number of informed bettors.

Brad R. Humphreys is on the faculty of the Department of Economics, in the College of Business and Economics at West Virginia University. His research interests include the economic impact of professional sports teams and facilities, the effect of social regulations on intercollegiate athletics, the economic determinants of participation in physical activity, and the financing of professional sports facility construction.

References

Cain, M., Law, D., & Peel, D. (2000). Testing for statistical and market efficiency when forecast errors are non-normal: The NFL betting market revisited. The Journal of Forecasting, 19, 575-586.

Dare, W., & Dennis, S. (2011). A test for bias of inherent characteristics in betting markets. Journal of Sports Economics, 12, 660-665.

Dare, W., & Holland, S. (2004). Efficiency in the NFL betting market: Modifying and consolidating research methods. Applied Economics, 36, 9-15.

Dare, W. & McDonald, S. (1996). A generalized model for testing the home and favorite team advantage in point spread markets. Journal of Financial Economics, 40, 295-318.

Gandar, J. M., Zuber, R. A., Johnson, R. S., & Dare, W. (2002). Re-examining the betting market on Major League Baseball games: Is there a reverse favorite-longshot bias? Applied Economics, 34, 1309-1317.

Golic, J., & Tomarkin, M. (1991). The degree of inefficiency in the football betting markets. Journal of Financial Economics, 30, 321-330.

Griffith, R. M. (1949). Odds adjustments by American horse race bettors. American Journal of Psychology, 62, 290-294. Reprinted in Hausch, D. B., et al. (1994). Efficiency of racetrack betting markets. New York, NY: Academic Press.

Humphreys, B., Paul, R. & Weinbach, A. (2010). Consumption benefits and gambling: Evidence from the NCAA basketball betting market. University of Alberta Department of Economics Working Paper No. 2010-07.

Ioannidis, C., & Peel, D. (2005). Testing for market efficiency in gambling markets when the errors are non-normal and heteroskedastic: An application of the wild bootstrap. Economics Letters, 87, 221-226.

McGlothlin, W. H. (1956). Stability of choices among uncertain alternatives. American Journal of Psychology, 69, 604-615. Reprinted in Hausch, et al., 1994.

Levitt, S. (2004). Why are gambling markets organized so differently from financial markets? The Economic Journal, 114, 223-46.

Paul, R., & Weinbach, A. (2002). Market inefficiency and a profitable betting rule: Evidence from totals on professional football. Journal of Sports Economics 3, 256-263.

Paul, R., & Weinbach, A. (2008). Does sportsbook.com set point spreads to maximize profits? Tests of the Levitt Model of sports book behavior. Journal of Prediction Markets, 1, 209-218.

Paul, R., & Weinbach, A. (2011). Bettor biases and price setting by sports books in the NFL: Further tests of the Levitt Hypothesis of sports book behavior. Applied Economics Letters, 18, 193-197.

Stigler, G., & Becker, G. (1977). De gustibus non est disputandum. The American Economic Review, 67, 76-90.

Woodland, L. M., & Woodland, B. M. (1994). Market efficiency and the favorite-longshot bias: The baseball betting market. Journal of Finance, 49, 269-280.

Woodland, L. M., & Woodland, B. M. (2001). Market efficiency and profitable wagering in the National Hockey League: Can bettors score on longshots? Southern Economic Journal, 67, 983-995.

Woodland, B., & Woodland, L. (2003). The reverse favourite-longshot bias and market efficiency in Major League Baseball: An update. Bulletin of Economic Research, 55, 113-124.

Zuber, R., Gandar, J., & Bowers, B. (1985). Beating the spread: Testing the efficiency of the gambling market for National Football League games. Journal of Political Economy, 93, 800-806.

Brad R. Humphreys [1], Rodney J. Paul [2], and Andrew P. Weinbach [3]

[1] West Virginia University

[2] Syracuse University

[3] Coastal Carolina University

Endnotes

(1) Gandar, et al. (2002), issued a correction to the methods used for calculating a unit bet.

(2) Dare and Dennis (2011) are not the first to use this sort of model. A similar model was also used by Cain, et al. (2000), and Ioannidis and Peel (2005).

(3) For the period 2005-2010, the Indianapolis Colts received 72% of the bets on average as the away team, the highest percentage of bets for any NFL team. In 2011, however, without Peyton Manning, the Colts received only 43.75% as the away team and 31.85% as the home team.

(4) The percentage of winning bets (WP) necessary to break even under the 11-for-10 rule is obtained by setting the expected value of the random variable, a gamble WP(10) + (1 - WP)(11), equal to zero (Zuber, Gandar, & Bowers, 1985).

Rodney J. Paul is a professor in the Department of Sport Management at Syracuse University where he specializes in the economics and finance of sport, macroeconomics, and international economics. He has presented at conferences nationally and internationally, and his work has appeared in a number of journals and book chapters on sport economics and business.

Andrew P. Weinbach is a professor in the E. Craig Wall Sr. College of Business Administration at Coastal Carolina University. His research interests include applied microeconomics, sports economics (patterns of consumer interest in live sporting events, including fan attendance, television ratings, and betting participation), industrial organization, and financial economics.
Table 1: Mean Forecast Errors--NFL Betting Market--2005-2011 Seasons

Characteristic    Number of     Mean forecast   t-statistic
                 observations       error

Favorites            1791          0.7549        3.2456 **
Underdogs            1791          0.3881         1.7601
Home team            1793          0.5290        2.3102 *
Away team            1793          0.5982        2.6695 *
Home favorites       1196          0.5355         1.8821
Away underdogs       1196          0.3037         1.1427
Away favorites       595           1.1958        2.9613 **
Home underdogs       595           0.5504         1.4276

Table 2: Mean Forecast Errors--NFL Betting Market--5-Year
Intervals

Years              Away       Home underdogs
                 favorites

MFE 1985-1989     -0.7964         0.7254
                 (-1.4972)       (1.3146)
MFE 1990-1994     0.1561          0.6445
                 (0.3216)        (1.4000)
MFE 1995-1999     0.1485          1.4550
                 (0.2881)      (2.9201 **)
MFE 2000-2004     0.2906          0.1819
                 (0.8093)        (0.5321)
MFE 2005-2011     1.1958          0.5504
                (2.9613 **)      (1.4276)

Table 3: Average Betting Percentages 2005-2011

Situation        % bet on   % bet on   % bet on   % bet on
                   home       away       over      under

All games         47.55%     52.45%     64.94%     35.06%
Home favorites    56.94%     43.06%     64.88%     35.12%
Away favorites    28.72%     71.28%     65.06%     34.94%

Table 4: Sides and Totals Regression Results--NFL 2005-2011

                      Dependent                     Dependent
                      variable:                     variable:
                    Percentage bet     Totals     Percentage bet
Sides regression     on favorite     regression      on over

Intercept             48.98 ***      Intercept      23.63 ***
                       (92.32)                       (10.99)
Absolute value of      1.30 ***        Total         0.98 ***
  point spread         (18.64)                       (19.32)
Away favorite         16.25 ***
  dummy                (29.43)

Table 5: NFL Team Betting Percentages and Average Point
Spreads Home and Away 2005-2011

                                             Difference
                         % bet      % bet      (home
Team                    as away    as home     -away)

New England Patriots     69.43      59.96      -9.46
Indianapolis Colts       67.93      57.79      -10.14
Pittsburgh Steelers      64.32      55.61      -8.71
San Diego Chargers       62.34      56.30      -6.04
Green Bay Packers        61.96      55.68      -6.29
New Orleans Saints       61.86      56.15      -5.71
Philadelphia Eagles      60.36      50.43      -9.93
New York Giants          60.11      56.88      -3.23
Cincinnati Bengals       58.88      48.18      -10.70
Dallas Cowboys           58.77      51.30      -7.46
Baltimore Ravens         56.27      50.50      -5.77
Atlanta Falcons          56.07      49.95      -6.13
Tennessee Titans         52.88      46.29      -6.59
Chicago Bears            52.63      49.73      -2.89
Denver Broncos           52.07      47.46      -4.61
New York Jets            50.27      46.95      -3.32
Carolina Panthers        49.57      48.54      -1.04
Minnesota Vikings        48.52      46.91      -1.61
Jacksonville Jaguars     48.38      44.70      -3.68
Seattle Seahawks         47.66      45.84      -1.82
Kansas City Chiefs       47.14      46.38      -0.77
Arizona Cardinals        47.07      43.66      -3.41
Houston Texans           46.96      45.39      -1.57
San Francisco 49ers      46.16      41.79      -4.38
St. Louis Rams           45.93      39.43      -6.50
Detroit Lions            45.23      39.70      -5.54
Tampa Bay Buccaneers     44.79      42.46      -2.32
Washington Redskins      44.77      40.32      -4.45
Miami Dolphins           43.95      39.27      -4.68
Buffalo Bills            43.79      42.09      -1.70
Cleveland Browns         41.39      36.84      -4.55
Oakland Raiders          41.16      38.91      -2.25

                                           Difference
                                             (home
                       Average   Average     point
                        point     point      spread
                       spread    spread      -away
                       as away   as home     point
Team                    team      team      spread)

New England Patriots   -3.438    -9.116      -5.68
Indianapolis Colts     -1.375    -5.893      -4.52
Pittsburgh Steelers    -2.259    -6.955      -4.70
San Diego Chargers     -2.036    -7.500      -5.46
Green Bay Packers       0.223    -4.616      -4.84
New Orleans Saints     -0.518    -4.682      -4.16
Philadelphia Eagles    -0.205    -5.027      -4.82
New York Giants         0.218    -4.868      -5.09
Cincinnati Bengals      2.777    -1.830      -4.61
Dallas Cowboys         -0.759    -6.402      -5.64
Baltimore Ravens        0.429    -5.089      -5.52
Atlanta Falcons         2.080    -3.045      -5.13
Tennessee Titans        2.955    -2.098      -5.05
Chicago Bears           1.848    -3.250      -5.10
Denver Broncos          2.241    -3.045      -5.29
New York Jets           3.170    -2.545      -5.71
Carolina Panthers       3.089    -2.036      -5.13
Minnesota Vikings       2.429    -3.188      -5.62
Jacksonville Jaguars    3.063    -2.491      -5.55
Seattle Seahawks        3.107    -2.688      -5.79
Kansas City Chiefs      5.714     0.277      -5.44
Arizona Cardinals       3.652    -1.643      -5.29
Houston Texans          4.116    -1.214      -5.33
San Francisco 49ers     5.750    -0.063      -5.81
St. Louis Rams          6.196     3.027      -3.17
Detroit Lions           6.866     1.911      -4.96
Tampa Bay Buccaneers    4.429    -0.625      -5.05
Washington Redskins     3.571    -0.804      -4.38
Miami Dolphins          4.464    -0.696      -5.16
Buffalo Bills           5.732     0.563      -5.17
Cleveland Browns        6.768     1.580      -5.19
Oakland Raiders         7.804     1.911      -5.89

Table 6: Betting Simulations--NFL 2005-2011

                 Favorites   Underdogs   Pushes

Home favorites      570         594        32
Away favorites      298         279        18
All games           868         873        50

                   Overs      Unders     Pushes

All games           894         852        45

                  Favorite     Underdog
                    win          win
                 percentage   percentage

Home favorites     48.97%       51.03%
Away favorites     51.65%       48.35%
All games          49.84%       50.14%

                  Over win    Under win
                 percentage   percentage

All games          51.20%       48.80%
联系我们|关于我们|网站声明
国家哲学社会科学文献中心版权所有