An analysis of the last hour of betting in the NFL.
Paul, Rodney J. ; Weinbach, Andrew P.
The betting market for the National Football League (NFL) takes the
form of a simple financial market. While betting on soccer, baseball,
and hockey games is generally tied to odds, most of the betting on
football in North America is based on a pointspread system. In
pointspread betting, when two teams are unevenly matched, the superior
team must win by more than a specified number of points (the
pointspread) in order for bettors to win. For example, Minnesota played
New Orleans in the first game of the 2010 NFL season. New Orleans was
viewed as the better team, and most sportsbooks offered wagering on this
game with a pointspread of 4.5; that is, New Orleans as the favorite
(New Orleans -4.5 or Minnesota +4.5). New Orleans won that game by a
score of 14 to 9 (a margin of victory of 5), just enough to cover the
pointspread and leaving New Orleans bettors as winners. As the underdog,
Minnesota bettors could have won with a Minnesota victory--a tie, rare
in the NFL, or a loss by fewer than 4.5 points. In the totals market,
sometimes called the over/under market, an overbettor will win the wager
when more points are scored by both teams than the total posted by the
sportsbook. An underbetter wins when both teams score fewer points are
than the posted total. In the Minnesota at New Orleans example, the
posted total was 48.5 and only 23 points were scored, so underbettors
won their bets. If the favorite wins by exactly the pointspread, or the
combined points of both teams equals the totals, the bet is considered a
push and all money is returned to the bettor.
In pointspread betting markets in the United States, most
sportsbooks generate commissions by offering wagers based on what is
sometimes called the 11-for-10 rule, in which bettors must risk $11 to
win $10. Under these rules, bettors must win more than 52.4% of the time
to overcome the commission on bets charged by the sportsbook--sometimes
called the vig or vigorish--and generate positive earnings. Given the
simple form of this financial market with a large number of interested
participants, generally widespread availability of game results, and
betting lines (pointspreads and totals), sports wagering markets became
a natural place to test the efficient markets hypothesis. If all
information is incorporated in the closing pointspread or total on a
given football game, the pointspread and total should serve as optimal
and unbiased forecasts of the score differential (favorite minus
underdog score) and combined points scored in a game, respectively.
Under the traditional models of sportsbook behavior--such as
Pankoff (1968), Zuber, et al. (1985), and Sauer, et al.
(1988)--sportsbooks were assumed to set a market-clearing price by
balancing the book. This price theoretically would attract equal amounts
of money on each side of the wagering proposition. Setting prices that
balance the book allows sportsbooks to earn risk-free returns when
balanced wagering is achieved, with sportsbooks earning their commission
on losing bets (under an 11-for-10 betting rule). A number of studies on
pointspread markets concluded that the null hypothesis of market
efficiency could not be rejected, despite significant public sentiment.
These results served as a significant stamp of approval for this theory
and supported the notion of the general wisdom of crowds.
Recently, detailed data on sportsbooks and sports gamblers have
allowed for a more comprehensive study of the sports wagering market for
the NFL and other sports. In the last few years, data on betting
percentages on favorites/underdogs and overs/unders, and even forms of
betting volume, have become available in addition to standard data on
pointspread, totals, and odds. The availability of this data has allowed
for an investigation of the traditional balanced book hypothesis when it
comes to the behavior of the sportsbook. If sportsbooks do not price to
balance the book--by attracting equal amounts of betting dollars on each
side of the betting proposition--then natural extensions to testing the
efficient markets hypothesis and other financial theories suddenly
become less straightforward: Prices may not reflect the actions of
bettors themselves but actually reflect sportsbook incentives.
Levitt (2004) suggested that sportsbooks may not price to balance
the book but may actually price to maximize profits. Under the Levitt
(2004) hypothesis, this profit maximization, occurs as sportsbooks
incorporate biases of sports gamblers into their prices, leading to
unbalanced action and potentially biased closing prices. Levitt (2004)
used data from a sports betting tournament to illustrate that road
favorites are over-bet by gamblers, leading to profitability when
wagering on home underdogs. Levitt suggested that sportsbooks
purposefully set biased prices to maximize profits; they do this by
earning greater returns in cases in which sports bettors were heavily
weighted on the side that lost more often than implied by efficiency.
Using data from Sportsbook.com and three sportsbooks compiled on
Sportsinsights.com, Paul and Weinbach (2008a, 2011) found that
sportsbooks are not balanced--that is, the percentage bet on favorites
increases with the magnitude of the favorite, and the percentage bet on
overs increases with the magnitude of the total. Given that the balanced
book hypothesis was rejected, some evidence was found in support of the
Levitt (2004) hypothesis: Underdogs who attracted very little of the
betting action outperformed the overbet favorites, resulting in
statistical profitability in a variety of cases.
In studies of other sports, however, Paul and Weinbach (2008b,
2009, 2010) found that the Levitt hypothesis was not supported. The
balanced book hypothesis was found to be soundly rejected for the NBA,
college football, and the NHL, but pointspreads did not appear to be
biased. Although the same preferences exist for gamblers (for favorites
and overs), simple betting strategies, which were found to be profitable
for the NFL, were shown to win very close to 50% of the time as the
efficient markets hypothesis could not be rejected for these sports.
Paul and Weinbach (2008b, 2009, 2010) suggested that sportsbooks may
actually price as a forecast, rather than to balance the books
(traditional sportsbook) or to exploit known bettor biases (Levitt
hypothesis) and thereby leading all simple strategies to win 50% of the
time. This pricing as a forecast allows the sportsbook to earn its
commission on losing bets in the long run. By viewing sports betting as
a repeated game rather than a one-shot game, sportsbooks may not care
about the game-to-game imbalances in betting dollars as long as the
prices they set are expected to split victories and losses evenly
between favorites and underdogs (and overs and unders).
We extend the analysis of more detailed betting data to the last
hours of trading for the NFL. In the betting markets for horse racing,
it is generally accepted that late betting action (right before the
start of the race) is more likely to represent information, as informed
bettors may wait until right before the close of betting to analyze the
tote board prices and calculate odds which may be in their favor. Horse
racing is parimutuel--that is, odds are not known at the time the bet is
placed and betting odds are calculated based upon all bets made on the
race after taking out the track take--and sports bettors in the sports
wagering markets "lock-in" the wager at the price when the
wager is placed. Although the horse racing market is quite different
from the market for sports betting, it is still useful to examine
whether the close of the betting market in the NFL wagering market is
similar to that of horse racing. In other words, we attempt to answer
the question, if betting action--which occurs near kickoff (the start of
the game)--represents information, is it pure noise or does it represent
potential biases of NFL fans who wish to wager on games as a form of
consumption?
We attempt to answer this question by comparing the betting
percentages on favorites and underdogs and overs and unders one hour
before kickoff of an NFL game and at the close of the market. These
detailed data were gathered for three NFL regular seasons: 2008-2009
through 2010-2011. We attempt to determine if following the late-betting
action leads to profitable returns, if these strategies essentially
break even, or if the late action is actually on the wrong side of the
betting proposition. We use an overall analysis of the data coupled with
simple betting simulations to address these issues.
NFL Last Hour of Trading
In betting markets such as horse racing, it is generally believed
that actions at the close of the betting market (start of the race)
represent information. Ottaviani and Sorensen (2008) suggest that late
bets in pari-mutuel markets tend to contain superior information about
the finishing order of horses. This result is driven by the point that
individuals with private information can benefit by waiting until just
before post time--this reduces the opportunities for others to respond
by following their wagers, which would lower returns in a pari-mutuel
system. This is consistent with the findings of Asch, Malkiel, and
Quandt (1982) as it relates to the horse racing market.
The betting market for horse racing is quite different than that of
professional sports wagering. The horse racing market is pari-mutuel, as
actual betting odds are only determined after all wagers have been
placed (and the take of the track removed). In professional sports
betting, such as the market for the NFL, the price of the wager is known
at the time of the bet. This price is the pointspread, and its value is
locked at the time the wager is placed. Ottaviani and Sorensen (2005)
note that, in fixed-odds betting, bettors with inside information have
no incentive to wager late as a means of concealing their own actions.
However, there still may be a benefit to betting late: The bettor may
learn more information by observing the actions of others. In addition,
all relevant information on the significance of injuries, game plans,
weather, and other variables may not be known until shortly before
kickoff. Gandar, Dare, and colleagues (1998) and Gandar, Zuber, and Dare
(2000) find that closing pointspreads and totals are superior to opening
pointspreads and totals. They suggest that informed traders are
responsible for the line moves between the open and close of betting.
If late betting action in the NFL is not dominated by informed
bettors and is purely the action of recreational bettors--who bet as
fans of the game rather than sophisticated investors--these late bets
may not reflect information at all. These consumption-based wagers could
reflect bettor biases for the best and most popular teams, which could
help to identify betting situations where prices--in particular favorite
prices--may be slightly inflated. Under this scenario, wagering against
the preferences of the public may actually be profitable. If the biased
preferences of the public are incorporated into the pointspread, taking
a contrarian position to the preferences of the general bettors could
win more often than implied by efficiency.
Table 1 summarizes the information we were able to obtain from
Sports Insights concerning betting action during the last hour of
betting on an NFL game. Sports Insights uses data from three online
sportsbooks: BetUS.com, CaribSports.com, and SportBet.com. Using
real-time data available on their website, we were able to gather
information on the percentage bet on the favorite and underdog, both at
the start of the game and one hour before the start of each game. At
these points in time, we were able to capture the betting volume in
terms of number of bets; the percentage bet on the favorite and
underdog, and over and under; and the pointspread/total at these times.
In addition, the movement of the prices in these betting
markets--pointspreads and totals--were captured one hour before market
close. Averages and standard deviations of these price movements are
also presented in Table 1. These data were calculated from that
information. We split the data into home favorite games and road
favorite games due to past winning strategies shown in the NFL related
to home underdogs (Levitt, 2004; Golec & Tamarkin, 1991; Gray &
Gray, 1997).
The number of bets placed in the last hour was around 18,000-19,000
for NFL games. On average, games with home favorites attracted over
18,000 bets, while games with road favorites attracted over 19,000 bets.
This is consistent with findings that road favorites in the NFL are
generally more popular propositions with bettors (see Levitt, 2004). In
the last hour before kickoff, these numbers of bets translated into
nearly 23% of the total betting action for NFL games--22.86% for home
favorites and 22.93% for road favorites. Therefore, nearly a quarter of
the betting action occurs in the 60 min leading up to the start of an
NFL game.
On average, the side that the public was backing in the last hour
of betting differed based on whether there was a home favorite or road
favorite. The percentage of bets on home favorites increased slightly
during the last hour, but the percentage of bets on road favorites
decreased by over a half of a percentage point on average in the last
hour. This could represent some evidence of informed bettors wagering on
home underdogs, which have been found to generate positive returns in
the past in the NFL and other sports.
In relation to the totals market, the percentage bet on the over
increased in the last hour for both games, with home favorites and with
road favorites. Games with road favorites increased more than games with
home favorites, which may imply that road favorite bettors also wagered
on the over in these contests.
By the time of market close, the betting public was found to bet
more heavily on the favorite and the over, as was shown previously for
the NFL by Paul and Weinbach (2008a). This shows that the sportsbook is
not perfectly balanced, as the predictable sides of the wager--favorites
and overs--consistently attract a greater percentage of the betting
action. As also was shown in Paul and Weinbach (2008a), road favorites
attract a much higher percentage of the bets (over 70% on average)
compared with home favorites (nearly 57% on average). The over was shown
to attract over 65% of the betting action for both home and road
favorites.
The average pointspread and total move during the last hour is
close to zero for all studied wagering propositions. For home favorites,
the average pointspread move was slightly toward the underdog and
slightly toward the under. On the other hand, for road favorites, the
average pointspread move was slightly toward the road favorite and the
over. This does not imply that pointspreads and totals do not move in
the last hour of betting before an NFL kickoff; it only illustrates that
the average value of news is zero within this betting market. (1)
Tables 2 and 3 present results of simple betting simulations from
the NFL for the 2008-2009 through 2010-2011 seasons. Results of placing
wagers on favorites and underdogs are shown for the situations in the
last hour of betting, where the percentage of bets increased on the
favorite and increased on the underdog. These results are shown for both
home underdogs and road underdogs. In addition, results are combined to
show the winning percentages of simple strategies of wagering against
the percentage change toward favorites and underdogs overall (both home
and road favorites) and for a strategy of wagering against all
pointspread changes. These strategies are simply contrarian wagering
positions, as the strategy used in these betting simulations only means
wagering against the more popular side of the betting proposition in the
last hour before kickoff. Log likelihood ratio tests, which do not
impose an equal mean and median restriction on the forecast errors, are
used to test the winning percentage of these strategies compared to the
null hypothesis, winning of a fair bet (win 50% of the time). Compared
to the null hypothesis of no profitability, winning 52.4% of the time is
enough to overcome the implicit commission charged with the sports-book
lay 11-to-10 rule, as outlined in Evan and Noble (1992).
In observing the betting results--based upon how the betting
percentages on the favorite/underdog and over/under change--a few points
are readily apparent. Wagering against the betting public when they are
wagering on the favorite in the last hour appears to be a winning
proposition. For home favorites, betting against the preferences of the
betting public when they wager on the favorite in the last hour wins
over 59% of the time, and it is found to be statistically significant at
the 5% level. For road favorites, betting against the public wagering on
the favorite in the last hour wins twothirds of the time in a very small
sample. This result was found to be statistically significant at the 10%
level.
Betting on the underdog, specifically when the percentage bet on
the favorite increases in the last hour, wins over 60% of the time. This
is significant at the 1% level, compared with a fair bet (winning 50% of
the time). It is significant at the 5% level, compared to the null
hypothesis of no profitability: winning 52.4% of the time, enough to
overcome the 11-to-10 rule at the sportsbook. In addition, the strategy
of wagering against all changes in betting percentages in the last hour
before the start of the game wins nearly 55% of the time; it was found
to be significant at the 10% level.
The totals market does not offer any findings of statistical
significance in relation to betting against (or on) changes in betting
percentages in the last hour before the start of an NFL game. However,
wagering against changes in betting percentages was shown to win more
than 50% of the time (51.36%). As mentioned, the threshold to earn
profits was not met for this sample, nor was the null hypothesis of a
fair bet (winning 50% of the time) rejected.
These results clearly show that there is not information embedded in wagers that occur in the hour leading up to kickoff in NFL games.
Late information--in relation to injuries, game plans, weather, and
other factors--does not appear to be used by bet tors to exploit
informational advantages and earn profits. In fact, wagering against the
actions of the betting public was shown to earn statistically
significant profits. This supports previous findings that show NFL
betting as a consumption activity for fans in which wagers are placed on
games to increase the enjoyment of watching NFL football. Access to
information--specifically regarding which propositions the public is
placing wagers in the last hour--provides insight into where contrarian
bettors can win often enough to reject market efficiency and earn
statistically significant profits.
Conclusions
Through the examination of actual betting percentages from three
online sports-books--gathered through data available on
http://www.sportsinsights.com--the last hour of betting before the start
of NFL games was analyzed. In the gambling market for horse racing,
there is general sentiment and some evidence to support that informed
bettors tend to wager near the start of the race. There is little
evidence to support late betting as informed betting in the wagering
market for professional football in the United States. In fact, there is
evidence that wagering against the preferences of the public, which are
evident in the last hour before kickoff, actually leads to profitability
as market efficiency can be rejected.
More than 22% of all wagering occurred in the last hour before
kickoff in the NFL. For the online sportsbooks from which the data were
gathered, this accounted for nearly 20,000 wagers on each game in the 60
min leading up to kickoff. On average, more of the bets accrued to home
teams in the sides markets, as both home favorites and home underdogs
attracted more wagers in the last hour. In the totals market, more
wagers were found to be on the over during this same time span.
Favorites and overs attracted the most wagers, well above 50%; this
clearly rejects the notion of the sports-book attempting to balance the
book. The average pointspread move was close to zero, even though the
public clearly favored the home team and the over in the last hour.
Simple betting simulations were performed using the changes in
betting percentages. When the betting percentages changed in the last
hour toward the home favorite, betting on the underdog (the opposite of
the move in the percentages) was found to win 59% of the time and the
null hypothesis of a fair bet was rejected. A general strategy of
betting against any percentage moving toward the favorite (home or road)
in the last hour won more than 60% of the time. It was found to be
statistically profitable compared to the null of no profitability--a
52.4% win percentage, enough to overcome the commission charged by the
sportsbook in wagering. In the totals market, statistical significance
was not found.
Overall, the actions of the betting public in the last hour before
kickoff in the NFL do not appear to represent information. It appears
that bettors who wager on NFL games in the hour leading up to kickoff
are much more likely to be recreational bettors, placing bets on their
favorite teams or on the over in totals wagers. These activities are
consistent with the notion of sports betting as consumption, as opposed
to investment, and leads to profits in following a simple contrarian
strategy of betting against the wagering action of the public in the
last hour of betting before kickoff. This strategy may persist as the
information on betting percentages is not yet widespread. To actually
use this information, bettors would either need to pay for an account on
http://www.sportsinsights.com or actively track and monitor the
percentages on Sunday morning on http://www.sportsbook.com. This
information does appear valuable since a statistically significant
wagering strategy is generated from real-time numbers presented on these
websites.
References
Asch, P., Malkiel, B., & Quandt, R. (1982). Racetrack betting
and informed behavior. Journal of Financial Economics, 10(2), 187-194.
Evan, W., & Noble, N. (1992). Testing efficiency in gambling
markets. Applied Economics, 24, 85-88.
Gandar, J., Dare, W., Brown, C., & Zuber, R. (1998). Informed
traders and price variations in the betting market for professional
basketball games. Journal of Finance, 53, 385-401.
Gandar, J., Zuber, R., & Dare, W. (2000). The search for
informed traders in the totals betting market for National Basketball
Association games. Journal of Sports Economics, 1, 177-186.
Golec, J., & Tamarkin, M. (1991). The degree of price
inefficiency in the football betting markets. Journal of Financial
Economics, 30, 311-23.
Gray P., & Gray S. (1997). Testing market efficiency: Evidence
from the NFL sports betting market. Journal of Finance, 52, 1725-37.
Levitt, S. (2004). Why are gambling markets organized so
differently from financial markets? The Economic Journal, 114, 223-46.
Ottaviani, M., & Sorensen, P. (2005). The timing of bets and
the favorite-longshot bias. Unpublished manuscript.
Ottaviani, M., & Sorensen, P. (2008). The favorite-longshot
bias: An overview of the main explanations in Hausch and Ziemba (Eds.).
Handbook of Sports and Lottery Markets. Amsterdam: Elsevier.
Pankoff, L. (1968). Market efficiency and football betting. Journal
of Business, 41, 203-214.
Paul, R., & Weinbach, A. (2008a). Does sportsbook.com set
pointspreads to maximize profits? Tests of the Levitt model of
sportsbook behavior. Journal of Prediction Markets, 1, 209-218.
Paul, R., & Weinbach, A. (2008b). Price setting in the NBA
gambling market: Tests of the Levitt model of sportsbook behavior.
International Journal of Sports Finance, 3, 2-18.
Paul, R., & Weinbach, A. (2009). Sportsbook behavior in the
NCAA football betting market: Tests of the traditional and Levitt models
of sportsbook behavior. Journal of Prediction Markets, 3, 21-37.
Paul, R., & Weinbach, A. (2010). Sportsbook Pricing and the
Behavioral Biases of Bettors in the NHL. Journal of Economics and
Finance. Forthcoming.
Paul R., & Weinbach, A. (2011). Bettor biases and price setting
by sportsbooks in the NFL: Further tests of the Levitt hypothesis of
sportsbook behavior. Applied Economics Letters, 18, 193-197.
Sauer, R., Brajer, V., Ferris, S., & Marr, M. (1988). Hold your
bets: Another look at the efficiency of the gambling market for National
Football League games. Journal of Political Economy, 96, 206-13.
Zuber, R., Gandar, J., & Bowers, B. (1985). Beating the spread:
Testing the efficiency of the gambling market for National Football
League games. Journal of Political Economy, 93, 800-6.
Endnote
(1) 28.87% of all games had a pointspread move in the last hour
before kickoff. 51.36% of these games had the pointspread move toward
the favorite. Of the moves, 73.64% were half-point moves.
Rodney J. Paul [1] and Andrew P. Weinbach [2]
[1] St. Bonaventure University
[2] Syracuse University
Rodney J. Paul is a professor in the Sport Management Department in
the David B. Falk College of Sport and Human Dynamics at Syracuse
University. He received his doctorate in applied economics from Clemson
University in 2000. His research interests include market efficiency,
prediction markets, behavioral biases, and the economics and finance of
sports.
Andrew P. Weinbach is an associate professor of economics and the
Colonel Lindsey H. Vereen Endowed Business Professor at the E. Craig Wall Sr. College of Business Administration at Coastal Carolina University. His research interests include the economics and finance of
sports, consumer behavior, and the economics of lotteries and gambling.
Table 1. NFL Last Hour of Betting
Home favorites Road favorites
Number of bets placed in the 18,315.12 19,164.18
last hour (6,252.25) (6,338.18)
Percentage of bets placed in the 22.86% 22.93%
last hour (5.92) (6.81)
Percentage of bets on favorite - 0.2475 -0.5078
(change in last hour) (2.1251) (3.0742)
Percentage of bets on over - 0.0731 0.2891
(change in last hour) (3.5894) (3.1614)
Percentage bet on favorite 56.63% 70.75%
(market close) (12.71) (9.49)
Percentage bet on over 65.88% 65.80%
(market close) (10.65) (9.13)
Average pointspread move in -0.0148 0.0176
last hour (0.4431) (0.4437)
Average total move in last hour -0.0484 0.0195
(1.8343) (0.3646)
Note. Average of each variable (Standard Deviation); data from
Sportsinsights.com online sportsbooks.
Table 2: Betting Simulation Results in the NFL Pointspread Market
Favorite Underdog
Home Favorites
All Games 233 263
Games with an increase in betting 47 69
percentage on the favorite in the
last hour
Games with an increase in betting 44 51
percentage on the underdog in the
last hour
Road Favorites
All Games 130 118
Games with an increase in betting 9 18
percentage on favorite in
last hour
Games with an increase in betting 37 31
percentage on the underdog in the
last hour
Combined Bet against Bet with
change in change in
betting betting
percentage percentage
Bet against percentage increase 87 56
on favorites in the last hour
Bet against percentage increase 80 83
on underdogs in the last hour
Bet against all percentage 167 138
increases in the last hour
Underdog win Log likelihood
percentage ratio: fair bet
Home Favorites
All Games 53.0242 1.8156
Games with an increase in betting 59.4828 4.1978 **
percentage on the favorite in the
last hour
Games with an increase in betting 53.6842 0.5163
percentage on the underdog in the
last hour
Road Favorites
All Games 47.5806 0.5809
Games with an increase in betting 66.6667 3.0582 *
percentage on favorite in
last hour
Games with an increase in betting 45.4882 0.5301
percentage on the underdog in the
last hour
Combined Win percentage: Log
betting against likelihood
change in Ratio: fair bet
betting (no profits)
percentage
Bet against percentage increase 60.8392 6.7738 ***
on favorites in the last hour (4.1449 **)
Bet against percentage increase 49.0798 0.0552
on underdogs in the last hour
Bet against all percentage 54.7541 2.7615 *
increases in the last hour
Note. Betting percentage change in the last hour. The log likelihood
test statistics have a chi-square distribution with one degree of
freedom. Critical Values are 2.706 (for an [alpha] = 0.10), 3.841
(for an [alpha] = 0.05), and 6.635 (for an [alpha] = 0.01). * is
significant at 10%; ** is significance at 5%.
Table 3: Betting Simulation Results in NFL Totals Market
Overs Unders
Home favorites All games 251 245
Games with an increase in betting 83 75
percentage on the over
in last hour
Games with an increase in betting 68 69
percentage on the under
Road favorites All 129 120
Games with an increase in betting 39 49
percentage on the over
in last hour
Games with an increase in betting 35 24
percentage on the under
in last hour
Combined Bet against Bet with
move move
Bet against percentage increase 124 122
on overs in last hour
Bet against percentage increase 103 93
on unders in last hour
Bet against all percentage 227 215
increases in last hour
Under win Log likelihood
percentage ratio: fair bet
Home favorites All games 49.3952 0.0726
Games with an increase in betting 47.4684 0.4052
percentage on the over
in last hour
Games with an increase in betting 50.3650 0.0073
percentage on the under
Road favorites All 48.1928 0.3254
Games with an increase in betting 44.6818 1.1388
percentage on the over
in last hour
Games with an increase in betting 40.6780 2.0629
percentage on the under
in last hour
Combined Bet against Log likelihood
move win ratio--fair bet
percentage
Bet against percentage increase 50.4065 0.0163
on overs in last hour
Bet against percentage increase 52.5510 0.5104
on unders in last hour
Bet against all percentage 51.3575 0.3258
increases in last hour
Note. Betting percentage change in the last hour. The log likelihood
test statistics have a chi-square distribution with one degree of
freedom. Critical Values are 2.706 (for an [alpha] = 0.10), 3.841
(for an [alpha] = 0.05), and 6.635 (for an [alpha] = 0.01). * is
significant at 10%; ** is significant at 5%.