Performance, salaries, and contract length: empirical evidence from German soccer.
Frick, Bernd
The recent transfers of Christiano Ronaldo from Manchester United,
and of Ricardo Izecson dos Santos Leite (Kaka) from Associazione Calcio
Milan to Real Madrid--as well as the increasing financial problems of
many of the top teams in the big five European leagues--have again
increased the public's attention for the global football
players' labor market. Therefore, the paper addresses two
important, and highly contested, issues: player remuneration and
contract duration (players are usually considered as overpaid and poorly
motivated. Using two different unbalanced panels from the German
Bundesliga league that cover six and 13 consecutive seasons respectively
(1997-98 to 2002-03 and 1995-96 to 2007-08), I show, first, that the
variance in player salaries can be explained, to a large extent, by the
variance in individual performance. That is, salaries can be explained
by career games played and games played last season, previous and recent
international appearances, and goals scored. Moreover, player position,
leadership skills, and region of birth clearly matter as well. The
impact of these characteristics varies across the salary distribution.
Second, I find robust evidence that player performance--measured
primarily, but not exclusively, by a subjective overall player rating
from Kicker, a highly respected soccer magazine-significantly increases
in the last year of the contract. In addition, the variance in player
performance is significantly lower in the last year of the contract.
These findings suggest that moral hazard is a widespread phenomenon,
even in professional soccer.
Keywords: salaries, contract duration, pay determination, moral
hazard, soccer Introduction
The development of player salaries in professional football in
Germany The escalating and/or skyrocketing salaries of professional
football players have only recently become a highly controversial issue
in Germany. Perhaps surprisingly, this has not always been the case:
When, in the summer of 1954, the members of the German national team
returned home after their glorious victory in the World Cup final
against Hungary, each player received a gratification of 2,000 DM--about
six months' pay of a male full-time employee (Muller-Jentsch,
1989). By that time, the enormous amount was considered by most people
to be a well-deserved recognition for an outstanding performance.
The public opinion, however, changed gradually. On July 28, 1962,
when the representatives of the 21 different regional football
associations in Germany agreed to introduce a single first division,
they also introduced a minimum and a maximum salary--the former being
250 DM per month and the latter 1,200 DM per month. (1) Moreover, the
maximum transfer fee was set at 50,000 DM, of which a maximum of 5,000
DM could be paid to the player; all of these caps were finally abandoned
in 1972. The salaries of the top players soon started to rise: In 1966,
Uwe Seeler--at the time, he was captain of the national team--earned
50,000 DM, while midfielder Gunther Netzer was paid 100,000 DM already
in 1972. Five years later, top-scorer Gerd Muller earned 500,000 DM per
season. In 1987, Rudi Voller was paid 1.1 Mio. DM, and in 1992, Andreas
Moller made 1.7 Mio. DM. Upon his return from the Italian Serie A to the
Bundesliga in 1995, Lothar Matthaus was paid 2.5 Mio. DM: An amount that
he more than tripled until 1998. (2) In 2001, Stefan Effenberg, as well
as Oliver Kahn, were paid 9.5 Mio. DM (Sonnenberg, 2002).
This development, which can mainly be attributed to the development
of the television revenue generated by the clubs, has, for most of the
time, been accompanied by public discussion about the adequacy of player
salaries. In addition, it has recently even attracted the attention of a
number of politicians. Since the mid-1960s, the increasing liabilities
of some first division clubs were considered as early signals of the
forthcoming "collapse" of professional football due to
"excessive" player and head coach salaries (Die Zeit, May 17,
1968; Der Spiegel, January 22, 1968). This discussion went on for
decades and culminated shortly before Christmas 2007 when Norbert
Lammert, the president of the German Bundestag--the nation's
parliament--released the following statement:
"I am particularly annoyed by the salary explosion that we
have recently experienced in professional sport in general and in soccer
in particular ... This is something I cannot understand at all"
(Onabrucker Zeitung, December 23, 2007).
This caused the president of the German Football Association, Theo
Zwanziger, to respond with the following statement:
"From a 'moral' point of view, the salaries of many
professional soccer players are too high-as are the incomes of most
actors and some top managers" (Suddeutsche Zeitung, January 9,
2008).
Given the steadily increasing ticket sales and merchandising
revenues, it is hardly surprising that football fans seem to be quite
relaxed with regard to the level and the development of player salaries.
In an online opinion poll that was started shortly after the interviews
were published, the daily newspaper Die Welt asked its readers whether
politicians should be concerned about the development of player salaries
in professional football. The results are shown in Table 1.
The fans' position is nicely summarized in the following quote
by sports journalist Oskar Beck:
"We football fans are a rather strange species. We complain
when our heroes earn enormous amounts of money, but at the same time we
readily accept higher ticket prices if this enables our favorite club to
sign yet another top-scorer. Moreover, we are prepared to pay 19.90
[euro] for the memoirs of Stefan Effenberg and the diaries of Lothar
Matthaus as if it were the most recent works of Nobel laureates Heinrich
Boll and Gunter Grass" (Die Welt, December 30, 2007).
In summary, it appears that fans have fewer problems with the
escalating and skyrocketing salaries than politicians and journalists
seem to expect. From an economic point of view, however, the question is
not whether the salaries are adequate or excessive, but whether the
observable variation in player remuneration can be explained by
differences in individual performance and the clubs' ability to
pay, which, in turn, is a function of past and recent sporting success,
market size, and tradition. These and related questions will be answered
in Section 2 of the following paper.
The development of contract duration in professional football in
Germany
The issue of contract duration is as contested as the remuneration
of players. Dragoslav Stepanovic, former head coach of Eintracht
Frankfurt, argued the following in an interview in the summer of 1992
when his team finished third in the Bundesliga--a position the club has
not since accomplished again:
"In principle, player contracts should not exceed three
months. In case of excellent performance such contracts can always be
extended for another three months."
Norbert Pflippen--a well-known player-agent who represented former
star player Christian Ziege by the time the young man was 21 years old
and had just signed a five-year contract with Bayern Munich--reasoned
similarly:
"An ambitious young player should never sign a long-term
contract. He must always be convinced that within one or two years he
will again be underpaid. Having the opportunity to renegotiate is
crucial."
Thus, not only sports fans, but head coaches and player agents also
seem to believe that players can strategically vary their
performance--an impression that is consistent with principal agent
theory. One of the major insights of this theory is that properly
designed incentive contracts will align the interests of a rational and
opportunistic agent with those of a principal not completely informed
about the talent and the abilities of the agent. (3) Explicit
incentives, such as performance-related pay, are not the only motivating
factor. Workers with fixed-term contracts, for example, have incentives
to vary effort at different points of their contract cycle--that is, to
increase effort just before a new contract is signed and to reduce it
after a lucrative multiyear contract is secured. The duration-related
incentives create a considerable moral hazard problem, a topic which has
been empirically examined only on occasion. (4)
Although the issue that will be dealt with in the second part of my
paper (see Section 3 below) is of critical importance for the managers
of professional soccer teams as well as the managers of
"normal" firms, most of the available studies rely on data
from the sports industry. This is not surprising because individual
performance can be measured easily and the data is readily available to
the researcher:
"Professional sport offers a unique opportunity for labor
market research. There is no other research setting than sports where we
know the name, face, and life history of every production worker and
supervisor in the industry. Total compensation packages and performance
statistics for each individual are widely available, and we have a
complete data set of worker-employer matches over the career of each
production worker and supervisor in the industry ... Moreover,
professional sports leagues have experienced major changes in labor
market rules and structure ... creating interesting natural experiments
that offer opportunities for analysis" (Kahn, 2000, p. 75).
Thus, Section 3 of my paper will empirically analyze the behavioral
consequences of short- versus long-term contracts. The main questions to
be addressed are as follows: Is "shirking"--as alleged by fans
and sports journalists--really an issue in professional football?
Second, does this kind of undesired behavior have an impact on the
sporting performance of the clubs? Most of the available studies answer
these questions by comparing a player's performance in the first
season after he has signed a long-term contract with that same
player's performance in the last year of his old contract. Given
the obvious problems of this approach, I take a different route: I look
at changes in players' performance as they approach renegotiation.
That is, I compare their performance in the last year of a particular
contract to the performance in the season(s) before that contract
expires. The assumption here is that, if performance improves in the
last year of the old contract, it is most likely the result of a
deliberate change in behavior. If, on the other hand, performance
deteriorates in the first year of the new, long-term contract, this
could be due to a number of different factors, such as stochastic variations in performance and/or random shocks that are beyond the
player's control.
The remuneration of professional football players
Theory. In the absence of labor market restrictions--such as salary
caps, reserve clauses, and/or draft rules--players will be paid
according to their marginal product; that is, the wage an individual
player receives is a function of his contribution to the team's
revenues which is, in turn, influenced by his talent and experience on
the one hand and his "fan appeal" on the other hand
(Rottenberg, 1956). However, since the clubs differ with respect to
their drawing potential--there are small market and large market
teams--they also differ with respect to their ability to pay. For
example, the marginal product of Arjen Robben or Franck Ribery is
certainly higher in Munich than it is in Freiburg or in Mainz. However,
since it rests on a number of critical assumptions--such as player
mobility, complete information, and risk neutrality--the neoclassical
model of wage determination has often been rejected, not only by sports
fans, but by some highly respected economists as well: "... the
elementary classical model presents a very poor description of
employment relations in advanced economies" (Milgrom & Roberts,
1992, p. 329).
However, the problems that are characteristic for most-if not
all-"real life" labor contracts (e.g., information
asymmetries, incompleteness, or importance of implicit elements) are
clearly less important in professional team sports. Here, an individual
player's performance can easily be measured, "shirking"
can be detected at low cost, effort and talent can be evaluated, not
only by a player's current club but by other teams as well. It is,
therefore, plausible to assume that in the German Bundesliga-as in other
professional team sports leagues with an unregulated labor
market-players are paid mainly according to their past and recent
performance and their ability to attract fans (5). Thus, the term
marginal product is used here to describe the value of an individual
player's contribution to the spectacle (i.e., the matches in which
he appears). (6)
Moreover, professions in which talent is highly valued by consumers
are usually characterized by a highly skewed distribution of earnings:
Small differences in talent translate into large differences in pay
(Rosen, 1981). Player reputation attracts additional spectators;
however, advances in technology also facilitate the reproduction of
matches at low cost. Together, these two effects lead to a considerable
expansion of the market. In general, players are neither completely
homogenous nor completely specialized. This, in turn, creates a
situation of bilateral monopoly in which players and teams share a
surplus or economic rent. Only a few players who are sufficiently
differentiated can shift surpluses (i.e., rents) completely into
salaries; these players will tend to be the superstars of their sports.
Previous Evidence. To the best of my knowledge, only four studies
have been published in English so far that seek to identify the
determinants of player salaries in professional football. Lucifora and
Simmons (2003) use information on 533 outfield players from the Italian
Serie A and Serie B at the beginning of the 1995-1996 season (i.e., a
cross section). They find that individual performance--measured
primarily by the number of games played and goals scored--has a
statistically significant and economically relevant influence on
salaries. Moreover, earnings are highly convex in the individual's
career goal-scoring rate and the assist rate, suggesting the existence
of a considerable superstar effect. Lehmann and Schulze (2008) use 651
player-year-observations from the German Bundesliga in the seasons
1998-1999 and 1999-2000. Their performance measures also have the
expected, and statistically significant, influence on salaries.
Surprisingly, however, media presence has a positive, but declining,
influence. This suggests decreasing returns to popularity--a finding
that is difficult to reconcile with the concept of superstardom (7).
Feess, Frick, and Muhlheusser (2004) use a sample of players appearing
in the German Bundesliga in the period 1994-1995 to 1999-2000 (n = 604
observations). They found that, above and beyond the traditional
performance measures--such as games played, goals scored, and
international appearances--contract length also has a positive and
statistically significant impact on a player's annual wage. They
also found that this effect has become much stronger in the "Post
Bosman Era"--that is, after the transfer of property rights from
the clubs to the players, a respective decision induced by the European
Court of Justice in December 1995. The finding that contract length and
annual salary are complements, rather than substitutes, again suggests
that superstar effects are of particular importance in the pay
determination process. Finally, Kuethe and Motamed (2010) use data on
193 athletes who played in the MLS in 2007 and were under league
contracts at the start of the 2008 season in order to identify the
impact of the designated player rule and all-star game participation on
individual salaries. Controlling for player age, experience, goals,
assists, and region of origin, both variables are found to have a
statistically significant impact on remuneration. This suggests that
superstardom is an important determinant of player salaries.
In summary, these papers show that salaries of professional
athletes are more than just a random occurrence, that systematic factors
determine these salaries to a large extent, and that these systematic
factors--such as age, experience, and performance--are very similar to
those found in other occupations. Where sports teams differ in structure
of earnings is in the distribution of salaries; that is, they are even
more highly skewed than in standard occupations. In addition, sports
teams apply more stringent selection procedures into occupations. For
example, poor performance by a player results in being dropped from team
squad and very quickly being discarded; there are high levels of
mobility within the industry (e.g., between teams) and into and out of
the industry, with shorter careers than in most occupations. (8)
Testable Hypotheses. The observable variance in player salaries is
primarily due to the variance in talent and performance:
1. Player salaries will increase with performance (e.g., league
appearances or goals), experience (i.e., age), and popularity (e.g.,
appearances in the national team). (9)
2. The most recent performance (i.e., in the last season) will have
a greater impact on player salaries than previous career performance.
Moreover, the club's differing ability to pay--which, in turn,
is a function of the size of the respective market, the club's
history, and its sporting performance--will also affect player salaries
significantly.
The structure and development of player salaries in the German
Bundesliga
Available Data. My primary source of information is Kicker, a
highly respected soccer magazine that offers market valuations of
players assessed at the beginning of a season for 13 consecutive years
(1995-1996 to 2007-2008) as a proxy for undisclosed salary; the salary
remains private and confidential not only in Germany but in the rest of
in Europe too. I am confident of the reliability of these proxies for
several reasons. First, the correlation between Kicker salary figures
and those from another reliable source (see http://www.transfermarkt.de)
is high at .75 (Torgler, Schmidt, & Frey, 2006). Second, the player
valuations in Kicker magazine have been compiled by a stable team of
experts who have established consistent practice over a long period. I,
therefore, interpret the players' market values as published by
Kicker as particularly reliable. Aggregating the individual market
values across teams, and dividing these by a constant factor of 1.5,
results in the aggregated wage bills of the 18 teams in the Bundesliga
as published in the annual reports of the German Football Association
for the period between 1996-2007. Furthermore, the correlation between
Kicker player valuations and a subset of actual salary data obtained
from the Bundesliga has been found to be high at .80 (Frick, 2003).
The size of my sample is quite large with 6,147
player-year-observations for 1,993 different players who were assigned
player characteristics, including number of career games played, number
of games played last season, number of career goals scored, number of
goals scored last season, number of career international appearances,
number of international appearances last season, team captain (dummy),
position (a set of three dummies), region of birth (six dummies), and
previous league. In addition, they
[FIGURE 1 OMITTED]
[FIGURE 2 OMITTED]
Descriptive Evidence
It appears from Figure 1 that average player salaries have
increased from 550,000 [euro] in 1995-1996 to about 1.3 Mio. [euro] in
the 2007-2008 season. Interestingly, the standard deviation constantly
oscillates around the mean, suggesting that the dispersion of player
salaries has remained more or less constant over time. (10) The decline
in player salaries in the 2003-2004 and 2004-2005 seasons has to be
attributed to the insolvency of the Kirch group--the company that had
bought the television rights for a record amount of 695 Mio. DM per
year, starting with the 2000-2001 season. Moreover, player salaries
differ considerably by position: In the 2007-2008 season, goalkeepers
earned on average about 900,000 [euro], while forwards were paid an
average of 1.45 Mio. [euro] (see Figure 2). The salaries of defenders
and midfielders are higher than those of goalkeepers but lower than
those of forwards.
Although statistically significant (2007-2008: F = 3.08, p <
.05), these averages hide considerable variation within the different
groups of players. Particularly in the case of goalkeepers, the standard
deviation of individual salaries--and, therefore, the corresponding
coefficient of variation--is rather high (see Table A1). Perhaps also
surprising is the fact that the wage premium of forwards seems to
decline over the years. Whether this is due to changes in the supply of
forwards (relative to other positions) or to changes in the quality of
all players under contract (relative to other positions), remains to be
seen.
Econometric Findings
I start with the estimation of an ordinary least squares (OLS)
model with robust standard errors, a random-effects (RE) model, and a
median regression (MR) model. (11) I then present the findings of
various quantile regressions (i.e., .10, .25, .75, and .90) with
bootstrapped standard errors (200 repetitions). The results are
comparable to those obtained from OLS as well as RE- and MR-estimation.
However, few of the coefficients remain constant over the percentiles.
The model to be estimated is of the following general form:
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]
where AGE: Player age
GPL: Number of appearances in Bundesliga in last season
CGP: Number of career appearances in Bundesliga
IAL: International appearances last season
IAP: International appearances in career
GSL: Goals scored last season in Bundesliga
CGS: Career goals scored in Bundesliga
CAP: Captain of team (0 = no; 1 = yes)
FDA: Previous team in first division abroad (0 = no; 1 = yes)
PD: Vector of position dummies (ref.: goalkeeper)
RD: Vector of region of birth dummies (ref.: Germany)
TD: Vector of team dummies (ref.: Borussia Moenchengladbach)
YD: Vector of year dummies (ref.: 2001/2002)
Thus, my models distinguish between a player's career
performance and his most recent (i.e., last season) performance. The
most recent performance--measured by inter alia, the number of games
played, the number of international appearances, and the number of goals
scored--is, of course not included in the career performance (the
results of OLS, RE, and MR estimations are displayed in Table 2 below).
(12)
Most studies of pay determination in football rely on the standard
conditional expectations model. However, the focus on the conditional
mean is likely to misrepresent the relationship between pay and
performance, if there are differences in the returns to performance
along the conditional distribution. Several studies of salary
determination in other professional (e.g., North American) team sports
use quantile regression estimation since log salary measures tend to
have even greater kurtosis values than in standard occupations (Berri
& Simmons, 2009; Hamilton, 1997; Leeds & Kowalewski, 2001;
Reilly & Witt, 2007; Simmons & Berri, 2009; Vincent &
Eastman, 2009). OLS salary regressions are sensitive to the presence of
outliers and can be inefficient if the log salary measure has a highly
non-normal distribution, as is often the case in professional team
sports. In contrast, quantile regression estimates are more robust.
Presence of non-normality is indicated by a large kurtosis value and
D'Agostino and colleagues' (1990) test is performed by the
sktest command in Stata 10.1. In my panel, the p-value for the test
statistic of the null hypothesis is .000, kurtosis does not depart from
the value associated with a normal distribution; hence, my log salary
data depart from normality, a result that is similar to those found in
some studies of North American sports (e.g., Berri & Simmons, 2009
study on the National Football League).
One further advantage of quantile regression is that it facilitates
examination of salary returns to characteristics at different points in
the salary distribution (Buchinsky, 1998; Koenker & Bassett, 1978).
That is, I can investigate the impacts of the available performance
measures at any quantile of the salary distribution, not just the
conditional mean. Moreover, the quantile regression approach is
semi-parametric in that it avoids assumptions about the parametric distribution of the regression error term, an especially suitable
feature where the data are heteroskedastic as in my case.
To ensure robustness of standard errors, I bootstrap with 200
replications. I report quantile regression estimates in Table 3. My main
findings can be summarized as follows (see Tables 2 and 3):
* First, age, career games played, international appearances over
the entire career, and international appearances in the last season all
have a statistically significant non-linear influence on salaries. The
statistically significant coefficient of the cubic term suggests
existence of superstar effects (Lucifora & Simmons, 2003).
* A strange result is obtained for career goals scored: The
coefficient of the linear and the cubic term are significant and
negative, while the coefficient of the squared term is positive and
significant. (13)
* Second, goals scored last season, as well as games played last
season, have a significantly positive and strictly linear influence on
annual income; that is, there seem to be no decreasing returns to either
goals scored or games played.
* Comparing the returns to career performance and to performance in
the last season, it appears that historical merits do not count very
much; that is, recent performance is--as expected--far more important
than past performance.
* Third, defenders, midfielders, and forwards earn significantly
higher salaries than goalkeepers. The premiums for these positions,
however, differ considerably across estimations: The effect is most
pronounced in the RE estimation and weakest in the MR model.
* Fourth, region of birth is also important: Players from South
America and Western Europe receive a considerable pay premium while
players from the rest of the world are neither favored nor discriminated
against. (14) The pay premium for South Americans and West Europeans is
not surprising: Other things equal, players from these regions attract
larger crowds (Wilson & Ying, 2003) and contribute more to
merchandising revenues (Kalter, 1999).
* The longer a player has been active in his current club, the
lower the c.p. of his annual salary. Whether this is the result of an
adverse selection process (e.g., better players are traded while less
talented players remain with their old club), or whether some players
are willing to forfeit money to stay at home, is not yet clear. (15)
* Finally, team captains and players who moved abroad from a first
division club to Germany are paid a significant premium too. As for team
captains, this is obviously due to leadership skills that are required
for the job and that are, therefore, particularly rewarded in the market
(Kuhn & Weinberger, 2005).
Few of the coefficients retain their magnitude across the different
quantiles of the salary distribution:16
* Generally, the maximum income is reached at an age of about 27 or
28 years. The age-earnings profile, however, is much flatter for the
players with the highest incomes.
* The impact of games played last season, as well as career games
played on annual salaries, is much stronger for players at the bottom of
the income distribution.
* International appearances--past as well as current--seem to have
a much stronger influence on the salaries of the players at the top of
the income distribution.
* Goals scored--past as well as current--tenure with the current
club, and being a team captain seem to have a more or less constant
impact on player salaries (i.e., the coefficients are quite similar for
the different quantiles).
* The coefficients of the position dummies change considerably
across the income distribution, indicating that goalkeepers are the real
superstars in the business. (17)
* The pay premium enjoyed by players from South America increases
across the pay distribution, while the premium for players from Western
Europe decreases. (18,19)
Contract Duration and Player Performance
What can we learn from the available literature?
The common perception among sports fans is that players become lazy
and expend less effort once they have signed a long-term contract. The
available evidence (summarized in Table 4 below) is less clear: While
some of the studies find robust evidence supporting the shirking
hypothesis, others do not find any sign of such behavior. However, even
if no shirking can be detected, opportunistic behavior may well be an
issue. First, reputation considerations may keep players from reducing
their effort levels. In this case, only a player who knows that he has
recently signed his last contract will have an incentive to withhold effort. Anticipating such behavior, managers will refrain from giving
long-term contracts to older workers. Second, many player contracts will
include incentive clauses tying individual and/or team performance to
compensation. This, in turn, is likely to result in a higher wage bill
because risk-averse players may expect a premium in exchange for their
readiness to accept contingent pay. (20)
Summarizing, agency theory identifies two different options for
teams to control moral hazard. First, monitoring can reduce information
asymmetries, and second, incentive contracts may be used to mitigate the
underlying motivation deficit. Since monitoring is often rather costly
and difficult to implement--especially with regard to the player's
behavior outside the game--teams tend to at least partly reward their
players depending on the output produced, assuming that measuring inputs
is more or less impossible. However, outcomes are not fully under the
control of the agent and, at the same time, risk aversion on behalf of
the player limits the team's ability to use output-related pay
only. Thus, an efficient contract balances the costs of risk bearing
against the benefits of improved incentives. (21)
Data, estimation and empirical findings
The sample used in this study includes all regular players (22) who
were under contract with any of the teams in the first German soccer
division (n = 760) obtained from various annual editions of Kicker, the
leading soccer magazine in the country. Altogether, the sample includes
1,866 player-year-observations from the 1998-1999 through the 2002-2003
seasons. The subjective performance measures used here are school grades
ranging from 1 (exceptional) to 6 (very poor) and summarize a
player's effort and contribution to his team's performance.
The number of graded appearances varies between 7,113 and 7,239 per
season. This means that, on average, between 23 and 24 graded players
appear during each match--a grade is awarded only if the player spends
at least 30 minutes on the pitch. Due to the definition chosen in this
paper, approximately 72% of the players are considered regular--recall
that these are players with nine and more appearances per season--and
28% are considered back-up players with less than nine appearances. The
number of regular players varies less than the number of back-up players
(n = 301-321; n = 110-154). This is mainly due to the fact that in
2000-2001, two of the three relegated teams increased their roster sizes
considerably during the season. Since regular players by definition
appear significantly more often than the back-up players, more than 93%
of the graded appearances (i.e., those of a minimum duration of 30 min)
were by regular players. Two hundred and eighty-six (37.6%) of the
players appear in my dataset for only one season and disappear again
thereafter due to a transfer to a lower division club or a transfer to a
club abroad, or because the player's club had been relegated at the
end of the season. On the other hand, 106 players (14.0%) managed to
survive in the Bundesliga for at least five seasons. (23)
[FIGURE 3 OMITTED]
Turning to the contract variable, it appears that 24% of the
observations are in their last contract year (see Table 5 and Figure 3).
About 34% have one year remaining on their contracts and 27% have two
seasons remaining. Since it is plausible to assume that, in the case of
a multiyear contract, a player's incentives to perform well will
increase linearly, the estimations presented below use the number of
remaining contract years as an exogenous variable; a censored contract
variable with any duration of more than two years was recoded as two.
The implicit assumption is that, with two years remaining on the
contract, players gradually start to deliver better performances in
order to reach their optimal bargaining position in the last season
before the contract expires.
The estimated models are of the following general form:
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]
where PP: player performance in season t [(rag = relative average
grade; see Figure A2), (apg = average player grade; see Figure A3), (vpp
= variance of player performance; see Figure A4)] (24)
CS: contract status in season t [remaining contract duration
(estimates 1.1, 2.1, and 3.1); censored remaining contract duration
(estimates 1.2, 2.2, and 3.2); last contract year (dummy; 0 = no; 1 =
yes; estimates 1.3, 2.3, and 3.3)]
GS: goals scored in season t
RC: number of red cards in season t
YC: number of yellow cards in season t
SP: semiprofessional (dummy; 0 = no; 1 = yes)
CGP: career games played in Bundesliga
CGP2: career games squared
AGE: player age
[AGE.sup.2]: age squared
INT: appearance in national team (dummy; 0 = no; 1 = yes)
TCCB: team change during Christmas break (dummy; 0 = no; 1 = yes)
DEF: defender (dummy; 0 = no; 1 = yes)
MID: midfielder (dummy; 0 = no; 1 = yes)
FOR: forward (dummy; 0 = no; 1 = yes)
ATG: average team grade
In models 1.1-1.3, the dependent variable is the individual
player's average grade; in models 2.1-2.3, it is the relative
individual average corrected by the average grade of the player's
team. Given the grade system used, higher values of the dependent
variable denote a weak or even a poor performance. (25) The expected
sign of the contract status variable is, therefore, positive in
estimates 1.1, 2.1, and 3.1 as well as in 1.2, 2.2, and 3.2, and
negative in estimates 1.3, 2.3, and 3.3.
1. The higher the remaining duration of a player's contract,
the poorer his performance will be and the higher the variance in his
performance.
2. The performance will significantly improve and the variance will
be significantly lower in the last year of the contract.
Looking at the control variables (see Tables 6-8), it appears that
the number of goals scored, and the number of yellow cards per season,
have a significantly positive influence on player performance--recall
the worse the performance, the higher the average grade. (26) Player age
and experience--measured by the number of career games played--have the
expected nonlinear impact on performance while being a member of the
national team, the number of red cards per season, and the position
dummies are--by and large--statistically insignificant. Perhaps
surprisingly, semiprofessionals, and players who have been traded over
the Christmas break, perform significantly better than otherwise
comparable players without these characteristics--perhaps expectations
are lower in these cases and players are, therefore, graded more
generously.
With regard to the variance of player performance, the picture is
slightly different (see Table 8). First, the number of goals scored and
the number of red cards increase the variation, as does membership in
the national team. Second, none of the coefficients of the other control
variables--apart from one of the position dummies--comes close to
statistical significance. Third, the higher the number of appearances in
the last season, the lower the variation in a player's performance.
Turning to the coefficients of the contract status variable, it
appears that, irrespective of its concrete specification, convincing
evidence in favor of the shirking hypothesis can be found. That is, the
shorter the remaining duration of a player's contract, the better
his performance. Moreover, the consistency in a player's
performance increases as he approaches renegotiation. Depending on the
specification of the model, a player's performance increases by
2%-3% per year as his contract elapses. This is by no means trivial:
Players are often monitored day-by-day, not only by their coaches, but
by millions of sports fans as well. Such an increase in performance is
certainly surprising as it mirrors a player's possibilities to
increase his effort as he expects to benefit from being more devoted to
his job.
Equally interesting in the context of the paper is yet another
question: Do these contract-related changes in individual performance
affect team performance? If the performance measures used in the paper
are valuable to the teams, we should observe team outcomes to follow the
individual player's performance (i.e., looking to a rise when many
players are in the last year of their contracts and to a fall when many
have signed new multiyear contracts). The relevant literature has
identified several wedges that might exist between individual and team
performance. First, if only some valuable tasks are measurable,
incentive effects can lead players to misallocate resources toward the
measurable tasks and away from other, equally important ones (see
Holmstrom & Milgrom, 1991). Second, the readiness to cooperate may
suffer under some incentive structures; that is, if players are paid
according to the number of goals scored or the number of appearances
(see Baker, 1992). Finally, rational individuals might behave
opportunistically when individuals who reduce their effort levels cannot
be identified (see Holmstrom, 1982). While the latter problem is
unlikely to occur in professional team sports, the former two are
certainly worth investigation.
To examine whether changes in individual player performance
actually affect team performance, I estimate a fixed effects model with
the average team grade as the endogenous variable and the number of
points at the end of the season as the dependent variable. (27) Taking
into account that an individual player's performance improves
considerably in the last contract year, the potential improvement in the
team's performance can be easily calculated. On average, four
players are up for contract negotiations each season. If that figure
increases by two, the team will secure slightly more than one additional
point (i.e., a draw instead of a loss). If half of the roster--instead
of one quarter--is in the last contract year, the team will win two
additional points. (28) Given the usually close competition--in some of
the seasons under consideration, already one point more would have
resulted in either avoiding relegation (e.g., Karlsruhe in 1997-1998 and
Nuremberg in 1998-1999) or in qualification for a European cup
competition (e.g., Berlin in 1998-1999, Leverkusen in 2000-2001, Munich
in 2001-2002, and Dortmund in 2002-2003)--these marginal changes in
individual performance can have massive economic consequences for the
clubs affected.
Summary and Implications
Using two large longitudinal datasets from German professional
football, the paper demonstrates that first players are remunerated by
the market according to their innate talent and their performance, with
the most recent performance being far more important than the
performance delivered years ago. The OLS and the RE models explain more
than 60% of the observable variance in player salaries. This is quite
high and indicates that the available performance measures--although far
from ideal--are indeed well suited for the empirical analysis. The
quantile regressions, in turn, demonstrate that restricting the analysis
to the standard models is problematic insofar as the focus on the
conditional mean is likely to misrepresent the relationship between pay
and performance; this is because there are considerable differences in
the returns to performance along the conditional distribution. Second,
the paper finds clear evidence of increasing player effort over the
duration of individual contracts. Other things equal, a player's
performance increases by 2%-3% in the last year of the contract,
indicating that players can--and indeed do--vary their effort levels
strategically.
The analyses can, and will be, extended in different directions.
(29) First, the wage equations will be estimated separately for
goalkeepers, defenders, midfielders, and forwards as the determinants of
player wages likely differ across positions. (30) Re-estimating the
models for regular and substitute players can also reveal interesting
insights in the wage determination process. Moreover, the number of
international appearances, previous as well as recent, should be
weighted by the quality of the respective national team; that is, its
position in the annual ranking of International Federation of
Association Football (FIFA). Finally, estimating the models for
different sub-periods will possibly yield information about changes in
the wage determination process over time.
Second, the contract models will be extended too. First, annual
salaries can be included in the estimations to control for unobserved
heterogeneity among players. Second, young and old players clearly have
different incentives; therefore, it is necessary to include a variable
in the estimation that interacts the dummy for last year of contract
with player age. Perhaps even more important is the fact that player
contracts are of a rolling nature; that is, they are very often renewed
before the old one is about to expire. Thus, the timing of renewal of a
contract should also be included in the refined estimations as an
additional explanatory variable. Finally, the question whether contract
length and annual salaries are complements or substitutes needs to be
addressed too (Link & Yosifov, 2011).
Clearly, current as well as proposed policy interventions in the
now globalized football players' labor market would benefit from
better contextual empirical evidence on the economic mechanisms that
influence current practices in professional sports. Hence, future
analyses should provide empirical evidence on how sports labor markets
function economically, using this evidence to predict the likely
consequences of proposed reforms. So far, an economic welfare analysis
of effects of sports policies has been largely absent from recent
debate, which tends to be dominated by specialists in law, sociology,
and sports management. In particular, the need for some of the proposed
interventions, such as quotas on team composition, is best assessed by
asking whether the labor market for players is aalocatively efficiently,
and if not, why not? So far, an analysis of labor market efficiency in
professional sports has not been forthcoming due to data limitations.
Using the available, and assembling new data from football across
several countries, rigorous investigations of labor market structure,
conduct, and performance in professional sports are possible and
rewarding.
Appendix
[FIGURE A1 OMITTED]
[FIGURE A2 OMITTED]
[FIGURE A3 OMITTED]
[FIGURE A4 OMITTED]
Table A1: Means and standard deviations
Variable Mean Std. Dev. Min. Max.
Pay 909,014 889,577 17,043 10,000,000
Log(Pay) 13.31 .96 9.74 16.12
Games Played 13.27 12.62 0 34
Goals Scored 1.63 3.14 0 28
Intern. Appearances 1.43 3.08 0 25
Career Games 55.81 80.61 0 540
Career Goals 6.34 14.93 0 171
Career Intern. Appear. 7.54 16.56 0 130
Tenure 2.67 3.12 0 21
Captain .04 - 0 1
First Division Abroad .04 - 0 1
Goalkeeper .11 - 0 1
Defender .28 - 0 1
Midfielder .39 - 0 1
Forward .22 - 0 1
Germany .58 - 0 1
South America .05 - 0 1
North America .01 - 0 1
West Europe .13 - 0 1
East Europe .16 - 0 1
Africa .05 - 0 1
Asia/Australia .02 - 0 1
References
Baker, G. P. (1992). Incentive contracts and performance
measurement. Journal of Political Economy, 100, 598-614.
Berri, D. J., &, Simmons, R. (2009). Race and the evaluation of
signal callers in the National Football League. Journal of Sports
Economics, 10, 23-43.
Bryson, A., Frick, B., & Simmons, R. (2009). The returns to
scarce talent: Footedness and player remuneration in European football.
Unpublished manuscript.
Buchinsky, M. (1998). Recent advances in quantile regression
models: A practical guideline for empirical research. Journal of Human
Resources, 33, 88-126.
Cantor, A. (1990). Firm-specific training and contract length.
Economica, 57, 1-14.
Cantor, R. (1988). Work effort and contract length. Economica, 55,
343-353.
Conlin, M. (1999). Empirical tests of a separating equilibrium in
National Football League contract negotiations. Rand Journal of
Economics, 30, 289-304.
Conlin, M., & Emerson, P. M. (1999). Double moral hazard and a
multi-dimensional separating equilibrium in contract negotiations: A
study of the National Football League. Department of Economics, Cornell
University, mimeo.
D'Agostino, R. B., Balanger, A., & D'Agostino, R. B.,
Jr. (1990). A suggestion for using powerful and informative tests of
normality. American Statistician, 44, 316-327.
Dye, R. A. (1985). Optimal length of labor contracts. International
Economic Review, 26, 251-270.
Engellandt, A., & Riphahn, R. (2005). Temporary contracts and
employee effort. Labour Economics, 12, 281-299.
Feess, E., Frick, B., & Muhlheusser, G. (2004). Legal
restrictions on buyout fees: Theory and evidence from German soccer. IZA Discussion Paper No. 1180, Bonn.
Fernie, S., & Metcalf, D. (1999). It's not what you pay
it's the way that you pay it and that's what gets results:
Jockeys' pay and performance. Labour, 13, 385-411.
Fort, R., & Maxcy, J. (1998). Last-period problems in sports.
Department of Economics, Washington State University, mimeo.
Frick, B. (2003). Contest theory and sport. Oxford Review of
Economic Policy, 19, 512-529.
Frick, B. (2007). The football players' labor market:
Empirical evidence from the major European leagues. Scottish Journal of
Political Economy, 54, 422-446.
Frick, B., & Deutscher, C. (2009). Die Entlohnung von
Fuhrungsfahigkeiten: Evidenz aus dem professionellen Fufiball [The
returns to leadership skills: Evidence from professional football].
Department of Management, University of Paderborn, mimeo.
Frick, B., Dilger, A., & Prinz, J. (2002).
Arbeitsmarktregulierung und nachvertraglicher Oppor tunismus: Die
Verhaltensfolgen garantierter Handgeldzahlungen in der National Football
League [Labor market regulation and post-contractural opportunism: The
effects of signing bonuses on player performance in the National
Football League]. Zeitschrift fur Betriebswirtschaft, 72, 163-180.
Frick, B., Pietzner, G., & Prinz, J. (2007). Career duration in
a competitive environment: The labor market for soccer players in
Germany. Eastern Economic Journal, 33, 429-442.
Frick, B., Pietzner, G., & Prinz, J. (2009). Team performance
and individual career duration: Evidence from the German
"Bundesliga" In P. Andersson, P. Ayton, & C. Schmidt
(Eds.), Myths and facts about football: The economics and psychology of
the world's greatest sport (pp. 327-348). Cambridge, UK: Cambridge
Scholars Publishing.
Gramm, C. L., & Schnell, J. F. (1994). Difficult choices:
Crossing the picket line during the 1987 National Football League
strike. Journal of Labor Economics, 12, 41-73.
Gramm, C. L., & Schnell, J. F. (1997). Following the leader:
Race and player behavior in the 1987 NFL strike. Advances in the
Economics of Sports, 2, 115-143.
Guadalupe, M. (2003). The hidden costs of fixed-term contracts: The
impact on work accidents. Labour Economics, 10, 339-357.
Hamilton, B. H. (1997). Racial discrimination and professional
basketball salaries in the 1990s. Applied Economics, 29, 287-296.
Holmes, P. (in press). New evidence on salary discrimination in
Major League Baseball. Labour Economics, 18.
Holmstrom, B. (1982). Moral hazard in teams. Bell Journal of
Economics, 13, 324-340.
Holmstrom, B., & Milgrom, P. (1991). Multitask principal-agent
analyses: Incentive contracts, asset ownership and job design. Journal
of Law, Economics, and Organization, 7, 24-52.
Horowitz, I., & Zappe, C. (1998). Thanks for the memories:
Baseball veterans' end-of-career salaries. Managerial) and Decision
Economics, 19, 377-382.
Huebl, L., & Swieter, D. (2002). Der Spielermarkt in der
FuBball-Bundesliga [The player market in German professional football].
Zeitschrift fur Betriebswirtschaft, Ergdnzungsheft 4, Sportokonomie, 72,
105-125.
Ichino, A., & Riphahn, R. (2005). The effect of employment
protection on worker effort. A comparison of absenteeism during and
after probation. Journal of the European Economic Association, 3,
120-143.
Jimeno, J. F., & Toharia, L. (1996). Effort, absenteeism, and
fixed term employment contracts. Revista Espanola de Economia, 13,
105-119.
Kahn, L. M. (2000). The sports business as a labor market
laboratory. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 14, 75-94.
Kalter, F. (1999). Ethische Kundenpraferenzen im professionellen
sport? Der Fall der FussballBundesliga [Ethical consumer preferences in
professional sport? The case of the German "Bundesliga"].
Zeitschrift fur Soziologie, 28, 219-234.
Kicker. (1995-2008). Special Issues "Bundesliga".
Nurnberg.
Koenker, R., & Bassett, G. (1978). Regression quantiles.
Econometrica, 46, 33-50.
Krautman, A. C. (1990). Shirking or stochastic productivity in
Major League Baseball? Southern Economic Journal, 56, 961-968.
Krueger, A. B. (2005). The economics of real superstars: The market
for rock concerts in the material world. Journal of Labor Economics, 23,
1-30.
Kuethe, T. H., & Motamed, M. (2010). Returns to stardom:
Evidence from U.S. Major League Soccer. Journal of Sports Economics, 11,
567-579.
Kuhn, P., & Weinberger, C. (2005). Leadership skills and wages.
Journal of Labor Economics, 23, 395-436.
Leeds, M., & Kowalewski, S. (2001). Winner take all in the NFL.
The effect of the salary cap and free agency on the compensation of
skill position players. Journal of Sports Economics, 2, 244-256.
Lehmann, E. (2000). Verdienen Fussballspieler was sie verdienen?
[Do football players deserve what they earn?] In H.-M. Schellhaass
(Ed.), Sportveranstaltungen zwischen Liga--und Medieninteressen (pp.
97-121). Schorndorf: Karl Hofmann.
Lehmann, E. E., & Schulze, G. G. (2008). What does it take to
be a star? The role of performance and the media for German soccer
players. Applied Economics Quarterly, 54, 59-70.
Lehmann, E., & Weigand, J. (1999). Determinanten der Entlohnung
von Profifussballspielern Eine empirische analyse fur die deutsche
Bundesliga [The determinants of player salaries--An empirical analysis
with data from German soccer]. Betriebswirts chaftliche Forschung und
Praxis, 51, 124-135.
Lehn, K. (1982). Property rights, risk sharing, and player
disability in Major League Baseball. Journal of Law and Economics, 25,
347-366.
Lehn, K. (1984). Information asymmetries in baseball's free
agent market. Economic Inquiry, 22, 37-44.
Link, C. R., & Yosifov, M. (in press). Contract length and
salaries: Compensating wage differentials in Major League Baseball.
Journal of Sports Economics, 12.
Lucifora, C., & Simmons, R. (2003). Superstar effects in
sports: Evidence from Italian soccer. Journal of Sports Economics,
4,-55.
Marburger, D. R. (2003). Does the assignment of property rights
encourage or discourage shirking? Evidence from Major League Baseball.
Journal of Sports Economics, 4, 19-34.
Maxcy, J. G. (1997). Do long-term contracts influence performance
in Major League Baseball? Advances in the Economics of Sports, 2,
157-176.
Maxcy, J. G., Fort, R. D., & Krautman, A. C. (2002). The
effectiveness of incentive mechanisms in Major League Baseball. Journal
of Sports Economics, 3, 246-255.
Milgrom, P., & Roberts, J. (1992). Economics, management, and
organization. Englewood Cliffs, NJ: Prentice-Hall.
Muller-Jentsch, W. (1989). Basisdaten der industriellen Beziehunge
[Long-term data on German industrial relations]. Frankfurt, Germany:
Campus
van Ommeren, J., & Hazans, M. (2008). Workers' valuation
of the remaining contract duration. Economica, 75, 116-139.
Pedace, R. (2008). Earnings, performance, and nationality discrimination in a highly competitive labor market as an analysis of
the English professional soccer league. Journal of Sports Economics, 9,
115-140.
Reilly, B., & Witt, R. (2007). Determinants of base pay and the
role of race in Major League Soccer: Evidence from the 2007 league
season. Department of Economics, University of Surrey, Discussion Paper
D19/07.
Riphahn, R., & Thalmeier, A. (2001). Behavioral effects of
probation periods: An analysis of worker absenteeism. Jahrbucher fur
Nationalokonomie und Statistik, 221, 179-201.
Rosen, S. (1981). The economics of superstars. American Economic
Review, 71, 845-858.
Rottenberg, S. (1956). The baseball player's labor market.
Journal of Political Economy, 64, 242-258.
Simmons, R., & Berri, D. J. (2009). Gains from specialization and free agency: The story from the gridiron. Review of Industrial
Organization, 34, 81-98.
Sonnenberg, M. (2002). Als die Gehalter laufen lernten [When
salaries started skyrocketing]. SportBild, 2, 24-29.
Stiroh, K. J. (2007). Playing for keeps: Pay and performance in the
NBA. Economic Inquiry, 45, 145-161.
Torgler, B., Schmidt, S., & Frey, B. (2006). Relative income
position and performance: An empirical panel analysis. FEEM Discussion
Paper No. 39, Milano.
Vincent, C., & Eastman, B. (2009). Determinants of pay in the
NFL. A quantile regression approach. Journal of Sports Economics, 10,
256-277.
Wilson, D., & Ying, Y.-H. (2003). Nationality preferences for
labour in the international football industry. Applied Economics, 35,
1551-1559.
Yang, C.-H., & Lin, H.-Y. (in press). Is there salary
discrimination by nationality in the NBA? Foreign talent or foreign
market. Journal of Sports Economics, 12.
Endnotes
(1) In the same year, the average salary of a full-time blue collar
worker amounted to 7,775 DM. (i.e., about 60% of a football
player's annual income). Today, the average player salary is about
45 times the average salary in Germany.
(2) In the latter year, Oliver Bierhoff--later Matthaus'
teammate in Munich--earned more than 12 Mio. DM in Italy.
(3) With respect to contract length as a "discipline
device," see A. Cantor (1990), R. Cantor (1988), Dye (1985), and
van Ommeren and Hazans (2008).
(4) The few studies that have been conducted with representative
samples of employees (see Engellandt & Riphahn, 2005; Riphahn &
Thalmeier, 2001; Guadalupe, 2003; Ichino & Riphahn, 2005; Jimeno
& Toharia, 1996) use information on work accidents, unpaid overtime,
and absence days as dependent variables. Although the result reported in
these papers is surprisingly consistent--fixed-term contracts induced
higher levels of performance--the independent variables are far from
perfect.
(5) Contrary to the findings reported by Horowitz and Zappe (1998)
for baseball veterans, this suggests that nostalgia effects will be of
minor importance only.
(6) I am grateful to an anonymous referee for making this point
because it has obvious implications for the empirical analysis presented
below. Contrary to the situation in most American team sports, few
individual performance measures are recorded in football. Apart from the
number of goals scored, assists made, tackles won, and yellow and red
cards received, as well as number of substitute appearances, nothing is
available at acceptable cost. It is, therefore, difficult to distinguish
talent from popularity and/or fan appeal. Fortunately, it turns out that
the set of measures that I use below to describe a player's talent,
popularity, and fan appeal are not very highly correlated (i.e.,
multicollinearity is not a problem).
(7) Publications in German include Frick and Deutscher (2009),
Huebl and Swieter (2002), Lehmann (2000), and Lehmann and Weigand
(1999). With the exception of the latter, all these papers use much
smaller samples from short sub-periods since the early 1990s.
(8) On the determinants of individual career length, see inter
alia, Frick (2007) as well as Frick, Pietzner, and Prinz (2007, 2009).
(9) Thus, the variables I use to explain the observable variance in
player salaries are indirect at best and measure an individual
player's contribution to his team's economic performance only
imperfectly.
(10) This is interesting, insofar as Theo Zwanziger, in the
interview quoted above, also argued that many politicians, by supporting
the developments that have been induced by the Bosnian-ruling of the
European Court of Justice in December 1995, "have made few
particularly gifted players richer and richer and the clubs poorer and
poorer." He then went on to argue that "UEFA and the national
associations will do their very best to introduce an individual salary
cap and to reach a more egalitarian wage structure in professional
football." However, the distribution of player salaries (as
measured by the Gini coefficient) has remained more or less constant
between 1995-1996 and 2007-2008 providing little reason for such an
intervention.
(11) Although the Hausman-Test suggests using the results from the
fixed effects estimation, I report the findings of the random effects
estimation. The problem is that region of birth is a constant for each
player and cannot be used in a fixed effects estimation. However, the
differences between the remaining coefficients in the RE and the FE
estimations are negligible.
(12) Contrary to the situation in most American team sports leagues
with their abundance of performance figures, measurement of individual
player performance in European football can be problematic, especially
for defenders whose task it is to prevent the opposing teams'
forwards to score goals. While counting the number of goals scored,
shots on goal, and assists is straightforward, it is far more difficult
to assess the performance of defensive players. In future work, I will
therefore estimate the models separately for the different groups of
players.
(13) This unexpected result survives a number of different
specifications: Interacting the number of career goals with the position
dummies leaves the finding virtually unaffected. Moreover, estimating
the model separately by position yields the same result for forwards and
midfielders but not for defenders. Estimating the model only for
position players (i.e., without the goalkeepers) again yields the
strange coefficients.
(14) This is in line with Pedace (2008) who finds that players from
South America also receive preferential labor market treatment in the
English Premier League. He argues that this positive discrimination is a
rational response from owners who observe increased attendance with a
larger presence of South American players.
(15) Anecdotal evidence seems to support the argument that some
players suffer from home sickness once they are traded to another club.
(16) Estimating the models with the lagged annual salary to control
for unobserved heterogeneity reduces the sample size considerably from
6,100 player-year-observations to 4,700. Although most of the
coefficients retain their statistical significance, their magnitudes are
somewhat reduced. The complete results are available from the author
upon request.
(17) This term has first been used by Alan Krueger (2005),
analyzing the revenues generated by particularly successful rock bands
and musicians.
(18) However, recent evidence from the National Basketball
Association (Yang & Lin, 2010) as well as from Major League Baseball
(Holmes, 2010) suggests that, particularly at the lower end of the
salary distribution, discrimination by race and/or nationality seems to
persist.
(19) In further research, subjective evaluations of a player's
performance (i.e., school grades) will also be used to estimate the
hedonic wage equations (for a first application see Section 3 below).
(20) Using data from ten consecutive seasons (1990-1991 to
1999-2000) from the first German soccer division, Frick (2003) shows
that the c.p. of the percentage of variable pay positively affects the
performance of the teams. This finding, however, raises a further
question: If the teams that pay their players, to a large extent via
bonuses, are more successful than those who prefer fixed payments, why
do not all teams turn to performance-related pay? The negative
correlation between the log of total pay and the percentage of variable
pay suggests that poor teams motivate their employees via bonuses while
rich teams achieve this goal by paying high fixed salaries.
(21) In this view, contractually secured income may entice the
player to shirk if the utility sacrificed with effort is not offset with
income. However, it is also possible that long-term contracts are used
as tournament devices. The reward of a secured multiyear contract may be
part of a lucrative compensation package designed to increase
competition among workers. Thus, in a tournament setting, such contracts
may serve as incentives for which workers compete by increasing their
individual effort levels. Moreover, long-term contracts may also be
offered to players by risk-averse managers for risk management purposes.
(22) These are players appearing in at least 25% of all regular
season matches. Since the league is formed by 18 teams, each team has 17
home matches and 17 away matches.
(23) Since the dataset is an unbalanced panel, the number of years
the individual players have been active in the Bundesliga differs
considerably. Note, however, that the presence in the dataset is not
identical with the duration of individual careers. First, if a player
cannot retain his status as a regular player (e.g., due to lack of
fitness or injury), he disappears from the dataset even though he is
still active as a back-up player for one of the first division teams.
Second, many of the regular players started their career as substitutes
who later managed to become established players. This means that they
have been playing in the Bundesliga already before they appear in the
dataset.
(24) The school grades that are used here to express a
player's performance--ranging from very good to very poor--are
clearly, but not exclusively, affected by whether a player receives a
yellow or a red card and whether he scores a goal or produces an assist.
Thus, the school grades express, in a simple one digit figure, a
player's contribution to his team's performance on the pitch
in a particular match.
(25) Kernel density estimates of the dependent variables are
displayed in Figures A2-A4 in the Appendix.
(26) Estimating models 1.1-1.3 without the average team grade as an
exogenous variable leaves the coefficient of the contract status
variable unaffected. The results are, of course, available from the
author upon request.
(27) The results are, of course, available from the author upon
request.
(28) A larger share of players negotiating a new contract can, of
course, also be problematic for the team's managers, because they
may find themselves in a hold-up situation where, particularly the
stars, can credibly threaten to sign with another team.
(29) A first example for an extension that is currently being
performed is Bryson, Frick, and Simmons (2009) who use an unbalanced
panel from the Bundesliga, as well as a cross-section from the Big Five
European leagues to analyze the impact of both-footedness and
left-footedness on player remuneration. Controlling for player age,
height, position, and national league, they find that both-feet players
enjoy a pay premium of more than 20%, while left-footed players receive
a statistically significant premium of about 10%.
(30) Another possibility is to interact the position dummies with
the number of goals scored, the number of career appearances, the number
of international appearances, etc. to see whether the returns to
experience and popularity differ by, or are equal across, position.
Author's Note
I would like to thank Marcel Battre, Christian Deutscher, Thomas
Fritz, Julia Nagelschneider, and Wiebke Held for their assistance in
compiling the datasets used in this study. Errors and omissions are, of
course, my own responsibility.
Bernd Frick [1]
[1] University of Paderborn
Bernd Frick is a professor in the Department of Management. His
research interests include personnel economics and sport economics.
Table 1: Are fans envious?
Possible Responses %
Yes, because politicians are 19
obliged to intervene if
certain developments in
society are causing
discontent.
Yes, because the salaries in 0
football are simply too
high.
No, because politicians
should in principle 36
abstain from intervening
in private businesses.
No, because the salaries are 45
the result of market
forces.
Source: welt.de
Table 2: Estimation results I: Various methods
Variable Random Effects Robust OLS
B T B T
Age .5121 22.43 *** .4559 18.99 ***
[Age.sup.2] -.0092 -21.48 *** -.0083 -18.69 ***
Games Played .0191 25.66 *** .0240 31.95 ***
Career Games .0042 7.48 *** .0056 11.27 ***
Career -.0021 -5.97 *** -.0028 -9.18 ***
[Games.sup.2] * 100
Career [Games.sup.]3 .0033 5.46 *** .0043 8.07 ***
* 10000
International Caps .0848 6.86 *** .0903 6.04 ***
International -.0071 -3.56 *** -.0081 -2.79 ***
[Caps.sup.2]
International .0002 2.19 ** .0002 1.74 *
[Caps.sup.3]
Career Caps .0118 4.19 *** .0125 5.36 ***
Career [Caps.sup.2] -.0003 -3.40 *** -.0003 4.17 ***
Career [Caps.sup.3] .0017 2.99 *** .0016 3.67 ***
* 1000
Goals Scored .0444 14.24 *** .0465 16.28 ***
Career Goals -.0129 -4.71 *** -.0114 -4.69 ***
Career [Goals.sup.2] .0002 4.13 *** .0002 4.38 ***
Career [Goals.sup.3] -.0011 -3.68 *** -.0011 -4.15 ***
* 1000
Tenure -.0142 -4.43 *** -.0187 -6.46 ***
Captain (1 = yes) .2692 6.60 *** .3406 10.17 ***
First Division Abroad .5910 12.46 *** .6159 11.41 ***
Defender .2113 5.17 *** .0990 3.20 ***
Midfielder .2677 6.65 *** .1667 5.34 ***
Forward .3157 7.14 *** .2167 5.97 ***
South America .4494 8.23 *** .3778 9.87 ***
North America -.0822 -.73 + -.1785 -1.92 *
West Europe .2442 6.62 *** .1848 7.00 ***
East Europe .0774 2.23 ** .0329 1.36 *
Africa .0654 1.24 + -.0117 -.30 +
Asia/Australia .0928 1.28 + .0099 .20 +
Constant 5.8725 19.30 *** 6.8245 21.14 ***
Team Dummies included
Season Dummies included
N of Observations 6,147 6,147
Obs. per Player 1-13 -
Number of Players 1,993 -
[R.sup.2] * 100 61,7 62,7
F-Value - 164.5 ***
Wald Chi2 6,672.0 *** -
LM-Test 392.0 *** -
Raw Sum of Dev. - -
Min Sum of Dev. - -
Variable Median Regression
B T
Age .4361 23.71 ***
[Age.sup.2] -.0079 -23.12 ***
Games Played .0226 33.12 ***
Career Games .0057 12.46 ***
Career -.0030 -10.26 ***
[Games.sup.2] * 100
Career [Games.sup.]3 .0046 9.06 ***
* 10000
International Caps .0909 8.02 ***
International -.0094 -5.01 ***
[Caps.sup.2]
International .0003 4.09 ***
[Caps.sup.3]
Career Caps .0131 5.94 ***
Career [Caps.sup.2] -.0003 -4.48 ***
Career [Caps.sup.3] .0016 3.67 ***
* 1000
Goals Scored .0513 18.26 ***
Career Goals -.0077 -3.56 ***
Career [Goals.sup.2] .0001 3.31 ***
Career [Goals.sup.3] -.0007 -3.11 ***
* 1000
Tenure -.0153 -6.53 ***
Captain (1 = yes) .3718 10.50 ***
First Division Abroad .6346 15.11 ***
Defender .0539 2.24 **
Midfielder .0965 4.04 **
Forward .1020 3.68 **
South America .3824 11.91 ***
North America -.1510 -2.10 **
West Europe .1969 8.53 ***
East Europe .0200 .95 +
Africa -.0166 -.52 +
Asia/Australia .0185 .42 +
Constant 7.1631 29.21 ***
Team Dummies
Season Dummies
N of Observations 6,147
Obs. per Player -
Number of Players -
[R.sup.2] * 100 40,5
F-Value -
Wald Chi2 -
LM-Test -
Raw Sum of Dev. 4,656.6
Min Sum of Dev. 2,772.6
Notes: + not significant, * p < .10, ** p < .05, *** p < .01
Table 3: Estimation results II: Quantile regressions
Variable .1 Quantile .25 Quantile
Age .5415 *** .5485 ***
[Age.sup.2] -.0097 *** -.0099 ***
Games Played .0347 *** .0271 ***
Career Games .0050 *** .0058 ***
Career [Games.sup.2] -.0027 *** -.0034 ***
* 100
Career [Games.sup.3] .0042 *** .0057 ***
* 10000
International Caps .0340 ** .0568 ***
International -.0003 + -.0034 *
[Caps.sup.2]
International .0000 + .0000 +
[Caps.sup.3]
Career Caps .0108 *** .0119 ***
Career [Caps.sup.2] -.0002 ** -.0003 ***
Career [Caps.sup.3] .0014 ** .0019 ***
* 1000
Goals Scored .0453 *** .0511 ***
Career Goals -.0094 ** -.0038 +
Career [Goals.sup.2] .0002 *** .0000 +
Career [Goals.sup.3] -.0014 *** .0000 +
* 1000
Tenure -.0134 *** -.0181 ***
Captain (1 = yes) .3662 *** .3742 ***
First Division .7485 *** .6895 ***
Abroad
Defender .2154 *** .1049 ***
Midfielder .2414 *** .1458 ***
Forward .2832 *** .1634 ***
South America .3010 *** .3086 ***
North America -.1989 + -.0509 +
West Europe .1999 *** .1992 ***
East Europe .0635 * .0690 ***
Africa -.0153 + .0538 +
Asia/Australia .1296 + .1042 **
Constant 4.6571 *** 5.1341 ***
Team Dummies included
Season Dummies included
N of Cases 6,147 6,147
Pseudo [R.sup.2] 43.6 42.4
* 100
Raw Sum of Dev. 2,196.5 3,891.5
Min Sum of Dev. 1,239.1 2,240.8
Variable .75 Quantile .9 Quantile
Age .3660 *** .2829 ***
[Age.sup.2] -.0068 *** -.0055 ***
Games Played .0173 *** .0124 ***
Career Games .0047 *** .0030 ***
Career [Games.sup.2] -.0021 *** -.0001 **
* 100
Career [Games.sup.3] .0030 *** .0013 +
* 10000
International Caps .1241 *** .1129 ***
International -.0149 *** -.0114 ***
[Caps.sup.2]
International .0006 *** .0004 ***
[Caps.sup.3]
Career Caps .0126 *** .0122 ***
Career [Caps.sup.2] -.0002 *** -.0002 *
Career [Caps.sup.3] .0013 *** .0009 +
* 1000
Goals Scored .0486 *** .0425 ***
Career Goals -.0132 *** -.0077 *
Career [Goals.sup.2] .0003 *** .0002 **
Career [Goals.sup.3] -.0001 *** -.0009 **
* 1000
Tenure -.0201 *** -.0177 ***
Captain (1 = yes) .3114 *** .3296 ***
First Division .5848 *** .4772 ***
Abroad
Defender -.0002 + -.1560 ***
Midfielder .0756 *** -.0537 +
Forward .1111 *** -.0170 +
South America .3863 *** .4230 ***
North America -.2002 *** -.2519 *
West Europe .1637 *** .1627 ***
East Europe -.0344 + .0085 +
Africa -.0389 + -.0320 +
Asia/Australia -.2022 *** -.1494 *
Constant 8.6862 *** 10.4911 ***
Team Dummies
Season Dummies
N of Cases 6,147 6,147
Pseudo [R.sup.2] 39.2 39.2
* 100
Raw Sum of Dev. 3,577.2 1,934.0
Min Sum of Dev. 2,139.6 1,175.5
Notes: + not significant, * p < .10, ** p < .05, *** p < .01
Table 4: Player opportunism in professional team sports: A selective
review of the literature
Author(s) and League and Data Basic Findings
Year of Used
Publication
Lehn (1982) 650 MLB players Long-term contracts increase
in 1980 the amount of time spent on
the disabled list: Each
additional year remaining on
the contract is associated
with a 25% increase in the
average number of days spent
on the disabled list. This
is due to the fact that
guaranteed multiyear
contracts reduce the
incentives for players to
invest in proper physical
conditioning. However, the
disincentive effect of
long-term contracts can be
mitigated by inclusion of
incentive bonuses in player
contracts.
Lehn (1984) 155 MLB players Players who re-sign for at
in 1980 least three years with their
old team experience a
significantly smaller
increase in days spent on
the disabled list than
players who signed for three
years or even longer with
another team.
Krautman (1990) 110 MLB players There is no evidence of a
(only hitters) significant departure from
signing contracts the means of players'
of more than 5 productivity distributions
years duration, due to proximity to contract
1976-1983 negotiations. Thus, the
observable variation in
performance is the result of
a stochastic process rather
than shirking.
Scoggins (1993) 110 MLB players A convincing answer to the
(only hitters) question whether shirking
signing contracts occurs or not depends on the
of more than 5 choice of the performance
years duration, measure (i.e., if total
1976-1983 bases instead of slugging
average is used as a
performance measure,
shirking can be detected).
Gramm and 1,106 out of Players with long-term
Schnell 1,260 players contracts were less likely
(1994, 1997) under contract to participate in the 1987
with one of the strike. Since the main
28 NFL teams on reason for the strike was
September 21, the NFLPA's demand for free
1987 agency and since average
career duration in the NFL
is rather short (i.e., about
three seasons), players with
long-term contracts were
less likely to reap the
benefits of free agency and
were, therefore, more
interested in maximizing
their current incomes.
Maxcy (1997) MLB 1986-1993; For players with long-term
1,343-2,284 contracts, status in regard
player-year to re-contracting at the end
observations for of the current season does
hitters and not influence performance.
882-1,552 The reason is that long-term
player-year contracts are given to
observations for players who have already
pitchers proven themselves as
reliable and consistent
performers and are,
therefore, not likely to
shirk.
Fort and Maxcy MLB 1986-1993; Performance does not
(1998) 2,238 player-year increase as players approach
observations for renegotiation (i.e., when
hitters and 1,625 the individual contract is
player-year about to expire and when the
observations for individual, therefore,
pitchers should be most likely to
expend more effort).
Particularly when players
with long-term contracts are
analyzed from the shirking
perspective, there is no
evidence of shirking.
Conlin (1999); 1,873 of the Rookies signing their first
Conlin and 2,016 players contract after training camp
Emerson (1999) selected in the has started reveal positive
1986-1991 NFL private information about
drafts their abilities. Thus,
players who sign after
longer contract negotiations
are of higher ability levels
(i.e., higher percentage of
active contracts and higher
number of games started in
first three years).
Moreover, a player's effort
level is influenced by the
remaining duration of his
contract; that is, the
number of games started is
significantly higher in the
last year of the contract.
Fernie and 50 British When performance-related pay
Metcalf (1999) jockeys, is replaced by guaranteed
1983-1995 annual salaries via
so-called "retainers," the
individual athlete's
performance deteriorates
dramatically. Thus,
non-contingent payments
introduce moral hazard into
a payment system which had
previously proved to be
rather successful in
overcoming such behavior.
Not surprisingly, therefore,
these non-contingent
payments have been largely
abandoned recently.
Frick, Dilger, 349 The only legal way to
and Prinz team-year circumvent or partly avoid
(2002) observations, the hard salary cap in the
NFL, 1988-1999 NFL is by paying signing
bonuses to free agents
(these bonuses are
prorated). However, these
guaranteed up-front payments
that are unrelated to actual
performance induce players
to behave opportunistically:
The higher the percentage of
the signing bonuses, the
poorer the performance of
the team.
Maxcy, Fort, 1,160 For both pitchers and
and Krautman player-year hitters, time spent on the
(2002) observations on disabled list decreases in
213 hitters and the season immediately
812 player-year preceding contract
observations on negotiations. Moreover,
140 pitchers in playing time is above
MLB average in that season.
However, there is no
evidence of ex post
opportunism because
long-term contracts do not
cause a subsequent decline
in performance.
Marburger (2003) 279 free agent The redistribution of
nonpitchers property rights that was
signing contracts caused by the conversion
between 1990 and from the reserve clause to
1993 with any of free agency should have
the MLB-teams and increased player effort.
133 nonpitchers However, free agency also
in 1970 who had saw an increase in multiyear
at least six contracts which, in turn,
years of major creates shirking incentives.
league experience The net impact of property
rights assignment on
shirking in MLB is obvious:
Free agents with one- and
two-year contracts
outperform comparable
reserve clause players over
the same time frame. This is
not the case for free agents
with contracts exceeding two
years.
Berri and 515 player-year Depending on the specific
Krautman (2006) observations in measure of performance used
the NBA, 2000/ in the estimates, the
2001-2002/2003 evidence appears to be
mixed: Although in the first
estimation the effect of
signing a long-term contract
on performance is
significantly negative, the
economic impact is small. In
the second estimation,
however, even this small
impact disappears.
Stiroh (2007) 349 NBA-player Individual performance
contracts signed improves in the year before
1993-2001 (2,077 signing a multiyear contract
player-year and declines after the
observations) contract is signed. This is
consistent with an observed
salary structure that
rewards both historical
performance and recent
improvement and thus
provides strong incentives
to increase effort and
improve performance before
signing a new multiyear
contract.
Table 5: Alternative measures of remaining
contract duration *
Variable Mean Std Dev
Remaining Contract 1, 35 1, 7
Years
Recoded Number of 1, 17 0, 79
Remaining Years ##
Last Year of 0, 24 -
Contract (0 = no;
1 = yes)
Notes: # Number of cases = 1,866
individual-year-observations for regular
players ## Number of years > 2 recoded
as 2
Table 6: Contract status and player performance (Dependent
variable: Average player grade)
Variable Model 1.1 Model 1.2
Contract Variable: Contract Variable:
Remaining Years Remaining Years
[less than or
equal to] 2
Average Team .8052 19.72 *** .8054 19.76 ***
Grade .0408 .0408
Contract Status .0187 2.70 *** .0283 3.32 ***
.0069 .0085
Defender -.0632 -.33 + -.0752 -.40 +
.1890 .1887
Midfielder -.0884 -.47 + -.0999 -.53 +
.1894 .1892
Forward -.0277 -.14 + -.0407 -.21 +
.1940 .1937
Goals Scored -.0385 13.23 *** -.0385 -13.25 ***
.0029 .0029
Red Cards .0079 .36 + .0074 .34 +
.0220 .0219
Yellow Cards -.0105 -3.52 *** -.0103 -3.49 ***
.0029 .0029
Semi-Profession. -.1570 -2.04 ** -.1556 -2.03 **
.0768 .0767
Career Games .0012 1.82 * .0012 1.87 *
.0006 .0006
Career [Games.
sup.2] (#) -.0001 -1.97 ** -.0001 -2.03 **
.0005 .0000
International .0001 .17 + .0001 .14 +
.0011 .0011
Age -.0782 -2.05 ** -.0849 -2.23 **
.0380 .0381
[Age.sup.2] .0011 1.95 * .0012 2.13 **
.0006 .0006
Team Change -.1207 -3.16 *** -.1145 -3.03 ***
.0382 .0377
Constant 2.0694 3.24 *** 2.1671 3.40 ***
.6380 .6365
N of Obs. 1,863 1,863
N of Players 760 760
F-Value 54.7 55.1
LM-Test 138.8 *** 143.2 ***
Hausman 111.6 *** 111.6 ***
Variable Model 1.3
Contract Variable:
Last Year-Dummy
Average Team .8100 19.80 ***
Grade .0409
Contract Status -.0413 -2.85 ***
.0145
Defender -.0717 -.38 +
.1889
Midfielder -.0994 -.53 +
.1894
Forward -.0395 -.20 +
.1939
Goals Scored -.0385 -13.23 ***
.0029
Red Cards .0069 .32 +
.0219
Yellow Cards -.0104 -3.49 ***
.0029
Semi-Profession. -.1616 -2.10 **
.0768
Career Games .0012 1.84 *
.0006
Career [Games.
sup.2] (#) -.0001 -1.97 **
.0000
International .0001 .09 +
.0011
Age -.0846 -2.22 **
.0381
[Age.sup.2] .0012 2.07 **
.0006
Team Change -.1059 -2.81 ***
.0376
Constant 2.2136 3.47 ***
.6379
N of Obs. 1,863
N of Players 760
F-Value 54.8
LM-Test 143.5 ***
Hausman 108.6 ***
Notes: (#) coefficient multiplied by 1,000 for ease of
presentation, + not significant, * p < .10, ** p < .05, p < .01
Table 7: Contract status and player performance (Dependent
variable: Average player grade relative to average grade of team)
Variable Model 2.1 Model 2.2
Contract Variable: Contract Variable:
Remaining Years Remaining Years
[less than or
equal to] 2
Contract Status .0199 2.85 *** .0296 3.44 ***
.0069 .0086
Defender -.0355 -.19 + -.0479 -.25 +
.1907 .1905
Midfielder -.0665 -.35 + -.0784 -.41 +
.1912 .1910
Forward -.0059 -.03 + -.0195 -.10 +
.1958 .1956
Goals Scored -.0369 12.65 *** -.0369 -12.66 ***
.0029 .0029
Red Cards -.0017 -.08 + -.0022 -.10 +
.0221 .0220
Yellow Cards -.0115 -3.85 *** -.0114 -3.81 ***
.0030 .0030
Semi-Profession. -.1509 -1.94 ** -.1495 -1.93 **
.0776 .0775
Career Games .0010 1.45 * .0010 1.51 +
.0006 .0006
Career [Games.
sup.2] (#) -.0009 -1.59 + -.0009 -1.66 **
.0005 .0005
International .0005 .51 + .0005 .48 +
.0011 .0011
Age -.0753 -1.96 ** -.0823 -2.14 **
.0384 .0384
[Age.sup.2] .0010 1.78 * .0012 1.97 **
.0006 .0006
Team Change -.1397 -3.64 *** -.1328 -3.50 ***
.0384 .0379
Constant 1.3492 2.16 ** 1.4533 2.33 ***
.6260 .6249
Nof Obs. 1,863 1,863
N of Players 760 760
F-Value 17.7 18.0
LM-Test 130.8 *** 134.6 ***
Hausman 95.3 *** 95.7 ***
Variable Model 2.3
Contract
Variable: Last
Year-Dummy
Contract Status -.0466 -3.19 ***
.0146
Defender -.0462 -.24 +
.1906
Midfielder -.0798 -.42 +
.1911
Forward -.0199 -.10 +
.1957
Goals Scored -.0369 -12.66 ***
.0029
Red Cards -.0025 -.11 +
.0221
Yellow Cards -.0114 -3.81 ***
.0030
Semi-Profession. -.1560 -2.01 **
.0775
Career Games .0010 1.50 +
.0006
Career [Games.
sup.2] (#) -.0009 -1.61 +
.0005
International .0004 .42 +
.0011
Age -.0827 -2.15 **
.0385
[Age.sup.2] .0011 1.93 *
.0006
Team Change -.1236 -3.27 ***
.0378
Constant 1.5288 2.44 ***
.6264
Nof Obs. 1,863
N of Players 760
F-Value 17.9
LM-Test 134.5 ***
Hausman 94.5 ***
Notes: (#) coefficient multiplied by 1,000 for ease of
presentation, + not significant, * p < .10, ** p < .05, p < .01
Table 8: Contract status and player performance (Dep.
variable: Variance of player grade)
Variable Model 3.1 Model 3.2 Contract
Contract Variable: Variable: Remaining
Remaining Years Years [less than or
equal to] 2
Contract Status .0090 1.64 * .0150 2.08 **
.0055 .0072
Number of Graded -.0034 -3.67 *** -.0034 -3.69 ***
Appearances .0009 .0009
Average Team Grade .1105 3.57 *** .1110 3.59 ***
.0310 .0309
Defender -.0561 -1.99 ** -.0569 -2.01 **
.0282 .0282
Midfielder -.0264 -.94 + -.0271 -.96 +
.0281 .0281
Forward .0178 .56 + .0169 .53 +
.0319 .0320
Goals Scored .0377 16.57 *** .0377 16.58 ***
.0022 .0022
Red Cards .0546 2.86 *** .0545 2.86 +
.0190 .0190
Yellow Cards -.0024 -.99 + -.0024 -.97 +
.0024 .0024
Career Games -.0001 -.83 + * -.0001 -.79 +
.0001 .0001
Career [Games.
sup.2] (#) .0001 .77 + .0001 .73 +
.0002 .0002
International .0569 4.52 *** .0570 4.53 ***
.0126 .0125
Age .0146 .78 + .0130 .69 +
.0187 .0187
[Age.sup.2] -.0003 -1.02 + -.0003 -.93 +
.0003 .0003
Semi- Professional -.0045 -.17 + -.0037 -.14 +
.0262 .0262
Team Change -.0201 -.65 + -.0188 -.61 +
.0310 .0308
Constant .1602 .60 + .1747 .65 +
.2691 .2688
N of Obs. 1,863 1,863 1,863
N of Players 760 760 760
F-Value 29.4 29.5 29.3
Wald [X.sup.2] 611.2 *** 611.4 ***
LM-Test 26.5 *** 26.3 ***
Hausman 14.5 + 13.3 +
Variable Model 3.3 Contract
Variable: Last
Year-Dummy
Contract Status -.0142 -1.11 +
.0128
Number of Graded -.0034 -3.65 ***
Appearances .0009
Average Team Grade .1073 3.47 ***
.0309
Defender -.0579 -2.05 **
.0282
Midfielder -.0279 -.99 +
.0281
Forward .0158 .49 +
.0320
Goals Scored .0378 16.61 ***
.0022
Red Cards .0547 2.86 ***
.0191
Yellow Cards -.0024 -.98 +
.0024
Career Games -.0001 -.86 +
.0001
Career [Games.
sup.2] (#) .0001 .80 +
.0002
International .0584 4.64 ***
.0125
Age .0142 .76 +
.0187
[Age.sup.2] -.0003 -1.02 +
.0003
Semi- Professional -.0046 -.18 +
.0263
Team Change -.0138 -.45 +
.0307
Constant .1985 .74 +
.2694
N of Obs.
N of Players
F-Value
Wald [X.sup.2] 606.6 ***
LM-Test 26.9 ***
Hausman 12.4 +
Notes: (#) coefficient multiplied by 1,000 for ease of
presentation, + not significant, * p < .10, ** p < .05, p < .01