Economic multipliers and mega-event analysis.
Matheson, Victor A.
Introduction
Economists often criticize economic impact studies that purport to
show that mega-events such as the Olympics, World Cup, or other sports
championships such as the Super Bowl bring large benefits to the
communities "lucky" enough to host them. These scholars
frequently cite the use of inappropriate multipliers as one of the
primary reasons why these impact studies overstate the economic gains to
the hosts of these events (see Siegfried and Zimbalist (2000), Crompton
(1995), or Baade and Matheson (2001) among others). Porter and Fletcher
(2008) echo these concerns, going so far as to note that most academic
journals will not publish economic impact studies generated using the
most commonly used software packages.
The concept of multipliers is well established in the field of
economics, however, and indeed the 1973 Nobel Prize in Economics was
awarded to Wassily Leontief for his work in developing the macroeconomic
input-output models used to derive multipliers. Therefore, it is not
appropriate to simply reject, out of hand, all use of multipliers in
mega-event impact analysis without a solid economic reason for doing so.
The purpose of this paper is to demonstrate one justification for
rejecting the use of standard economic multipliers in the analysis of
the economic impact of mega-events.
Before proceeding further, it is important to more precisely define
the terminology economists use when discussing multipliers. First,
practitioners of economic impact analysis are often quite vague about
the distinctions between economic impact, economic benefits, and
increased spending and typically use these terms interchangeably. Of
course, increased spending in an area does not necessarily lead to
increased incomes, and an economy may not "benefit" in an
appreciable way just because spending increases. While economists would
most likely define the benefits of an event to a city as being related
to the income generated for its citizens, economic impact reports
invariably equate economic impact with spending, and, therefore, it is
this that will be examined in this paper.
Economists also use two differing conventions in reporting
multipliers. One method calculates the multiplier as equal to indirect
spending divided by direct spending, so that a multiplier of 1 results
in total spending being double that of the direct spending. Others, such
as Humphreys (1994), report that the multiplier equals indirect spending
plus direct spending all divided by direct spending, so that instead a
multiplier of 2 implies a doubling of direct spending. The second
convention seems more natural and more widespread, so it will be used in
the remainder of this paper.
Economic impact analysis is generally done by estimating attendance
at an event, surveying a sample of visitors as to their spending
associated with the game or convention, and then applying a multiplier
to account for money circulating through the economy after the initial
round of spending. For example, an economic impact analysis for the
American football championship game, Super Bowl XXVIII, in Atlanta in
1994 estimated 306,680 visitor days with a typical visitor spending $252
per day for a direct impact of $77.3 million. An economic multiplier of
2.148 is then applied for an indirect impact of $88.7 million and a
total economic benefit of $166 million (Humphreys, 1994).
The economic multipliers used in these analyses are calculated
using complex input-output tables for specific industries. One commonly
used model in the United States is the Bureau of Economic Analysis'
Regional Industrial Multiplier System (RIMS II) that provides
final-demand output multipliers for 473 detailed industries, including
hotel accommodations, eating and drinking establishments, and arts,
entertainment, and recreation. One common criticism of the use of
multipliers in the analysis of professional sports is simply that the
multipliers used are too high since many athletes live outside the local
area in which they play. Therefore, wages paid to these athletes are
less likely to recirculate throughout the local economy than wages paid
to workers in other fields leading to a lower multiplier effect for
professional sports than in other industries (Siegfried & Zimbalist,
2002). While this criticism is certainly valid, the problem can be
addressed simply by creating input-output tables at a sufficient level
of detail to specifically address the peculiarities of the professional
sports industry.
When examining mega-events, however, the problem of inflated
multipliers becomes even more problematic. The multipliers in RIMS II
(or other multiplier models) are based upon inter-industry relationships
within regions based upon an economic area's normal production
patterns. During mega-events, however, the economy within a region may
be anything but normal, and therefore, these same inter-industry
relationships may not hold. As noted by Porter and Fletcher (2008),
since there is no reason to believe that the usual economic multipliers
are the same during mega-events, any economic analyses based upon these
multipliers may be highly inaccurate. Indeed, there is substantial
reason to believe that during mega-events, these multipliers are highly
overstated, and, therefore, their use overestimates the true impact of
these events on the local economy. This concept is easily explored
through a simple numerical example.
Numerical Example
Suppose the hotel industry, an industry that accounts for up to
half of all visitor spending during mega-events, is characterized by a
situation where hotel service is provided by combining capital, which
can be supplied either locally or by national or international capital
markets, and labor, which is supplied exclusively by local workers.
Income earned by capital owners (or stockholders) who do not live in the
city in which the hotel is located is unlikely to be respent in the
local economy in comparison to wages earned by local labor. Revenues
that flow out of an economy after an initial round of spending are
typically referred to as "leakages."
In particular, suppose that a hotel typically supplies 75 rooms at
a price of $150 per night requiring the use of 75 workers earning $100
per day. Any revenues in excess of labor costs accrue to capital owners
as profit. The multiplier effect from hotel expenditures depends on how
labor and capital spend their respective earnings in the local economy.
If both the laborers and hotel owners are local, assume that 50% of
their earnings are re-spent on local goods and that a multiplier equal
to 2 is applied to any subsequent rounds of spending. The direct and
indirect impact of hotel spending is shown in Table 1, Scenario 1.1
Alternatively, if the hotel is part of a nationally owned chain, the
workers are still local, but the capital owners are national, and,
therefore, income earned by capital will not recirculate in the economy
as shown in Table 1, Scenario 1.2.
Scenario 2
Suppose the mega-event increases the number of rooms sold to 100
while leaving the room prices unchanged. The hotel hires 100 workers
(instead of 75) in order to accommodate the higher demand. This
additional labor can be drawn from the existing labor pool by offering
more hours to existing workers or by tapping into the ranks of the
unemployed. Either way, earnings to labor increases with the event. The
corresponding direct and indirect earnings from the event if the hotel
is locally owned is shown in Table 1, Scenario 2.1, while the figures
for a nationally owned hotel are shown in Scenario 2.2. As seen in the
table, as long as the higher demand from the mega-event results in labor
and capital equally sharing in the increased revenue, then the
corresponding multipliers remain unchanged.
A second important fact can be shown from comparing Scenarios 1.1
and 1.2 to Scenarios 2.1 and 2.2. Even if all hotel revenues during a
specific period can be attributed to a particular event, while the gross
hotel revenues associated with the event are high, the marginal revenues
are much lower because the event visitors crowd out the regular hotel
business. For example, in Scenario 2.1, the gross direct hotel revenues
are 15,000; however, the net direct impact of the event is only the
difference between hotel revenues during the event and revenues
typically, or 3,750.
Scenario 3
Suppose the mega-event increases the number of rooms sold to 100
while leaving the room prices unchanged. In this scenario, however, the
hotel does not hire additional workers in the face of the higher demand.
The existing workers are simply expected to work harder or more
efficiently to order to meet the customers' needs in the crowded
hotel. The corresponding direct and indirect earnings from the event if
the hotel is locally owned is shown in Table 1, Scenario 3.1, while the
figures for a nationally owned hotel are shown in Scenario 3.2. As seen
in the table, when capital and labor are both locally supplied, the
multiplier is unaffected by the distribution of the proceeds from the
event among the factors of production since both will re-spend the same
fraction of their earnings locally. When the hotel is nationally owned,
however, the increase in the portion of the hotel's revenue that
accrues to capital serves to reduce the multiplier. Indeed, the
mega-event results in no marginal increase in indirect spending
whatsoever. A typical impact analysis would apply the usual multiplier
of 1.67 to the 15,000 in direct hotel spending to arrive at an estimate
of a 25,000 (= 1.67 x 15,000 = 25,000) gain from the event. Instead, the
gross total impact is only 22,500 (= 1.5 x 15,000 = 22,500), and the net
total impact is a mere 3,750 (18,750 total from Scenario 1.2 vs. 22,500
total from Scenario 3.2). Furthermore, the marginal effect of the event
on the income of local citizens is actually zero since none of the
increase in hotel revenues accrues to local residents.
Scenario 4
Finally, suppose the mega-event leaves the number of rooms sold and
workers hired constant at 75, but the price of a room doubles to $300.
In empirical observations of hotel prices during mega-events, it is not
uncommon to observe prices that are double or triple those of non-event
room rates. The corresponding direct and indirect earnings from the
event for a locally and nationally owned hotel are shown in Table 1,
Scenarios 4.1 and 4.2, respectively. As in scenario 3, the increase in
room price increases hotel profits while leaving labor's income
unchanged. Once more, when capital and labor are both locally supplied,
the multiplier is unaffected by the distribution of the proceeds from
the event, but when the hotel is not locally owned, the increase in the
portion of the hotel's revenue that accrues to capital reduces the
multiplier.
Other Considerations
Several other factors can affect the way in which the multiplier
changes during a mega-event. First, the presence of local hotel taxes
does likely ensure that at least some portion of the hotel's
windfall is retained locally. Of course, general sales tax and hotel tax
collections are often split between the local municipality and the
state, but suppose that it is the local government that imposes a 10%
tax on room fees that it will get to keep in its entirety and that the
incidence of the tax falls completely on the consumer. Furthermore,
assume local tax collections recirculate through the economy at the same
rate as other local income so that the multiplier on this tax revenue is
2. Table 1, Scenarios 1.3 through 4.3 show the direct and indirect
revenues for the base case and scenarios 1 though 4 for a nationally
owned chain. Comparing the multipliers in Scenario 1.2 to Scenario 1.3,
Scenario 2.2 to Scenario 2.3, Scenario 3.2 to Scenario 3.3, and Scenario
4.2 to Scenario 4.3, the presence of government taxation serves to raise
the multiplier as compared to the situation without taxation.
Second, capital need not be the only source of leakage from a
mega-event. If workers from outside the local area come to the host city
to provide labor during a mega-event, their earnings are likely to be
repatriated back to their home city once the event is over. One
particularly notorious but well publicized example of this occurred
during the 2006 World Cup in Germany. The country's brothels
imported an estimated 40,000 sex workers during the World Cup to
accommodate anticipated demand (CBS News, 2006). These foreign workers
are unlikely to spend the same portion of their earnings within the
German host cities as domestic workers who already resided within the
venues. Of course, many other types of labor ranging from specialized
security providers to street vendors may temporarily relocate to the
host city of a mega-event to provide services.
Going back to Scenario 2 where the mega-event increases the number
of rooms sold to 100 while leaving the room prices unchanged, suppose
the 25 extra workers the hotel hires in order to accommodate the higher
demand are now imported from outside the host city and suppose none of
these workers' earnings are spent locally. The corresponding direct
and indirect earnings from the event if the hotel is locally owned is
shown in Table 1, Scenario 5.1, while the figures for a nationally owned
hotel are shown in Table 1, Scenario 5.2. As seen in the table, the fact
that the imported workers do not re-spend their earnings in the local
economy reduces the multipliers in both cases as compared to the
corresponding situations in Scenarios 2.1 and 2.2.
Conclusion and Recommendations
In estimating economic impacts from mega-events, analysts
frequently use multipliers derived from input-output tables based on the
normal state of the economy even though the presence of a large
temporary tourist attraction such as the Olympics or the World Cup
indicates a departure from this normal state. Mega-events are
characterized by high utilization rates and increased prices for
tourism-related industries. While local labor may benefit to some extent
through increases in hours worked or higher tips, the main recipient of
this windfall is likely to be business owners (and perhaps workers from
outside the region). Expenditures in industries dominated by nationally
owned chains such as large hotels, rental car agencies, and airlines,
and to a lesser extent motels, restaurants, and general retailers may
rise significantly due to a mega-event, but local incomes will not
increase substantially. Since the benefits accrue to non-local capital
owners leading to higher than normal leakages of income, the money
generated from these events is unlikely to recirculate through the
economy, and any multipliers applied are, therefore, probably inflated.
Are there any obvious solutions to this apparent problem in
economic impact analysis? In many ways the situation described in this
paper is similar to that described by Lucas (1976) in pointing out the
potential problems associated with implementing macroeconomic policy.
The so-called "Lucas Critique" suggests that it is naive to
presume that one can predict the effects of macroeconomic policy changes
based solely on historical data much as this paper shows that it may be
equally foolish to presume that one can predict the effects of
mega-events on local economies using fixed multipliers based on average
economic patterns. Lucas and other rational expectations economists such
as Kyland and Prescott advocated the use of computable general
equilibrium (CGE) models, and indeed, Dwyer, Forsythe, and Spurr (2004)
use this technique in their work on the economic impact of sporting
events in Australia. In general, they find that the use of CGE
techniques that allow the multipliers to vary along with the state of
the economy serve to reduce estimated economic impacts from sporting
events in comparison to static models using fixed multipliers.
As few sports boosters seem intent on adopting more conservative
approaches to estimating economic impact, caution is warranted whenever
economic impact estimates are presented. Cities routinely offer to spend
large sums of money in order to attract major sporting events in large
part based upon exaggerated claims of an economic windfall, but a
skeptical public should beware of economists bearing reports showing
"mega-benefits" from mega-events.
References
Baade, R., & Matheson, V. (2001). Home run or wild pitch?
Assessing the economic impact of Major League Baseball's All-Star
Game. Journal of Sports Economics, 2(4), 307-327.
CBS News. (2006, June 8, 2006). Vatican laments World Cup
prostitution.
Crompton, J. (1995). Economic impact analysis of sports facilities
and events: Eleven sources of misapplication. Journal of Sport
Management, 9(1), 14-35.
Dwyer, L, Forsyth, P., & Spurr, R. (2004). Evaluating
tourism's economic effects: New and old approaches. Tourism
Management, 25(3), 307-317.
Humphreys, J. (1994). The economic impact of hosting Super Bowl
XXVIII on Georgia. Georgia Business and Economic Conditions, May-June,
18-21.
Lucas, R. (1976). Econometric policy evaluation: A critique.
Carnegie-Rochester Conference Series on Public Policy, 1, 19-46.
Porter, P., & Fletcher, D. (2008). The economic impact of the
Olympic Games: Ex ante predictions and ex poste reality. Journal of
Sport Management, 22(4), 470-486.
Siegfried, J., & Zimbalist, A. (2000). The economics of sports
facilities and their communities. Journal of Economic Perspectives,
14(3), 95-114.
Siegfried, J., & Zimbalist, A. (2002). Note on the local
economic impact of sports expenditures. Journal of Sports Economics,
3(4), 361-366.
Victor A. Matheson (1)
(1) College of Holy Cross
Victor A. Matheson is an associate professor in the Department of
Economics. His research interests include the economics of collegiate
and professional sports.
Table 1: Economic Impact Estimates and the Resulting Multiplier
Direct Economic Impact
Model/Scenario Labor Capital Gov. Total
Scenario 1.1: Base case 7,500 3,750 -- 11,250
Local ownership
Scenario 1.2: Base case 7,500 3,750 -- 11,250
Foreign ownership
Scenario 1.3: Base case 7,500 3,750 1,125 12,375
w/taxation--Foreign
ownership
Scenario 2.1: Increased 10,000 5,000 -- 15,000
demand for rooms and
labor--Local ownership
Scenario 2.2: Increased 10,000 5,000 -- 15,000
demand for rooms and
labor--Foreign ownership
Scenario 2.3: Increased 10,000 5,000 1,500 16,500
demand for rooms and
labor w/taxation--
Foreign ownership
Scenario 3.1: Increased 7,500 7,500 -- 15,000
demand for rooms
only--Local ownership
Scenario 3.2: Increased 7,500 7,500 -- 15,000
demand for rooms only--
Foreign ownership
Scenario 3.3: Increased 7,500 7,500 1,500 16,500
demand for rooms only
w/taxation--Foreign
ownership
Scenario 4.1: Increased 7,500 15,000 -- 22,500
price of rooms--Local
ownership
Scenario 4.2: Increased 7,500 15,000 -- 22,500
price of rooms--Foreign
ownership
Scenario 4.3: Increased 7,500 15,000 2,250 24,750
price of rooms
w/taxation--Foreign
ownership
Scenario 2.1: Increased 10,000 5,000 -- 15,000
demand for rooms and
labor--Local ownership,
local labor
Scenario 5.1: Increased 10,000 5,000 -- 15,000
demand for rooms and
labor--Local ownership,
foreign labor
Scenario 2.2: Increased 10,000 5,000 -- 15,000
demand for rooms and
labor--Foreign
ownership, local labor
Scenario 5.2: Increased 10,000 5,000 -- 15,000
demand for rooms and
labor--Foreign ownership
and labor
Indirect Economic Impact
Model/Scenario Labor Capital Gov. Total
Scenario 1.1: Base case 7,500 3,750 -- 11,250
Local ownership
Scenario 1.2: Base case 7,500 0 -- 7,500
Foreign ownership
Scenario 1.3: Base case 7,500 0 1,125 8,625
w/taxation--Foreign
ownership
Scenario 2.1: Increased 10,000 5,000 -- 15,000
demand for rooms and
labor--Local ownership
Scenario 2.2: Increased 10,000 0 -- 10,000
demand for rooms and
labor--Foreign ownership
Scenario 2.3: Increased 10,000 0 1,500 11,500
demand for rooms and
labor w/taxation--
Foreign ownership
Scenario 3.1: Increased 7,500 7,500 -- 15,000
demand for rooms
only--Local ownership
Scenario 3.2: Increased 7,500 0 -- 7,500
demand for rooms only--
Foreign ownership
Scenario 3.3: Increased 7,500 0 1,500 9,000
demand for rooms only
w/taxation--Foreign
ownership
Scenario 4.1: Increased 7,500 15,000 -- 22,500
price of rooms--Local
ownership
Scenario 4.2: Increased 7,500 0 -- 7,500
price of rooms--Foreign
ownership
Scenario 4.3: Increased 7,500 0 2,250 9,750
price of rooms
w/taxation--Foreign
ownership
Scenario 2.1: Increased 10,000 5,000 -- 15,000
demand for rooms and
labor--Local ownership,
local labor
Scenario 5.1: Increased 7,500 5,000 -- 12,500
demand for rooms and
labor--Local ownership,
foreign labor
Scenario 2.2: Increased 10,000 0 -- 10,000
demand for rooms and
labor--Foreign
ownership, local labor
Scenario 5.2: Increased 7,500 0 -- 7,000
demand for rooms and
labor--Foreign ownership
and labor
Model/Scenario Mult.
Scenario 1.1: Base case 2.00
Local ownership
Scenario 1.2: Base case 1.67
Foreign ownership
Scenario 1.3: Base case 1.70
w/taxation--Foreign
ownership
Scenario 2.1: Increased 2.00
demand for rooms and
labor--Local ownership
Scenario 2.2: Increased 1.67
demand for rooms and
labor--Foreign ownership
Scenario 2.3: Increased 1.70
demand for rooms and
labor w/taxation--
Foreign ownership
Scenario 3.1: Increased 2.00
demand for rooms
only--Local ownership
Scenario 3.2: Increased 1.50
demand for rooms only--
Foreign ownership
Scenario 3.3: Increased 1.55
demand for rooms only
w/taxation--Foreign
ownership
Scenario 4.1: Increased 2.00
price of rooms--Local
ownership
Scenario 4.2: Increased 1.25
price of rooms--Foreign
ownership
Scenario 4.3: Increased 1.39
price of rooms
w/taxation--Foreign
ownership
Scenario 2.1: Increased 2.00
demand for rooms and
labor--Local ownership,
local labor
Scenario 5.1: Increased 1.83
demand for rooms and
labor--Local ownership,
foreign labor
Scenario 2.2: Increased 1.67
demand for rooms and
labor--Foreign
ownership, local labor
Scenario 5.2: Increased 1.50
demand for rooms and
labor--Foreign ownership
and labor