The effect of luxury taxes on competitive balance, club profits, and social welfare in sports leagues.
Dietl, Helmut M. ; Lang, Markus ; Werner, Stephan 等
Introduction
A "luxury tax," or competitive balance tax, is a
surcharge on the aggregate payroll of a sports team that exceeds a
predetermined limit set by the corresponding sports league. The luxury
tax was essentially designed to slow the growth of salaries and to
prevent large-market teams from signing all of the top players within a
league. The money derived from this tax is distributed among the
financially weaker teams. The luxury tax thus aims to create a more
balanced league, because redistribution among clubs counteracts
financial imbalances.
In North America, the National Basketball Association (NBA) and
Major League Baseball (MLB) operate with a luxury tax system. In 1984,
the NBA became the first league to introduce salary cap provisions. (1)
The NBA's salary cap is a so-called "soft cap," meaning
that there are several exceptions that allow teams to exceed the salary
cap in order to sign players. These exceptions are mainly designed to
enable teams to retain popular players. In 1999, the NBA also introduced
a luxury tax system for those teams with an average team payroll
exceeding the salary cap by a predefined amount. These teams have to pay
a 100% tax to the league for each dollar their payroll exceeds the tax
level.
The first luxury tax in professional sports was introduced in 1996
by MLB as part of its Collective Bargaining Agreement (CBA). This
agreement imposed a luxury tax of 35% for the first two years and 34%
for the third year on the teams with the top five payrolls during the
1997, 1998, and 1999 seasons. Between 2000 and 2002, the luxury tax
system was replaced by a revenue-sharing system. MLB reintroduced a
luxury tax system in 2003 and set fixed limits on payrolls for every
year. For instance, the limit was $137 million in 2006, $148 million in
2007, and $155 million in 2008. The excess payroll is taxed at 22.5% for
first-time offenders, 30% for the second offense and 40% for three or
more offenses. Table 1 shows recent luxury tax payments in the NBA and
MLB.
The welfare effect of luxury taxes has not yet been studied in the
sports economic literature. There are, however, some studies that
analyze the effect of luxury taxes on competitive balance and player
salaries. Gustafson and Hadley (1996) find that a luxury tax will
depress the demand curve for star players on high-payroll teams and will
not alter the demand for star players by low-payroll teams, resulting in
a lower equilibrium salary for star players. The new equilibrium is
further characterized by a higher level of competitive balance, because
the high-payroll teams will hire fewer star players and the low-payroll
teams will hire more star players as compared to the period prior the
introduction of the luxury tax.
Marburger (1997) develops a model with two profit-maximizing clubs,
including one large-market club and one small-market club, and a fixed
talent supply. He shows that luxury taxes that are uniformly imposed as
a linear function of a club's payroll and that are not
redistributed to other clubs do not affect club profitability because
the decline in salaries equals the increase in taxes. Luxury taxes that
are redistributed according to a linear subsidy function result in lower
salaries and higher profits, but they do not affect competitive balance.
In order to reward small-market clubs and improve competitive balance,
the proceeds of luxury taxes must be distributed uniformly among all
clubs.
Ajilore and Hendrickson (2005) analyze the effect of luxury taxes
on competitive balance in MLB by empirically estimating the impact of
luxury taxes on team competitiveness. Their results show that the
introduction of a luxury tax in MLB has reduced the competitive
inequality of teams. Most of their results, however, are driven by a
single team, the New York Yankees. Finally, Van der Burg and Prinz
(2005) propose a progressive tax on either the revenues or the payroll
of sports clubs as a means to enhance competitive balance in team sports
league. Their theoretical analysis shows that both types of tax will
create asymmetric changes in the marginal revenues or the marginal costs
of the clubs and thus yield a more balanced league.
In the present paper, we add to the literature by providing a
welfare analysis of luxury taxes in a professional team sports league.
In particular, we analyze the effect of luxury taxes on competitive
balance, club profits, and social welfare. We show that a luxury tax
increases aggregate player salaries in the league and produces a more
balanced league. Moreover, a higher tax rate increases the profits of
large-market clubs, whereas the profits of small-market clubs only
increase if the tax rate is not set inadequately high. Finally, we show
that social welfare increases with a luxury tax.
Model
The following model describes the impact of luxury taxes on social
welfare in a professional team sports league consisting of an even
number of profit-maximizing clubs. The league generates total revenues
according to a league demand function. League revenues are then split
among the clubs that differ with respect to their market share. We
assume that there are two types of clubs, namely, large-market clubs and
small-market clubs. In order to maximize profits, each club
independently invests in playing talent.
League demand depends on the quality of the league, q, and is
derived as follows. (2) We assume a continuum of fans that differ in
their willingness to pay for a league with quality q. Every fan k has a
certain preference for quality that is measured by [MATHEMATICAL
EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]. The fans [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION
NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] are assumed to be uniformly distributed in
[0,1], that is, the measure of potential fans is one. The net utility of
fan [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] is specified as
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]. At price p, the fan
that is indifferent between consuming the league product or not is given
by [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]. Hence, the
measure of fans that purchase at price p is [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT
REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]. The league demand function is therefore given by
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]. Note that league
demand increases in quality, albeit with a decreasing rate; that is,
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]. By normalizing all
other costs (e.g., stadium and broadcasting costs) to zero, league
revenues are simply [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII].
Then, the league will choose the profit-maximizing price [MATHEMATICAL
EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]. (3) Given this profit-maximizing
price, league revenues depend solely on the quality of the league as
follows:
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]
Following the sports economic literature (e.g., Szymanski, 2003),
we assume that league quality depends on the level of the competition as
well as the potential suspense associated with a close competition
(competitive balance). Moreover, we assume that the supply of talent is
perfectly elastic. As a consequence, the unit cost/price of talent is
exogenously given and constant. Without loss of generality, we normalize the unit cost/price of talent to one, which means that talent
investments of club i, denoted by [x.sub.i], are equal to their salary
payments. In the subsequent analysis, we use the terms "player
salaries" and "talent investments" interchangeably.
The level of competition is measured by the aggregate talent within
the n-club league. We assume that the marginal effect of player salaries
(talent investments) [x.sub.i] on the level of the competition, T, is
positive but decreasing:
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII], (1)
This is guaranteed in our model if [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT
REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII], which will always be satisfied in equilibrium.
Competitive balance, CB, is measured by minus the variance of
player salaries and yields: (4)
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII].
Note that a lower variance of player salaries among the n clubs
implies closer competition and, therefore, a higher degree of
competitive balance. If all clubs invest the same amount in talent, then
the measure for competitive balance attains its maximum and equals zero.
League quality is now defined as:
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII].
with [mu] [member of] (0,1). The parameter [mu] represents the
relative weight that fans place on aggregate talent and competitive
balance. Given aggregate player salaries of the other (n - 1) clubs,
league quality increases with club i's player salaries [x.sub.i]
until a threshold value [x.sub.i]([mu]). Since fans have at least some
preference for [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII].
competitive balance, excessive dominance by one club causes quality to
decrease.
League revenues are split between the two types of clubs according
to their market shares. For the sake of simplicity, we assume that half
of the n clubs are large-market clubs which receive a bigger share of
league revenues than the small-market clubs. (5) Each of the
large-market clubs receives a fraction [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT
REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] of league revenues, and each of the small-market
clubs receives a fraction [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN
ASCII] of league revenues, with
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII].
We denote [J.sub.l] and [J.sub.s] as the set of large-market and
small-market clubs, respectively, i.e., [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT
REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII].
Furthermore, our league features a luxury tax system with an
endogenously determined luxury tax and subsidy. (6) A club must pay a
luxury tax if its player salaries lie above the league's average
salary level. The club with player salaries below the league's
average salary level then receives this tax as a subsidy. We model the
endogenously determined tax or subsidy, [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT
REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII], as follows
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII].
where the parameter r [member of] [0,1] represents the tax rate.
Note that if club i spends more than the league's average salary
level, then this club has to pay a luxury tax, whereas it receives a
subsidy if it spends less than the average level in the league, i.e.,
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]. Moreover, note that
the luxury tax or subsidy involves a pure redistribution among clubs
because [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII].
The profit function [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN
ASCII] of I [member of] J club is given by
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] (2)
with [delta] = l for I [member of] [J.sub.l] and [MATHEMATICAL
EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII].
Social welfare is given by the sum of the aggregate consumer (or
fan) surplus, the aggregate club profit and the aggregate player
salaries. Aggregate consumer surplus, CS, corresponds to the integral of
the demand function, d(p,q), from the equilibrium price [p.sup.*] =
[q/2] to the maximum price [bar.p] = q, which is the maximum price fans
are willing to pay for quality q, that is,
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII].
The summation of aggregate consumer surplus, aggregate club profits
and aggregate player salaries produces social welfare as
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII].
Note that neither aggregate player salaries, taxes, nor subsidies
directly influence social welfare, because salaries merely represent a
transfer from clubs to players, and the tax or subsidy involves a pure
redistribution among clubs.
As mentioned above, clubs are assumed to be profit-maximizing and
thus, each club i [member of] J aims to solve the following maximization
problem: (7)
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII].
The solution to the maximization problem is given in the next
lemma:
Lemma 1
The equilibrium player salaries (talent investments) for club i
[member of] J are given by
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII], (3)
with [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] Proof: See
Appendix A.1.
The lemma shows that all large-market (small-market) clubs choose
the same salary level, [x.sub.l] ([x.sub.s]). Moreover, the large-market
clubs spend more on player salaries than the small-market clubs because
the marginal revenue of talent investments is higher for the former type
of clubs. As a consequence, each large-market club has to pay a luxury
tax, and each small-market club receives a subsidy, which is financed by
the large-market clubs.
We see that a higher tax rate r induces small-market clubs to
increase their talent investments, i.e., [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT
REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]. This result is intuitively clear: a higher tax
rate increases the subsidies to small-market clubs, which are financed
by large-market clubs, such that the investment costs of small-market
clubs decrease.
The effect of a higher tax rate on the talent investments of
large-market clubs, however, is ambiguous and depends on the fans'
preference parameter [mu]. Note that
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]
with [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]. A higher
tax rate thus induces large-market clubs to increase their investment
level if fans have a high preference for competitive balance, i.e., [mu]
< [mu]', and to decrease their investment level if fans have a
high preference for aggregate talent, i.e.,[mu] < [mu]'.
The rationale for this result is as follows. If [mu] is relatively
low, fans have a high preference for competitive balance and the
equilibrium (3) is already characterized by a high level of competitive
balance and a low level of aggregate talent. At these equilibrium
levels, the marginal benefit of a higher level of aggregate talent,
which translates into higher revenues, is larger than the higher
investment costs due to a higher tax. As a consequence, large-market
clubs will increase their investment level.
In contrast, if [mu] is relatively high, the equilibrium is already
characterized by a high level of aggregate talent and a low level of
competitive balance. In this case, the marginal benefit of a higher
level of aggregate talent is small, and cannot compensate for the higher
investments costs, inducing the large-market clubs to decrease their
investment level.
On aggregate, however, the investment level always increases with a
higher tax rate. That is, even if large-market clubs decrease their
investments (i.e., if [mu] < [mu]'), they never compensate for
the increase of talent among small-market clubs.
The luxury tax paid by each large-market club, i [member of] J, in
equilibrium is given by
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII].
Meanwhile the subsidy received by each small-market club,
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII], is given by
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII].
Note that a higher tax rate, r, increases the subsidy,
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII], received by
small-market clubs and decreases the luxury tax, [MATHEMATICAL
EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII], paid by large-market clubs until
the maximum and minimum, respectively, is reached for [MATHEMATICAL
EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII].
In equilibrium, the aggregate level of player salaries, S*(r), and
competitive balance, CB*(r), are given by
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII].
We thus derive the following proposition.
Proposition 1
A higher tax rate increases the level of competition and produces a
more balanced league.
Proof: See Appendix A.2.
Remember that on aggregate, the investment level increases with a
higher tax rate: that is, the net effect of a higher tax rate is
positive, and aggregate player salaries in the league will increase,
i.e., [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]. It follows
that a higher level of aggregate player salaries in the league
translates through the talent function (1) into a higher level of the
competition, T*.
The proposition further shows that a higher tax rate produces a
more balanced league and, thus, increases competitive balance, i.e.
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]. The rationale for
this result is that a higher tax diminishes differences among clubs.
That is, even if large-market clubs increase their investment levels,
small-market clubs will always respond with even higher investment
levels such that [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII].
Since both the level of the competition, T* and competitive
balance, CB*, increase through a higher tax rate, it is clear that
league quality, as given by [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN
ASCII], will also increase. A higher league quality will then result in
higher league revenues, LR*.
As a consequence, we are able to establish the following
proposition:
Proposition 2
A higher tax rate increases social welfare in a team sports league
comprised of profit-maximizing clubs.
Proof: Straightforward and therefore omitted.
The proposition posits that the introduction of a luxury tax system
that redistributes revenues from large-market clubs to small-market
clubs increases social welfare in a team sports league comprised of
profit-maximizing clubs, and an elastic supply of talent. Since a higher
tax rate increases league quality, it will also increase social welfare
because welfare is directly proportional to league quality. Note that
the result of the proposition is independent of the fans'
preferences for aggregate talent and competitive balance.
In the following proposition, we analyze the effect of a higher tax
rate on club profits.
Proposition 3
A higher tax rate always increases the profits of large-market
clubs, whereas the profits of small-market clubs only increase until the
profit maximum is reached for a tax rate given by [MATHEMATICAL
EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII].
Proof: See Appendix A.3.
This proposition posits that even though large-market clubs must
subsidize small-market clubs, the large-market clubs always benefit from
a higher tax, whereas the small-market clubs only benefit up to a
certain tax level, [r.sup.*]. The rationale for this result is as
follows. On the revenue side, both clubs benefit from higher league
revenues as a result of a higher luxury tax. Large-market clubs,
however, benefit from the higher league revenues at an above-average
rate because they receive a larger share of league revenues. On the cost
side, small-market clubs face higher investment costs due to higher
player salaries, while the investment costs for large-market clubs
decrease (increase) if fans have a high preference for aggregate talent
(competitive balance). For small-market clubs, the higher subsidies and
higher revenues compensate for the higher player salaries only until the
tax rate attains [r.sup.*]. For large-market clubs, however, the higher
revenues always compensate for the higher costs, and thus, profits
increase with a higher tax rate.
Conclusion
Luxury taxes are an important way to increase competitive balance
in professional sports leagues. In this paper, we analyze the effects of
a luxury tax on competitive balance, club profits, and social welfare
under the assumption that the supply of talent is elastic and clubs
maximize profits. We develop a game-theoretic model of an n-club league
consisting of small-market and large-market clubs and derive fan demand
from a general utility function by assuming that a fan's
willingness to pay depends on the quality of the league. Our league
features the combination of an endogenously determined luxury tax and
subsidy. Clubs with payroll exceeding the average salary level must pay
a luxury tax on the excess amount. These proceeds are then redistributed
proportionally to those clubs with a payroll below the league average.
Our analysis shows that a higher luxury tax induces small-market
clubs to increase their player salaries. If fans have a high preference
for aggregate talent, however, large-market clubs will respond by
decreasing their player salaries. Aggregate payrolls will increase with
a higher tax rate, as the increase in player salaries by small-market
clubs is always larger than the decrease in player salaries by
large-market clubs. As a consequence, both competitive balance and
aggregate player salaries in the league will increase. The effect of
luxury taxes on social welfare is positive, because league quality will
always increase as a result of the combination of luxury taxes and its
resulting subsidies. Finally, our model shows that a luxury tax will
increase the profits of large-market clubs, whereas the profits of
small-market clubs only increase if the tax rate is not set inadequately
high. This result holds despite the fact that large-market clubs must
finance the subsidies for small-market clubs.
Further research is necessary, for example, to model the bargaining
game among clubs and league authorities in the distribution of league
revenues. Moreover, luxury taxes have not yet been analyzed in the
context of open league with promotion and relegation, or so-called mixed
leagues, that is, in leagues in which some clubs maximize profits, while
others aim to maximize wins. (8) Finally, an interesting avenue for
further research is the analysis of luxury taxes in the context of a
league with a fixed supply of talent and an endogenously determined
cost/price per unit of talent.
Appendix A
A.1 Proof of Lemma 1
The first-order conditions of equation (2) are given by (9)
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII],
if [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII], and
if [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]. Note that
[delta] = l for [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII].
Solving the system of first-order conditions yields the following
equilibrium investment levels:
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]
with, [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII].
In order to guarantee positive equilibrium investments, we assume
that [alpha] is sufficiently large. Moreover, in order to guarantee that
large-market clubs always invest more than small-market clubs, we assume
that [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII].
A.2 Proof of Proposition 1
First, we prove that a higher tax rate increases the level of
competition. Substituting the equilibrium talent investments (3) in the
talent function, T, given by (1) and computing the derivative with
respect to r yields
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII].
We derive that [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII].
Second, we show that competitive balance increases with a higher
tax rate. We find that
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]
Since [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII], it holds
that [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII], which
completes the proof.
A.3 Proof of Proposition 3
In order to analyze the effect of a luxury tax on club profits, we
consider a two-club league with n = 2 and set the fan preference
parameter to [mu] = 1/2. (10) Substituting the equilibrium talent
investments (3) into the profit function (2) and maximizing it with
respect to the tax rate, r, yields the following profit-maximizing tax
rate for large-market clubs
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII],
and for small-market clubs
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII].
We can show that [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN
ASCII], i.e., that the maximum profit for large-market clubs is not
within the interval of feasible tax rates. As a consequence, profits for
large-market clubs increase for all r [member of] [0,1]. In contrast,
for small-market clubs, the profit-maximizing tax rate, [MATHEMATICAL
EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII], is in the interval (0,1]. It
follows that the profits of small-market clubs increase when
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] and decrease when
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII].
Authors' Note
We gratefully acknowledge the financial support provided by the
Swiss National Science Foundation (Grants Nos. 100012-105270 and
100014-120503) and the research fund of the University of Zurich.
References
Ajilore, O., & Hendrickson, J. (2005). The impact of the luxury
tax on competitive balance in Major League Baseball. IASE Working Paper
Series, Paper No. 07-27.
Buraimo, B., Forrest, D., & Simmons, R. (2007). Freedom of
entry, market size, and competitive outcome: Evidence from English
soccer. Southern Economic Journal 74(1), 204-213.
Buraimo, B., & Simmons, R. (2008). Competitive balance and
attendance in Major League Baseball: An empirical test of the
uncertainty of outcome hypothesis. International Journal of Sport
Finance 3, 146-155.
Dietl, H., Franck, E., & Lang, M. (2008). Overinvestment in
team sports leagues: A contest theory model. Scottish Journal of
Political Economy 55, 353-368.
Dietl, H., & Lang, M. (2008). The effect of gate revenue
sharing on social welfare. Contemporary Economic Policy 26, 448.459.
Dietl, H., Lang, M., & Rathke, A. (2009). The effect of salary
caps in professional team sports on social welfare. The B.E. Journal of
Economic Analysis and Policy, 9, Article 17.
Dietl, H., Lang, M., & Werner, S. (2009). Social welfare in
sports leagues with profit-maximizing and/or win-maximizing clubs.
Southern Economic Journal, 76, 375-396.
Falconieri, S., Palomino, F., & Sakovics, J. (2004). Collective
versus individual sale of television rights in league sports. Journal of
the European Economic Association 5, 833-862.
Fort, R., & Quirk, J. (1995). Cross-subsidization, incentives,
and outcomes in professional team sports leagues. Journal of Economic
Literature, 33, 1265-1299.
Fort, R., & Quirk, J. (2004). Owner objectives and competitive
balance. Journal of Sports Economics, 5, 20-32.
Frick, B., Prinz, J., & Winkelmann, K. (2003). Pay inequalities
and team performance: Empirical evidence from the North American major
leagues. International Journal of Manpower, 24, 472-488.
Gustafson, E., & Hadley, L. (1996). The luxury tax proposal for
Major League Baseball: A partial equilibrium analysis. In J. Fizel, E.
Gustafson, & L. Hadley (Eds.), Baseball economics: Current research,
pp. 145-159. Westport, CT: Praeger.
Hoehn, T., & Szymanski, S. (1999). The Americanization of
European football. Economic Policy, 14, 204-240.
Humphreys, B. (2002). Alternative measures of competitive balance
in sports leagues. Journal of Sports Economics, 3(2), 133.
Kesenne, S. (2000a). The impact of salary caps in professional team
sports. Scottish Journal of Political Economy, 47, 422-430.
Kesenne, S. (2000b). Revenue sharing and competitive balance in
professional team sports. Journal of Sports Economics, 1, 56-65.
Kesenne, S. (2007). The economic theory of professional team
sports--An analytical treatment. Cheltenham, UK: Edward Elgar.
Marburger, D. (1997). Gate revenue sharing and luxury taxes in
professional sports. Contemporary Economic Policy, 15, 114-123.
Sloane, P. (1971). The economics of professional football: The
football club as a utility maximizer. Scottish Journal of Political
Economy, 17, 121-146.
Szymanski, S. (2003). The economic design of sporting contests.
Journal of Economic Literature, 41, 1137-1187.
Van der Burg, T., & Prinz, A. (2005). Progressive taxation as a
means for improving competitive balance. Scottish Journal of Political
Economy, 52, 65-74.
Vrooman, J. (1995). A general theory of professional sports
leagues. Southern Economic Journal, 61, 971-990.
Vrooman, J. (2000). The economics of American sports leagues.
Scottish Journal of Political Economy, 47, 364-398.
Endnotes
(1) A salary cap is a limit on the amount of money a club can spend
on player salaries. The cap is usually defined as a percentage of
average annual revenues and limits a club's investment in playing
talent. For a more detailed analysis, see e.g., Fort and Quirk (1995),
Kesenne (2000a), Szymanski (2003), Vrooman (1995, 2000), and Dietl,
Lang, and Rathke (2009).
(2) Our approach is similar to Falconieri et al. (2004), but we use
a different quality function. The quality function q in Falconieri et
al. always increases with a club's own talent investments, i.e.,
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] regardless of how
unbalanced the league becomes. In contrast, in our model, quality
decreases if the league becomes too unbalanced. Also see Dietl and Lang
(2008) who derive league demand as in the present paper.
(3) Note that the optimal price increase with quality, i.e.,
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII].
(4) For an analysis of competitive balance in sports leagues, see
e.g., Humphreys (2002), Buraimo et al. (2007), and Buraimo and Simmons
(2008). Moreover, see Frick et al. (2003), who investigate the
consequences of wage disparities on team performance.
(5) An interesting avenue for further research is to generalize the
results by implementing a parameter that characterizes the fraction of
large-market and small-market clubs, respectively.
(6) See also Marburger (1997).
(7) For a discussion of the club objective function, see e.g.,
Sloane (1971), Hoehn and Szymanski (1999), Fort and Quirk (2004),
Kesenne (2000b, 2007), and Dietl, Lang, and Werner (2009).
(8) See, e.g., Dietl, Franck, and Lang (2008), who investigate the
overinvestment problem in open leagues and Dietl, Lang, and Werner
(2009), who analyze social welfare in mixed leagues.
(9) It is easy to show that the corresponding second-order
conditions for a maximum are satisfied.
(10) This parameterization allows us to derive closed-form
solutions. The results remain qualitatively the same for other parameter
configurations.
Helmut M. Dietl [1], Markus Lang [1], and Stephan Werner [1]
[1] University of Zurich
Helmut M. Dietl is a professor with the Institute for Strategy and
Business Economics. His research interests include sport economics,
service management, and organization.
Markus Lang is a senior research associate with the Institute for
Strategy and Business Economics. His research interests include contest
theory, sport economics, and regulatory economics.
Stephan Werner is a senior research associate with the Institute
for Strategy and Business Economics. His research interests include game
theory and sport economics.
Table 1: Luxury Tax Payments in the NBA and MLB
Luxury Tax Payments (in US$)
League Club Season 2006-07 Season 2007-08
NBA New York Knicks 45'100'000 19'700'000
Dalas Mavericks 7'200'000 19'600'000
Cleveland Cavaliers -- 14'000'000
Denver Nuggets 2'000'000 13'600'000
Miami Heat -- 8'300'000
Boston Celtics -- 8'200'000
Minnesota Timberwolves 1'000'000 --
LA Lakers -- 5'100'000
Phoenix Suns -- 3'900'000
San Antonio Spurs 200'000 --
League Club Season 2006 Season 2007
MLB New York Yankees 26'000'000 23'880'000
Boston Red Soxs 498'000 6'060'000