The allocation of time to sports and cultural activities: an analysis of individual decisions.
Muniz, Cristina ; Rodriguez, Placido ; Suarez, Maria J. 等
Introduction
Sports and culture are rarely linked in academic research. While a
burgeoning literature exists in both cultural and sport economics, both
subjects have generally been studied in isolation despite their clear
similarities: Both are forms of leisure time allocation that may be
jointly chosen by individuals. This common feature justifies a joint
analysis of both activities.
An interesting question addressed in this article is whether these
leisure activities tend to be demanded jointly or separately. On one
hand, both activities may be considered as a social occasion and a
chance to spend time and socialize with others. On the other hand,
sports and cultural activities are time-intensive goods and may compete
for individual leisure time.
The aim of this research is to analyze the individual's
decision to allocate time to sports and cultural activities using the
neoclassical consumption theory. In Spain, the literature on sports
participation (we include physical activity) from an economic
perspective is scarce and, as far as we know, no articles study both of
these leisure activities. Garcia et al. (2009) develop a structural
model of the allocation of time to sports and leisure, assuming a
Constant Elasticity of Substitution (CES) utility function. The current
paper builds upon Garcia et al.'s model by adding another use of
leisure time: time devoted to cultural activities. Thus, we specify a
model that defines three uses of time besides working time: sports,
cultural, and other leisure activities. This model leads to a system of
three demand equations for time not allocated to work, which are
estimated using the Seemingly Unrelated Regression (SUR) method.
The dataset used in this research is "La Encuesta de Empleo
del Tiempo" (Spanish Time Use Survey, 2002-2003) conducted by the
Instituto Nacional de Estadistica (INE; National Statistics Office)
according to the Eurostat guidelines for harmonized European time use
surveys. The distinctive feature of this database is a diary that
provides information on the activities of each individual across a given
day, provided in 10 min intervals.
Literature Review
Sports Economics
There is a wide body of literature on sports economics, including
several textbooks and handbooks that analyze various aspects of interest
to economists. (1) Moreover, there is growing economic literature that
specifically examines sports participation, among which it is worth
mentioning Humphreys and Ruseski (2006, 2007, 2009, 2010); Downward and
Riordan (2007); Wicker, Breuer, and Pawlowski (2009); and Downward and
Rasciute (2010).
The research on mass participation in sports draws upon two major
theoretical approaches: the neoclassical theory and the heterodox
economics approach. The central feature of the neoclassical models is to
assume that agents are rational in the sense that their objective is to
maximize their individual utility subject to certain restrictions.
Moreover, consumer preferences are generally considered invariant. In
this framework, sports (and cultural participation) can be treated as
commodity demands or as demands for leisure time, either extending the
standard labor supply model or applying Becker's allocation of time
theory (Becker, 1965).
Heterodox approaches, on the other hand, comprise psychological
theories of consumption, post-Keynesian theory, and sociological theory.
They tend to provide a more descriptive account of how decisions are
made instead of relying on a theory of behavioral optimization.
Consequently, habits and a hierarchical structure of demand may be
relevant. In addition, these approaches view preferences as dependent
upon experience with consumption, thus reflecting learning-by-doing and
the preferences and behaviors of others. As a result, preferences are
endogenous and can be linked to lifestyles. (2)
Most of the published studies on sports participation are only
empirical, and few theoretical models analyze sports participation.
Among those papers with a theoretical framework, Cawley (2004) extends
Becker's time use model (1965) to physical activity and specifies
the SLOTH model; according to this model, people allocate their time to
the following activities: sleep (S), leisure (including physical
activity) (L), occupation (O), transportation (T), and home production
(H). Humphreys and Ruseski (2006) combine the main aspects of the SLOTH
framework with a recreation demand model (McConnell, 1992) and
distinguish between participation and frequency of participation. Their
model predicts that the economic factors that affect these two decisions
work in opposite directions: Income has a positive effect on
participation and a negative effect on time spent in physical activity.
(3)
Humphreys and Ruseski (2007) follow the neoclassical approach to
examine sports consumption in the U.S. and analyze variation in
participation and time spent in physical activity across groups of
activities. Thus, changes in government spending on parks and recreation
increase participation in some activities but reduce it in others.
Humphreys and Ruseski (2009) demonstrate the importance of economic
factors, such as income and opportunity cost, to explain physical
activity and conclude that it can be considered to be a normal good.
Downward's (2007) empirical research explores the choice to
participate in sports in the U.K. His results suggest "more support
for the predictions of heterodox theories for sport demand than the
neoclassical theories" (Downward, 2007, p. 650) because the income
effects decrease when sport is disaggregated. Further, he finds that
changes in working time are not significant determinants of
participation. In contrast, socioeconomic variables such as sex,
education, and household composition appear to be the main factors that
affect sports participation.
Downward and Riordan (2007) also argue that such results could be
consistent with Becker's time allocation model. These authors find
evidence that investment in personal consumption capital and social
capital--through social interactions--increases participation in sports.
As with cultural goods, previous consumption can increase current
consumption because of the skills acquired (Downward & Rasciute,
2010). Moreover, Becker's approach is also supported more recently
by Breuer and Wicker (2008) and Wicker et al. (2009) in the case of
Germany. (4)
In Spain, the analysis of sports participation and physical
activity has traditionally had a sociological emphasis. This point is
illustrated by the studies of Garcia Ferrando (2001a, 2001b, 2005,
2006), Fernandez-Ballesteros (1998), Fernandez-Ballesteros et al. (2004,
2007), Lagardera Otero (1992), Martinez del Castillo et al. (2005,
2006), Moscoso (2005), and Puig and Soler (2004). In these studies, the
authors examine the degree to which sedentary lifestyles have become
dominant among the Spanish population. They also study how physical
activity or sports contribute to the improvement of individuals'
feelings of health, wellbeing, and quality of life.
Lera-Lopez and Rapun-Garate (2005, 2007) and Garcia et al. (2009)
are the only works that analyze sports participation from an economic
perspective in Spain. Other authors examine the links between
participation and expenditure in a Spanish region, although no explicit
theoretical orientation is noted.
Cultural Economics
Before discussing the empirical literature on participation in
cultural activities, we will briefly overview theories of participation
in the arts. Performing arts consist of theater, opera, ballet and
modern dance, symphony concerts, and chamber recitals. Since the work of
Baumol and Bowen (1966), a majority of studies deal with live performing
arts, which motivates our focus on the demand for these cultural
activities. (5)
As McCarthy and Jinnett (2001) point out, there are two different
approaches to the analysis of participation decisions. First, under the
traditional economic approach, individuals behave as rational consumers
who seek to maximize their utility given their preferences and price and
income restrictions.
Other authors find that tastes play a more active role in consumer
decisions, especially in relation to cultural goods among others. Many
cultural economists assert that current arts demand is influenced by
past arts exposure. Within theories on taste cultivation, some authors
believe that past consumption can positively influence present and
future consumption through rational addiction (Stigler & Becker,
1977). Aficionados are thereby distinguished from casual attendees.
However, others focus on consumption as a learning process. This
approach directly opposes the rational addiction approach, wherein the
formation of tastes can be perceived as a deterministic process and,
thus, consumption is shortsighted (myopic). In the learning-by-consuming
approach (Levy-Garboua & Montmarquette, 1996, 2002), the formation
of tastes is a dynamic process. In other words, any new experience can
change consumer tastes.
In summary, consumption is affected by factors such as prices and
income. In addition, as people attain more knowledge about cultural
goods, they are more likely to participate in consumption because they
gain greater satisfaction than those who do not have that information.
In recent years, the empirical literature has focused on a variety
of cultural activities, such as original art objects (paintings,
sculpture, and other artifacts), theater, and music. Seaman's
(2005) survey about attendance at arts events concludes that, although
various and complex models of these activities have been developed,
there is no consensus regarding the determinants of arts demand. In
other words, many of the cases that have been theoretically postulated have not been corroborated by empirical evidence. In particular, the
hypotheses that cultural goods always behave as luxury goods and that
education has a greater effect than income (two variables that are
difficult to separate in practice and lead to multicollinearity
problems) are still controversial. In addition, assumptions concerning
the values of demand elasticities have not been agreed upon in the
literature.
Despite this lack of consensus, one important dimension of the
empirical study of art consumption--not present in sports economics
research--is that it explores the relationship between different types
of cultural demand. Pommerehne and Kirchgassner (1987), Kurabayashi and
Ito (1992), Levy-Garboua and Montmarquette (1996), and Prieto-Rodriguez
and Fernandez-Blanco (2000) study the correlation between different
genres through various econometric techniques.
Sport and Cultural Demand
The possibility of substitution between various activities has been
addressed in Kesenne (1981, 1983), Kesenne and Butzen (1987), and
Downward and Rasciute (2010). There are some studies about
time-intensive goods, such as sports and performing arts, revealing that
these leisure activities are more expensive than others even if the
prices are the same because of the shadow price of time (see Loyland
& Ringstad, 2010).
There are few studies about the relationship between arts and
sports demands. Montgomery and Robinson (2006, 2008) discuss the
tradeoffs between attendance at cultural events and other types of
events. They estimate a system of regressions that includes the natural
log of the number of times an event is attended as the dependent
variable. Their results suggest that sports activities compete with art
events for attendance. (6)
In the U.S., Kopczynski and Hager (2003) consider the relationship
between various individual characteristics and attitudes toward the
performing arts. They conclude that regular performing arts attendees
also attend other leisure activities, including sporting events, more
frequently than others. Finally, Swanson et al. (2008) explore the
relationship of six motivations (i.e., aesthetic, education, escapism,
recreation, self-esteem, and social interaction) with arts performance
attendance. The fact that consumption is positively associated with
these motives supports previous findings in the sport-spectator
literature.
In Europe, Loyland and Ringstad (2009) explore sports demand in
Norway and conclude that sports and most other leisure goods are
substitutes. In Spain, Fernandez-Blanco and Prieto-Rodriguez (2001) also
examine the substitutability between sports and culture. They estimate a
trivariate probit model to determine the probability of attending live
sports, listening to music, and attending the cinema. These authors find
positive error covariances between all three activities, which indicate
that sports do not compete with the consumption of music or cinema.
However, they do find substantial differences in the estimated effects
of gender and education on live sports attendance and on music and
cinema consumption. Thus, they conclude that males and those with less
education have much higher sports attendance than females and more
educated individuals.
The research presented here specifies and estimates a model of the
allocation of time to sports, culture, and other leisure activities. The
paper develops and estimates a neoclassical model based on the work of
Humphreys and Ruseski (2006), Downward and Riordan (2007), and Garcia et
al. (2009). However, the current paper expands upon the previous
literature because these earlier papers focus on the time allocated to
sports.
Model of Participation in Leisure Activities
We specified a structural model of time allocation and derived the
system of time demand equations to be estimated. The model developed in
this paper is an extension of the research previously conducted by
Garcia et al. (2009), which estimated a system of two typical
Marshallian demand functions of time devoted to sports and other leisure
practices. Furthermore, in this study, three possible time allocation
possibilities were examined besides working time: sports, cultural
activities, and other leisure time.
Following Garcia et al. (2009), we assumed a simplified CES as the
utility function. The CES utility function is commonly used to model the
static labor supply choice. (7) We chose this function for its
flexibility--it does not impose a linear relationship between wages and
time spent on various leisure activities--and for ease of estimation.
However, it is important to note that this functional form does not
allow inferior goods to be included in the model. (8) However, this
issue is not a serious problem for our research because sports and
cultural activities can be considered normal goods.
We assumed that individual preferences are a function of
consumption and time that people devote to sports, culture, and other
leisure activities. According to the neoclassical model, the purpose of
each individual is to maximize the level of utility subject to a budget
constraint.
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] (1)
where U denotes utility, c is consumption, [l.sub.0] is leisure
time (not devoted to sports or cultural activities), [l.sub.1] is time
spent on sports activities, [l.sub.2] is time spent on cultural
activities, w is hourly earnings, y is non-labor income, and T is the
time endowment (24 hours per day). Finally, [alpha], [beta], [delta],
and [gamma] are parameters of the utility function that must meet the
following conditions:
[gamma] > -1
[alpha], [beta], [delta] > 0
Additionally, we allowed both observable and unobservable factors
to enter the preferences through the parameters a, p, and 8 according
to:
[alpha] = [e.sup.(z0[phi]0-[mu]0)] (2)
[beta] = [e.sup.(z1[phi]1-[mu]1)] (3)
[delta] = [e.sup.(z2[phi]2-[mu]2)] (4)
where [Z.sub.0], [Z.sub.1], and [Z.sub.2] are vectors of
explanatory variables that may influence an individual's
well-being, and [[mu].sub.0], [[mu].sub.1], and [[mu].sub.2] are random
variables that capture unobservable factors affecting the individual
valuation of leisure activities.
From the first-order conditions for interior solutions, we obtained
the following system of relative demands:
log [c/[l.sub.0]] = [1/[1+[gamma]]log w -
[[Z.sub.0][[phi].sub.0]/[1+[gamma]][gamma] + [[mu].sub.0]/[1+[gamma]]
(5)
log [c/[l.sub.1]] = [1/[1+[gamma]]log w -
[[Z.sub.1][[phi].sub.1]/[1+[gamma]][gamma] + [[mu].sub.1]/[1+[gamma]]
(6)
log [c/[l.sub.2]] = [1/[1+[gamma]]log w -
[[Z.sub.2][[phi].sub.2]/[1+[gamma]][gamma] + [[mu].sub.2]/[1+[gamma]]
(7)
Estimating Equations (5)-(7) allowed us to understand the
determinants of individuals' time allocation decisions. Regarding
the relationship between sports and cultural activities, the opportunity
cost was the same in both cases--the amount of income that is not
received by substituting work for all leisure activities--and, thus, the
complementarity or substitutability between these types of leisure was
analyzed through the correlation between the residuals of the last two
equations ([[mu].sub.1] and [[mu].sub.2]). We noted that, although this
is consistent with our theoretical approach, it also reveals a
limitation of the model because prices are not included. Most likely,
the costs of participation would differ between different cultural
activities and sports. (9)
Data and Estimation Procedure
The data used to estimate the model specified in the previous
section were provided by La Encuesta de Empleo del Tiempo (The Time Use
Survey) conducted by the INE from 2002 to 2003. (10) This survey
gathered information on the daily activities of individuals in a sample
of approximately 24,000 households. Data collection instruments included
individual diaries and questionnaires pertaining to individuals and
households. (11)
The sample population in the survey consisted of all members of a
household who resided in private homes. The sample was distributed
uniformly throughout the year, and the distribution was wider on weekend
days because individual behavior is more variable on the weekends.
Individuals' daily activity was recorded by a diary that all
household members over the age of 10 completed on a given day. The daily
activity diary collected 24 consecutive hours (from 6:00 a.m. until 6:00
a.m. the next day) of data in 10 min intervals. At each interval, the
respondent recorded the main activity he or she was engaged in and any
secondary activity that was performed at the same time.
These activities are coded according to a list of harmonized
activities from Eurostat. The 177 main activities were classified into
10 groups: personal care, work, education, home and family, volunteer
work and meetings, social life and entertainment, sports and outdoor
activities, hobbies and games, media, and travel and unspecified time
uses.
Therefore, we could determine the four dependent variables on the
left-hand side of relative demand Equations (5)-(7).
Time spent on sports activities. This variable was defined as the
amount of time (measured hours per day) assigned to both sports and
physical activity, such as walking, playing football, going to the gym,
dancing, fishing, and swimming; it also includes the time spent
attending sporting events. It is, therefore, an aggregate variable that
measured both active and passive participation in sport activities.
There are three reasons for this aggregation. First, a homogeneous
definition of sports and culture is necessary. Second, following Dawson
and Downward (2009), we considered that both demands generally manifest
"a latent variable of sport consumption" (Dawson &
Downward, 2009, p. 23)--the same reasoning is applied to cultural
activities. Third, aggregation provided us with a larger sample size.
Time spent on cultural participation. This variable was defined in
a similar way as the sports variable. It was the amount of time
(measured in hours per day) allocated to artistic activities, such as
painting, sculpture, ceramics, graphic arts, pottery, making movies,
singing, dancing, playing musical instruments, and writing novels or
poetry. We also considered the time spent as a spectator at cultural
events. Therefore, time spent on cultural participation was also an
aggregate variable that included active and passive participation in
cultural activities.
Time spent on other leisure activities. This variable was defined
as the amount of time (measured in hours per day) assigned to leisure
activities other than those captured by the previous two variables. The
leisure variable acted as a time residual that captured time not devoted
to work, sports, or cultural activities. It is important to note that
variables such as time watching television or reading books were
subsumed into the leisure residual and were not considered as part of
the previous two groups.
Consumption. This variable represented the daily net family income.
It was computed using information about monthly family income from all
sources. Because income was reported in ranges, we assigned the interval
midpoint to each household.
In this research, we only focused on the behavior of the
working-age population. Therefore, we estimated the model using a sample
of people between 18 and 65 years of age. In addition, to correctly
measure individual earnings, we only took into account the survey
information regarding each individual's primary occupation.
Individuals with a secondary occupation were dropped from the sample. We
also eliminated all individuals who worked more than 112 hrs per week
and those observations for which no information was available on the
variables under study.
Our main goal was to estimate the relative demand system of
Equations (5)-(7). This system of relative demand equations was only
applicable to the subsample of people who participated in both cultural
and sports activities on the day they were interviewed. (12) Because
this subsample was not randomly selected from the population, we had to
control for possible selection biases. Thus, our estimation procedure
consisted of two stages.
First, participation in sports and cultural activities was
estimated using a bivariate probit model. The dependent variables in
this bivariate probit model were discrete variables that took the value
of 1 when individuals participated in the activities during the selected
day, and it was zero otherwise. From the bivariate probit coefficients,
we computed a transformation of the predicted individual probabilities
to correct the selection biases in the demand equations to be estimated
in the second stage (see Baffoe-Bonnie, 2009; Ham, 1982).
Second, the linear equation system (5)-(7) was estimated assuming
that the random components [[mu].sub.0], [[mu].sub.1], and [[mu].sub.2]
were distributed as a trivariate normal distribution with zero means and
constant variances. Additionally, our theoretical model imposed the
single constraint that the coefficient on the logarithm of wages must be
the same in all three equations. Thus, we estimated the system using the
SUR method, which allowed correlation between the random terms and
cross-equation restrictions on the parameters. Previous studies have
shown that this econometric technique can offer more efficient
estimators when the equations are linked via their error terms (Cameron
& Trivedi, 2005; Greene, 2008). Finally, this equation system was
estimated using the subsample of people who participated in sports and
cultural activities; therefore, we included the selection rule estimates
computed from the previous stage to correct the sample selection
problem. (13)
In the empirical analysis, separate equations were estimated for
men and women because previous findings in the literature on the
allocation of time suggest that there are important behavioral
differences depending on gender. Empirical studies on gender differences
in leisure time confirm that there is still a leisure gap favoring men.
Women experience lower-quality free time and less total free time than
men because men have many more hours of pure leisure without other
activities or responsibilities, and men's leisure is less likely to
be interrupted than women's (Bittman & Wajcman, 2000; Mattingly
& Bianchi, 2003; Mattingly & Sayer, 2006). Furthermore,
following Swanson et al. (2008), gender may be associated with different
motivations in both sports and cultural participation because males are
characterized by self-focused goals, while females pursue harmonious
relations and affiliation with others in their leisure time.
Table 1 provides the definition and summary statistics of the
variables used in the empirical analysis.
The independent variables included in bivariate probit models to
explain the probability of participation in cultural and sports
activities are as follows: age, age squared, health, marital status,
number of children younger than 12-years-old, number of adults in the
home, degree of urbanization, non-labor income, region, educational
level, and dummies to control for the term and day of the week when the
information is collected.
Regarding the relative demands for leisure time, the explanatory
variables included are as follows: age, age squared, marital status,
number of children younger than 12-years-old, number of adults in the
home, a dummy to control for the weekend, predicted hourly earnings, and
two terms to correct sample selection biases.
In the system of relative demand equations, we included predicted
hourly earnings because wages are computed as a ratio of labor earnings
and working hours, which may lead to endogeneity problems. Additionally,
there is no information about the earnings of nonworking individuals.
(14)
For identification reasons, we assumed that some variables only
influenced the decision to participate but not the intensity. (15) In
particular, in the SUR estimates, we dropped health status, term, degree
of urbanization, and non-labor income because these variables may affect
the probability of participating but not the amount of time devoted to
the activity. Moreover, educational level and region were assumed to
have an indirect influence on the leisure demands via their effect on
individual earnings. (16)
Results
The coefficients estimated in the bivariate probit model that
explains the probability of participating in sports and cultural
activities are presented in Table 2. Although interpretation of the
coefficients in probit regression was not straightforward, the marginal
effects had the same signs as the regression coefficients for all
individuals in the sample.
It is worth noting that the correlation coefficient was positive
and significant for both males and females, which means that individual
sports participation and cultural participation were not independent.
Instead, there was a relationship of complementarity between the two
leisure activities.
In Table 2, the estimated coefficients suggested that males and
females display the same behaviors in relation to cultural activities
and sports according to age. Age displayed a U-shaped relationship to
participation in cultural activities and sports (although this
relationship was not significant for females' participation in
cultural activities). For males, the minimum probability of
participation in cultural activities was reached at the age of 45. This
result reinforces a general hypothesis about arts participation:
"After some age, an evening out can be presumed to entail
additional implicit costs" (Gray, 2003, p. 358). This variable
showed a negative effect, which was similar to the findings of most
previous studies (Downward, 2007; Gratton & Tice, 1991; Humphreys
& Ruseski, 2006). Furthermore, the influence of age on sports
participation agreed with the results of Garcia et al. (2009).
With regard to other explanatory variables, the male probability of
sports participation increased when a chronic illness was present. This
result was surprising but may be reasonable because our dependent
variable included both active and passive sports. Thus, the disease may
promote passive participation as a spectator of sports.
Being married negatively affected participation in cultural
activities. However, for sports activities, this variable was only
significant for females, and it had a positive sign. Because sports
activities are more frequently practiced by males, married women attend
sporting events or participate in certain sports activities with their
husbands (Montgomery & Robinson, 2008).
In addition to marital status, household composition also affected
participation. Family responsibilities reduced the time available for
leisure activity. Like sports, cultural participation was time
consuming, and the presence of children under 12 years of age in the
household had an adverse effect on both types of participation,
especially for females (the variable was not significant for males for
cultural activities). In addition, the presence of adults in the
household also reduced participation in cultural activities.
Education level showed a positive effect on both types of leisure
activities. Moreover, if we compared the marginal effects of the
explanatory variables, the coefficients suggested that this effect was
higher for cultural activities. As we would expect a priori, there is
evidence of the importance of the acquisition of skills, which allows
increased appreciation and enjoyment of cultural activities (Baumol
& Bowen, 1966; Gray, 2003).
The results also showed that non-labor income had a positive effect
on both activities (only significant for females), as is suggested by
theory. Regarding the effect of the time of year, we found that sports
participation intensified during the spring and summer seasons, and
cultural participation decreased during these terms. One possible
explanation for this trend is that sports activities are held outdoors,
so the weather becomes a significant factor, whereas cultural activities
are often carried out in enclosed places. Moreover, the practice of
these activities is concentrated on weekends, when individuals have more
leisure time and lower opportunity costs of participation.
In terms of the geographic variables, it might be expected that the
likelihood of sports and cultural participation would be higher in urban
areas, especially in larger cities, where there is greater supply of
such activities. The results confirmed in some cases--based on sign,
although variables are not always significant--that participation in
sports and cultural activities is promoted by the presence of major
sports and cultural facilities in big cities.
As mentioned before, we estimated three equations: the ratios of
consumption to time allocated to sports, cultural activities, and other
leisure activities. However, we only showed the results for the relative
demands for culture and sports because these are the two equations of
interest according to the goal of our research. In Table 3, we show the
results for two of the three equations estimated. (17)
A Breusch-Pagan test was used to examine the correlation of errors
across equations. The null hypothesis of diagonal errors was rejected
because there was a positive correlation between the residuals of the
three demand equations. Therefore, time spent on sports, culture, and
other leisure activities were not independent. This finding may be
caused by the common character of both cultural activities and sports as
social activities. Thus, the individual presumably achieved his or her
desire to interact with other individuals through participation in one
activity or the other.
In accordance with our objectives, our comments exclusively address
the results regarding the relative demands for cultural activities and
sports. First, we saw that the influence of some variables on the
participation decision was different from their effect on the time
allocation decision. Therefore, participation and participation
frequency are different decisions (Humphreys & Ruseski, 2006).
To analyze the effect of these variables properly, we noted that
the signs were interpreted in the opposite direction in the estimates
because c/[l.sub.1] and c/[l.sub.2] were the dependent variables.
Thus, the relative demands for cultural activities and sports
declined in relation to hourly earnings because, when hourly earnings
grew, the opportunity costs of all types of leisure activity increased.
(18)
Additionally, we computed a Wald test with the null hypothesis that
the earnings coefficients were the same in all equations, and we
accepted this hypothesis. Thus, the results were consistent with our
theoretical model, and we concluded that the SUR method was more
convenient than ordinary least square estimation because it allowed us
to incorporate cross-equation restrictions.
A positive effect of age was identified. The relative demands of
both males and females continued to increase with age, although age was
only significant for cultural activities for females and only for sports
for males. There was no consensus in the literature about the effect of
this variable; some previous studies also found positive effects for
age, while others found the opposite effect.
The presence of children at home reduced the female probability of
participation in cultural and sports activities and the relative demand
for culture. Thus, for females, children discouraged both the choice to
participate and the frequency of participation in cultural activities.
Following Gray (2003), although having children at home implies
"childcare expenses and implicit costs in the form of parental
concern" (Gray, 2003, p. 358), we expected a priori that mothers
would like to share cultural activities with their children. However,
the results suggested the opposite effect. In previous studies on the
frequency of participation in sports, the presence of children reduced
sports participation, especially for females (Gratton & Tice, 1991;
Humphreys & Ruseski, 2006). However, in Garcia et al. (2009), this
factor positively affected the relative demand for sports of both men
and women. This finding may suggest that parents practice such
activities to ensure that their children develop a taste for sports.
The presence of adults in the household also reduced the intensity
of participation in cultural and sports activities, probably because it
increased the costs of family entertainment. Marriage undermined the
relative demands of males and females for sports and cultural
activities. Finally, it is logical that participation in these cultural
activities intensified during the weekend for females.
The significance of the correction terms of selection bias
([lambda]) confirms that the time allocation decision was logically
dependent on the decision to participate for both activities.
Conclusions
In this paper, we specified and estimated a structural neoclassical
model to analyze individual behavior concerning sports and cultural
activities and disaggregated the choices of males and females. The
dataset came from the Time Use Survey elaborated by the INE for the
period of 2002 to 2003.
To estimate the relative demands for the different types of
leisure, we applied the SUR methodology. These demands equations
[(5)-(7)] were estimated only on the subsample of individuals who
allocated time to both sports and culture during the day selected. As
this sample selection may bias the results, we controlled for possible
selection biases by including two correction terms in the demand
equations. These terms were computed from the bivariate probit estimates
calculated in the first stage.
A comparison with previous literature is not straightforward
because there is no similar homogeneous definition of cultural and
sports activities. However, most of our results concerning participation
in cultural activities--especially with respect to the effects of
education, age, marital status, and number of children--were similar to
those found in previous research. Our results also reinforced the
findings in the empirical literature on sports participation: Being
younger, educated, and having no children at home increase sports
participation.
As both sports and culture are time-intensive, family
responsibilities negatively affect both participation and participation
frequency, especially for females and for cultural activities. Our
results suggested the continued presence of a gender gap in leisure:
Women are at a substantial disadvantage because childcare is still
distributed unevenly.
Therefore, the government could promote greater job flexibility and
better work-family policies to enhance sports and culture activities on
weekdays. This opportunity cost is higher when wages increase, and the
shadow prices for cultural and sports activities increase with an
increase in predicted earnings per hour. Moreover, we suggest that many
of these activities require travel time; thus, the government should
encourage people to be more involved in the practice of sports and build
new infrastructure to reduce the gap between rural and urban areas in
our model.
Household composition also affected leisure time enjoyed by the
individual in other ways. Previous studies show that married people have
less leisure time compared to the non-married. Our results supported
these findings, showing a negative effect over sports and culture
demands--although marriage increased the probability for wives to
participate in sports.
However, practicing these activities is not free due to monetary
barriers. These barriers increase along with the family size because
sports and culture are social activities, often shared with other
household members.
The government should also try to eliminate these barriers by
subsidizing and increasing grants to low-income families. In particular,
as cultural participation is different from general leisure
recreation--because of specific training and because skills are often
necessary to appreciate cultural goods--educational barriers are
especially important in the case of culture, as shown by the calculated
marginal effects.
In summary, we found differences in time allocation for sports and
cultural activities between males and females and presented evidence for
the existence of a gender gap in free time. This result validates our
decision to conduct separate estimates based on sex and allows us to
suggest actions to be taken by public authorities.
In addition, the incorporation of a new demand equation that
measures time allocated to culture allowed us to compare different
individual leisure practices. Previous models focused only on sports and
did not allow for such comparisons.
Finally, it is worth noting that there was a positive correlation
between sports and cultural activities, both in terms of the probability
of participation and the amount of time allocated to these activities.
This finding suggests that a relationship of complementarity exists
between both activities.
References
Ahn, S. C., & Lee, Y. H. (2003). Life-cycle demand for Major
League Baseball. Paper presented at the 2003 Western Economics
Association meeting, Denver, CO.
Amemiya, T. (1985). Advanced econometrics. Cambridge, MA: Harvard
University Press.
Andreff, W., & Szymanski, S. (Eds.). (2006). Handbook on the
economics of sports. Cheltenham, United Kingdom: Edward Elgar Publishing.
Baffoe-Bonnie, J. (2009). Black-White wage differentials in a
multiple sample selection bias model. Atlantic Economic Journal, 37,
1-16.
Baumol, W. J., & Bowen, W. G. (1966). Performing arts: The
economic dilemma. Cambridge, MA: The MIT Press.
Becker, G. (1965). A theory of the allocation of time. Economic
Journal, 75, 493-517.
Becker, G., Grossman, M., & Murphy, K. M. (1994). An empirical
analysis of cigarette addiction. National Bureau of Economic Research,
Cambridge, MA.
Bittman, M., & Wajcman, J. (2000). The rush hour: The character
of leisure time and gender equity. Social Forces, 79, 165-189.
Breuer, C., & Wicker, P. (2008). Demographic and economic
factors influencing inclusion in the German sports system: A
microanalysis of the years 1985 to 2005. European Journal for Sport and
Society, 5, 35-43.
Breuer, C., & Wicker, P. (2009). Decreasing sports activity
with increasing age? Findings from a 20-year longitudinal and cohort
sequence analysis. Research Quarterly for Exercise and Sport, 80(1),
22-31.
Buraimo, B., Humphreys, B., & Simmons, R. (2010). Participation
and engagement in sport: A double hurdle approach for the United
Kingdom. Selected works of Babatunde Buraimo, University of Central
Lancashire, United Kingdom.
Cameron, A. C., & Trivedi, P. K. (2005). Microeconometrics:
Methods and applications. Cambridge, MA: Cambridge University Press.
Cawley, J. (2004). An economic framework for understanding physical
activity and eating behaviour. American Journal of Preventive Medicine,
27, 117-125.
Dawson, P., & Downward, P. (2009). Participation,
spectatorship, and media coverage in sport. Manuscript in preparation,
University of Bath, United Kingdom.
Downward, P. (2007). Exploring the economic choice to participate
in sport: Results from the 2002 General Household Survey. The
International Review of Applied Economics, 21, 633-653.
Downward, P., & Dawson, A. (2000). The economics of
professional team sports. New York: Routledge.
Downward, P., Dawson, A., & Dejonghe, T. (2009). Sports
economics: Theory, evidence, and policy. London: Butterworth-Heinemann.
Downward, P., & Rasciute, S. (2010). The relative demands for
sports and leisure in England. European Sport Management Quarterly, 10,
189-214.
Downward, P., & Riordan, J. (2007). Social interactions and the
demand for sport: An economic analysis. Contemporary Economic Policy,
25, 518-537.
Farrell, L., & Shields, M. A. (2002). Investigating the
economic and demographic determinants of sporting participation in
England. Journal of the Royal Statistical Society (A), 165, 335-348.
Fernandez-Ballesteros, R. (1998). Quality of life: Concept and
assessment. In J. Adair, D. Belanger, & K. Dion (Eds.), Advances in
psychological science: Social, personal and cultural aspects (pp.
387-406). Hove, United Kingdom: Psychology Press.
Fernandez-Ballesteros, R., Kruse, A., Zamarron, M. D., and Caprara,
M. G. (2007). Quality of life, life satisfaction, and positive aging. In
R. Fernandez-Ballestros (Ed.), Geropsychology: European perspective for
an aging world (pp. 197-223). Cambridge, MA: Hogrefe & Huber
Publishers.
Fernandez-Ballesteros, R., Zamarron, M. D., Rudinger, G., Schroots,
J. J. F., Hekkinnen, E., Drusini, A., et al. (2004). Assessing
competence: The European Survey on Aging Protocol (ESAP). Gerontology,
50, 330-347.
Fizel, J. (2006). Handbook of sports economics research. Armonk,
New York, M. E. Sharpe.
Fort, R. (2011). Sports economics (3rd ed.). Upper Saddle River,
NJ, Prentice Hall.
Friedberg, L., & Webb, A. (2006). The chore wars. Selected
works of Anthony Webb, University of Maryland, College Park, Maryland.
Garcia, J., Lera-Lopez, F., & Suarez, M. J. (2009). Estimation
of a structural model of the determinants of the time spent on physical
activity and sport: Evidence for Spain. Economic discussion paper,
Universidad de Oviedo, Asturias, Spain.
Garcia Ferrando, M. (2001a). Los Espanolesy el deporte: Practicasy
comportamientos en la ultima decada del Siglo XX. [The Spanish and
sport: Practices and behaviors in the last decade of the 20th Century.]
Madrid, Spain: Ministerio de Education, Cultura, y Deporte, Consejo
Superior de Deportes.
Garcia Ferrando, M. (2001b). La gestion del deporte en el ambito
municipal: De la promotion a la fidelizacion del cliente. [Sport
management in the municipal area: Promotion to the customer loyalty]. In
M. Latiesa et al. (Eds.), deportey cambio social en el umbral del Siglo
XXI (pp. 17-40). Madrid, Spain: Librerias Deportivas Esteban Sanz.
Garcia Ferrando, M. (2005). Globalization y deporte: Paradojas de
la globalization. [Globilization and sport: Paradoxes of globalization].
In A. Arino (Ed.), Las encrucijadas de la diversidad cultural (pp.
453-466). Madrid, Spain: Centro de Investigaciones Sociologicas.
Garcia Ferrando, M. (2006). Posmodernidad y deporte: Entre la
individualization y la masificacion [Postmodernism and sport: Between
the indiviualization and massification]. Encuesta de los Habitos
Deportivos de los Espanoles 2005. Madrid, Spain: CIS/Siglo XXI.
Gratton, C., & Tice, A. (1991). The demand for sport: A
two-stage econometric model estimated from the health and lifestyle
survey. Discussion paper, Manchester Polytechnic, United Kingdom.
Gray, C. M. (2003). Participation. In R. Towse (Ed.), A handbook of
cultural economics (pp. 356-365). Cheltenham, United Kingdom: Edward
Elgar.
Greene, W. (2008). Econometric analysis (6th ed.). New York:
Prentice Hall.
Ham, J. C. (1982). Estimation of a labour supply model with
censoring due to unemployment and underemployment. Review of Economic
Studies, 49, 335-354.
Heckman, J. J. (1979). Sample selection bias as a specification
error. Econometrica, 47, 153-61.
Hovemann, G., & Wicker, P. (2009). Determinants of sport
participation in the European Union. European Journal for Sport and
Society, 6, 51-59.
Humphreys, B., & Ruseski, J. (2006). Economic determinants of
participation in physical activity and sport. Manuscript in preparation,
University of Illinois, Urbana-Champaign.
Humphreys, B., & Ruseski, J. (2007). Participation in physical
activity and government spending on parks and recreation. Contemporary
Economic Policy, 25, 538-552.
Humphreys, B., & Ruseski, J. (2009). The economics of
participation and time spent in physical activity. Manuscript in
preparation, University of Alberta, Canada.
Humphreys, B., & Ruseski, J. (2010). The economic choice of
participation and time spent in physical activity and sport in Canada.
Manuscript in preparation, University of Alberta, Canada.
Humphreys, B., Soebbing, B., & Lee, Y. (2010). Consumer
behaviour in lottery: The double hurdle approach and zeros in gambling
survey data. International Gambling Studies, 10, 165-172.
Instituto Nacional de Estadistica (2004). La Encuesta de Empleo del
Tiempo [Spanish Time Use Survey 2002-2003]. Madrid, Spain: Author.
Johnston, J., & Dinardo, J. (1997). Econometric methods (4th
ed.). New York: McGraw-Hill.
Juster, F. T., & Stafford, F. P. (1991). The allocation of
time: Empirical findings, behavioral models, and problems of
measurement. Journal of Economic Literature, 29, 471-522.
Kesenne, S. (1981). Time-allocation and the linear expenditure
system. Recherces Economiques de Louvain, 46, 113-123.
Kesenne, S. (1983). Substitution in consumption: An application to
the allocation of time. European Economic Review, 23, 231-239.
Kesenne, S., & Butzen, P. (1987). Subsidizing sports
facilities: The shadow price-elasticities of sports. Applied Economics,
19, 101-110.
Kopczynski, M., & Hager, M. (2003). Denver: Performing arts
research coalition community report 2002. Denver, CO: Pew Charitable
Trusts.
Kurabayashi, Y., & Ito, T. (1992). Socio-economic
characteristics of audiences for western classical music in Japan: A
statistical analysis. In R. Towse & A. Khakee (Eds.), Cultural
economics (pp. 275-287). Heidelberg, Germany: Springer-Verlag.
Lagardera Otero, F. (1992). Deporte y calidad de vida: La sociedad
deportivizada [Sport and quality of life: The sportsmanship society]. In
C. Garcia Lopez (coord.), Actas del 80 Congreso Cientifico Olimpico 1992
(pp. 412-423). Benalmadena, Spain: Instituto Andaluz del Deporte, Junta de Andalucia.
Lee, Y. H., & Smith, T. G. (2008). Why are Americans addicted
to baseball? An empirical analysis of fandom in Korea and the United
States. Contemporary Economic Policy, 26, 32-48.
Leeds, M., & Von Allmen, P. (2002).The economics of sports.
Boston, MA: Addison-Wesley.
Lera-Lopez, F., & Rapun-Garate, M. (2005). Sports participation
versus consumer expenditure on sport: Different determinants and
strategies in sports management. European Sports Management Quarterly,
5, 167-186.
Lera-Lopez, F., & Rapun-Garate, M. (2007). The demand for
sport: Sport consumption and participation models. Journal of Sport
Management, 21, 103-122.
Levy-Garboua, L., & Montmarquette, C. (1996). A
microeconometric study of theater demand. Journal of Cultural Economics,
20, 25-50.
Levy-Garboua, L., & Montmarquette, C. (2002). The demand for
the arts. Presented in a scientific series at Centre Interuniversitarie
de Reserche and Analyze des Organizations, Montreal, Canada.
Loyland, K., & Ringstad, V. (2009). On the price and income
sensitivity of the demand for sports: Has Linder's disease become
more serious? Journal of Sports Economics, 10, 601-618.
Loyland, K., & Ringstad, V. (2010). Borrowing demand at local
public libraries in Sweden. Presented at the 16th International
Conference on Cultural Economics by the Association for Childhood
Education International, Copenhagen, Denmark.
Maddala, G. S. (1983). Limited dependent and qualitative variables
in econometrics. Cambridge, England: Cambridge University Press.
Martinez del Castillo, J., Jimenez-Beatty, J. E., Graupera, J. L.,
& Rodriguez, M. L. (2006). Condiciones de vida, socializacion, y
actividad fisica en la vejez [Living conditions, socialization, and
physical activity in old age]. Revista International de Sociologia, 44,
39-62.
Martinez del Castillo, J., Vazquez, B., Graupera, J. L.,
Jimenez-Beatty, J. E., Alfaro, E., Hernandez, M., & Avelino, D.
(2005). Estudio sobre la actividad fisicay deportiva de las mujeres del
municipio de Madrid: Habitos, demandas, y barreras [Study about sport
and physical activity of women in the municipality of Madrid: Habits,
demands, and barriers]. Madrid, Spain: Ayuntamiento de Madrid, Area de
Gobierno de Empleo y Servicios a la Ciudadania.
Mattingly, M. J., & Bianchi, S. M. (2003). Gender differences
in the quantity and quality of free time: The U.S. experience. Social
Forces, 81, 999-1030.
Mattingly, M. J., & Sayer, L. C. (2006). Under pressure: Gender
differences in the relationship between free time and feeling rushed.
Journal of Marriage and Family, 68, 205-221.
McCarthy, K. F., & Jinnett, K. (2001). A new framework for
building participation in the arts. Santa Monica, CA: Rand.
McConnell, K. (1992). On-site time in the demand for recreation.
American Journal of Agricultural Economics, 74, 918-25.
Montgomery, S. S., & Robinson, M. D. (2006). Take me out to the
opera: Are sports and arts complements? Evidence from the performing
arts research coalition data. International Journal of Arts Management,
8, 24-37.
Montgomery, S. S., & Robinson, M. D. (2008). Dick and Jane go
to the ballet or was it the baseball game? Empirical evidence on the
battle of sexes within a human capital appreciation model. Presented at
the 15th International Conference on Cultural Economics by the
Association for Cultural Economics International, Northeastern
University, Boston, MA.
Montgomery, S. S., & Robinson, M. D. (2010). Empirical evidence
of the effects of marriage on male and female attendance at sports and
arts. Social Science Quarterly, 91(1), 99-116.
Moscoso, D. (2005). La construction social y cultural del liderazgo
en el deporte. [Social construction and cultural leadership in sport].
Apunts: Education Fisica y Deportes, 79, 5-12.
Mulligan, C. B., Schneider, B., & Wolfe, R. (2005).
Non-response and population representation in studies on adolescent time
use. Electronic International Journal of Time Use Research, 2, 33-53.
Pommerehne, W., & Kirchgassner, G. (1987). The impact of
television on the demand for cinema and theatre performances. In N. K.
Grant et al. (Eds.), Economic efficiency and the performing arts (pp.
44-61). Akron, OH: Association for Cultural Economics.
Prieto-Rodriguez, J., & V. Fernandez-Blanco (2000, May). Are
live sports substitutes of culture consumption? Some evidence for the
Spanish Case. Presented at the ACEI 11th International Biennial Conference, Minneapolis, MN.
Prieto-Rodriguez, J., & Fernandez-Blanco, V. (2000). Are
popular and classical music listeners the same people? Journal of
Cultural Economics, 24, 147-164.
Puig, N., & Soler, S. (2004). Mujer y deporte en Espana: Estado
de la cuestion y propuesta interpretativa [Women and Sport in Spain:
Current situation and proposed interpretive]. Apunts: Educacion Fisica y
Deportes, 76, 71-78.
Sandy, R., Sloane, P., & Rosentraub, M. (2004). The economics
of sport: An international perspective. New York: Palgrave Macmillan.
Seaman, B. A. (2005). Attendance and public participation in the
performing arts: A review of the empirical literature. Manuscript in
preparation, Georgia State University, Atlanta, GA.
Spenner, E. L., Fenn A. J., & Crooker, J. R. (2004). The demand
for NFL attendance: A rational addiction model. Manuscript in
preparation, Colorado College, Colorado Springs.
Stern, N. (1986). On the specification of labour supply functions.
In R. Blundell & I. Walker (Eds.), Unemployment, search, and labour
supply (pp. 143-189). Cambridge, United Kingdom: Cambridge University
Press.
Stigler, G. J., & Becker, G. S. (1977). De gustibus non est
disputandum [Taste of a dispute]. American Economic Review, 67, 76-90.
Stratton, M., Conn, L., Liaw, C., & Connolly, L. (2005). Sport
and related physical activity: The social correlates of participation
and non-participation by adults. Presented at a Sport Management
Association of Australia and New Zealand Conference, Canberra,
Australia.
Swanson, S. R., Davis, J. C., & Zhao, Y. (2008). Art for
art's sake? An examination of motives for arts performance
attendance. Nonprofit and Voluntary Sector Quarterly, 37, 300-323.
Throsby, D. (1994). The production and consumption of the arts: A
view of cultural economics. Journal of Economic Literature, 32, 1-29.
Wicker, P., Breuer, C., & Pawlowski, T. (2009). Promoting sport
for all to age specific target groups: The impact of sport
infrastructure. European Sports Management Quarterly, 9, 103-118.
Zabalza, A., (1983). The CES utility function, non-linear budget
constraints, and labour supply: Results on female participation and
hours. Economic Journal, 93, 312-330.
Authors' Note
We would like to thank Paul Downward and Jaume Garcia for detailed
comments and helpful research assistance on earlier drafts of this
paper. We are very grateful to two anonymous referees for useful
comments on the previous version of this paper. The usual disclaimer
applies.
Cristina Muniz [2], Placido Rodriguez [2], and Maria J. Suarez [1]
[1] Fundacion Observatorio Economico del Deporte
[2] University of Oviedo, Spain
Cristina Muniz is an assistant professor and researcher at the
University of Oviedo, Spain. She is also a member of the research team
of the Fundacion Observatorio Economico del Deporte. Her main research
interests are the behavior of participants in sport as well as the
analysis of the demand for performing arts.
Placido Rodriguez is a professor and researcher at the University
of Oviedo, Spain. He is Director of the Fundacion Observatorio Economico
del Deporte and also President of the International Association of
Sports Economists (IASE). He is a co-editor with S. Kesenne and J.
Garcia of the book Sports Economics after Fifty Years: Essays in Honour
of Simon Rottenberg. He is also former President of Real Sporting de
Gijon.
Maria J. Suarez is senior lecturer of economics at the Department
of Economics of the University of Oviedo, Spain. Her research interests
include labor and sports economics.
Endnotes
(1) Downward and Dawson (2000); Leeds and Von Allmen (2002); Sandy
et al. (2004); Fizel (2006); Andreff and Szymanski (2006); Downward,
Dawson, and Dejonghe (2009); and Fort (2011).
(2) For the attendance-only case, researchers are beginning to
support the notion that fans display characteristics of rational
addiction (as in cultural goods, as discussed below) in their
consumption behavior. See Becker, Grossman, and Murphy (1994); Ahn and
Lee (2003); Spenner et al. (2004); and Lee and Smith (2008).
(3) More recently, Humphreys and Ruseski (2010) also found a
similar result: Higher incomes are again associated with higher
participation and less time spent on sports, although the income effect
is now small.
(4) However, other authors only performed empirical analyses: for
example Farrell and Shields (2002), Stratton et al. (2005), Breuer and
Wicker (2009), and Hovemann and Wicker (2009).
(5) See Throsby (1994) for an analysis of other art forms.
(6) See also Montgomery and Robinson (2010), who analyze
differences in time allocation by sex.
(7) See, for example, Zabalza (1983) and Kesenne (1983). In
particular, Kesenne (1983) assumes CES utility functions to analyze
substitution in consumption for leisure and non-leisure activities
within the Becker framework of the allocation of time. The Stone-Geary
function has also been used in consumption studies, but its performance
has been disappointing when leisure is incorporated into the set of
commodities (Zabalza, 1983). Moreover, in the field of sports economics,
Downward and Rasciute (2010) use a Cobb-Douglas utility function, which
is more restrictive than the CES because it implies that the elasticity
of substitution is equal to 1.
(8) See Stern (1986) for details on the specification of different
functional forms for the utility function.
(9) The model developed by Humphreys and Ruseski (2006) contains a
full budget constraint that includes time and monetary cost of
participation in sport.
(10) The fieldwork was conducted for a full year from October 7,
2002, until October 5, 2003; information was obtained weekly.
(11) Researchers seem to agree that the diary is the best option
because the measure of time allocation is more accurate than in other
methods. However, diaries also have the disadvantages of sometimes being
so general as to be misleading when examining multi-tasking (Juster
& Stafford, 1991) and containing biases due to lack of response
(Friedberg & Webb, 2006) or inaccurate estimates of time use during
a week or a month (Mulligan et al., 2005).
(12) The time spent on other leisure activities also must be
positive, but all individuals met this condition.
(13) We can observe a zero value of time allocated to sports or
culture either because the person did not participate in that activity
the day the information was collected (infrequency of consumption) or
because the individual never participated in it. The sample selection
model does not take into account these possibilities (Buraimo,
Humphreys, & Simmons, 2010; Humphreys et al., 2010). However, the
double hurdle model distinguishes both mechanisms that may generate
zeros: participation in consumption and corner solutions.
(14) Predicted earnings were computed from a wage equation
estimated using the subsample of workers and applying Heckman's
two-stage method (Heckman, 1979). The estimation process was not
detailed in this paper but is available by request.
(15) According to Maddala (1983), Amemiya (1985), and Johnston and
DiNardo (1997), at least one of the explanatory variables in the first
equation must be excluded in the second step for identification.
However, as Downward and Riordan (2007) point out, finding variables
that are excluded from the frequency equation, but not the probability
of participation equation, is difficult and arbitrary in many cases.
(16) Downward and Riordan (2007) identify the equations by allowing
alternative functional forms in the error terms.
(17) The results of the relative demand for other leisure
activities are available upon request.
(18) Downward and Riordan (2007) find the same effect.
Table 1. Summary Statistics of Explanatory Variables
(N = 360)
Variable Definition
Socioeconomic and demographic characteristics
AGE Age of respondent
MARRIED 1 if respondent is married; 0 otherwise
NCHILD12 1 if household includes children aged 12
years or younger; 0 otherwise
NLABINC Non-labor individual income: Calculated as
income from other household members.
EDUC1 1 if respondent completed primary education;
0 otherwise.
EDUC2 1 if respondent completed secondary
education; 0 otherwise.
EDUC3 1 if respondent completed university
degree; 0 otherwise.
WEEKEND 1 if day is Saturday or Sunday; 0 otherwise.
ILL 1 if respondent is ill, unfit, or has a
disability; 0 otherwise.
QUART1 1 if month is January, February, or March;
0 otherwise
QUART2 1 if month is April, May, or June;
0 otherwise
QUART3 1 if month is July, August, or September;
0 otherwise
URB2 1 if respondent lives in a township with
more than 100,000 inhabitants; 0 otherwise
URB3 1 if respondent lives in a township with
less than 100,000 inhabitants; 0 otherwise
ADULT3 1 if respondent lives in a household with
more than 2 adults; 0 otherwise
REGION Dummies for Andalucia, Aragon, Asturias,
Baleares, Canarias, Cantabria, Castilla-Leon,
Castilla-La Mancha, Cataluna, Comunidad
Valenciana, Extremadura, Galicia, Murcia,
Navarra, Pais Vasco, and La Rioja
LOG W Logarithm of hourly predicted earnings,
computed from a wage equation through
Heckman's two-stage method
Variable Mean Standard
deviation
Socioeconomic and demographic characteristics
AGE 38.8195 14.3404
MARRIED 0.4806 0.5004
NCHILD12 0.2444 0.5936
NLABINC 1242.778 1055.208
EDUC1 0.26944 0.4443
EDUC2 0.3611 0.4810
EDUC3 0.275 0.4472
WEEKEND 0.6228 0.4900
ILL 0.1639 0.3707
QUART1 0.2806 0.4499
QUART2 0.2362 0.4253
QUART3 0.2362 0.4253
URB2 0.0916 0.2890
URB3 0.4195 0.4942
ADULT3 0.4556 0.4988
REGION
LOG W 1.7013 0.3225
Table 2 Bivariate Probit: Cultural and Sports
Participation of Males and Females.
Explanatory Males
variables
Cultural activities Sports
Coefficient t Coefficient t
Age -0.0382 -3.59 -0.0525 -7.75
Agesq 0.0421 3.31 0.0750 9.41
Married -0.1626 -2.94 -0.0518 -1.49
Nchild12 -0.0486 -1.38 -0.0565 -2.70
Educ1 0.1752 2.84 0.0428 1.30
Educ2 0.4439 7.08 0.0891 2.47
Educ3 0.5892 8.53 0.2244 5.30
Ill 0.0572 1.07 0.1875 5.86
Weekend 0.4363 11.67 0.4858 19.88
Quart1 -0.1050 -2.03 -0.0329 -1.00
Quart2 -0.0589 -1.13 0.0528 1.59
Quart3 -0.0527 -0.98 0.0861 2.52
Urb2 -0.0165 -0.22 0.0315 0.67
Urb3 -0.0419 -1.01 -0.0785 -2.99
Adult3 -0.0920 -2.18 -0.0308 -1.16
Andalu -0.0780 -1.07 0.0808 1.77
Aragon 0.0561 0.47 0.0263 0.33
Asturi -0.0218 -0.18 0.2131 2.84
Balear -0.0546 -0.36 -0.0602 -0.66
Canari 0.1131 1.07 0.1359 1.81
Cantab -0.1487 -1.20 0.1351 1.81
Castle 0.0408 0.41 0.2825 4.40
Castma 0.0209 0.18 0.0410 0.57
Catalu 0.0719 0.96 0.0076 0.16
Valenc 0.1937 2.12 0.0714 1.16
Extrem 0.1049 0.82 0.3171 3.83
Galici 0.0162 0.19 0.1452 2.66
Murcia -0.2330 -1.70 -0.0461 -0.60
Navarra 0.0387 0.37 0.2455 3.65
Pvasco 0.0331 0.25 0.3557 4.20
Rioja -0.0499 -0.36 0.2178 2.55
Nlabinc 0.0001 0.67 0.0001 1.26
Explanatory Females
variables
Cultural activities Sports
Coefficient t Coefficient t
Age -0.0027 -0.27 -0.2798 -4.57
Agesq 0.0011 0.09 0.0408 5.62
Married -0.2028 -4.41 0.0943 3.25
Nchild12 -0.1196 -3.78 -0.0363 -2.00
Educ1 0.1891 3.55 0.0784 2.67
Educ2 0.3261 5.57 0.0141 0.41
Educ3 0,4507 7.19 0.1230 3.15
Ill 0.0296 0.60 -0.0093 -0.31
Weekend 0.4473 13.06 0.2292 10.27
Quart1 -0.0929 -2.00 0.0228 0.76
Quart2 -0.1199 -2.53 0.1127 3.77
Quart3 -0.1289 -2.60 0.1528 4.94
Urb2 -0.0498 -0.73 0.0459 1.09
Urb3 -0.0840 -2.23 -0.0175 -0.73
Adult3 -0.1011 -2.65 -0.0241 -1.01
Andalu -0.0205 -0.31 -0.0113 -0.27
Aragon -0.0354 -0.30 0.1126 1.56
Asturi 0.1562 1.50 0.0594 0.87
Balear 0.1043 0.80 0.0054 0.06
Canari 0.0065 0.06 -0.0246 -0.40
Cantab -0.0065 -0.06 0.2621 3.75
Castle -0.0216 -0.22 0.4017 6.81
Castma 0.0073 0.07 0.0724 1.11
Catalu 0.1177 1.68 0.0089 0.20
Valenc 0.3525 4.35 0.0127 0.23
Extrem 0.2184 1.97 0.3310 4.60
Galici 0.0129 0.16 0.0919 1.87
Murcia -0.1904 -1.42 0.1693 2.40
Navarra 0.1961 2.04 0.3317 5.21
Pvasco 0.1886 1.62 0.4222 5.49
Rioja -0.1068 -0.74 0.2244 2.74
Nlabinc 0.0001 1.26 0.0001 4.61
Table 3. Relative Demands for Sports and Cultural Activities
of Males and Females
Explanatory Males
variables
Cultural activities Sports
log c/[l.sub.1] log c/[l.sub.2]
Coefficient t Coefficient t
Log W 0.9826 6.23 0.9826 6.23
Age -0.0554 -1.85 -0.0175 -0.64
Agesq 0.0412 1.14 0.0041 0.12
Married 0.4852 3.02 0.3646 2.53
Nchild12 0.0732 0.71 0.1137 1.22
Adult3 0.4625 4.35 0.2270 2.38
Weekend -0.1213 -0.81 -0.1781 -1.32
Lambda2 0.0369 0.17 0.1566 0.79
Lambda3 3.2971 2.06 3.2501 2.22
[R.sup.2] 0.1662 0.1778
Sample size 360
Explanatory Females
variables
Cultural activities Sports
log c/[l.sub.1] log c/[l.sub.2]
Coefficient t Coefficient t
Log W 0.8819 7.85 0.8819 7.85
Age -0.0230 -0.85 -0.0521 -1.98
Agesq 0.0125 0.38 0.0386 1.21
Married 0.3372 2.44 0.4754 3.54
Nchild12 0.0757 0.84 0.1563 1.78
Adult3 0.6025 6.01 0.6117 6.27
Weekend 0.0265 0.23 -0.1922 -1.75
Lambda2 0.2039 1.25 0.4879 3.07
Lambda3 1.5682 1.79 2.3614 2.77
[R.sup.2] 0.1924 0.2334
Sample size 389