The impact of pooling and sharing broadcast rights in professional team sports.
Kesenne, Stefan
Introduction
In the White Paper on Sports (2007) of the European Commission, it
is stated that: "While joint selling of media rights raises
competition concerns, the Commission has accepted it under certain
conditions. Collective selling can be important for the distribution of
income and can be a tool for achieving greater solidarity within
sports:' Although the Commission does not reject the individual
selling of broadcast rights by clubs, it clearly prefers the pooling of
rights in order to facilitate the distribution. In most national
football championships in Europe, as well as in the US major leagues,
the broadcast rights are pooled by the league and distributed in one way
or another among all clubs. In a few countries, like Spain, Portugal,
and Italy, the individual football clubs can individually sell the media
rights of their home games. In a few court cases, in Holland, Germany,
and Spain, it has been confirmed that the legal owner of the broadcast
rights of a team's home game is the club and not the league. In
several other court cases, the leagues won. From an economic point of
view, individual selling is preferable because collective selling
creates a monopoly that can cause welfare losses with prices that are
too high and output that is too low (see Noll, 1999). On the other hand,
the peculiar economics of professional team sports can also justify that
part of the rights can be assigned to the league (see Neale, 1964). One
team cannot play a game--a team needs an opponent--and together they
supply the product. Moreover, the value of a game is much higher if it
is part of a championship, organized by the league as a cartel of clubs,
than if it is just an occasional game. Also, a certain competitive
balance between the teams is necessary to make the games and the
championship more attractive. From this point of view, a shared
ownership and some distribution of broadcast rights by the league can be
justified (see Jeanrenaud & Kesenne, 2006).
In this paper, we analyze the impact that can be expected from the
selling and the distribution of broadcasting rights on the demand for
talent and the competitive balance. We will only concentrate on profit
maximization as the objective of club owners. If clubs are win
maximizers, under a zero or non-zero profit constraint, it is obvious
that any sharing arrangement that makes the small-market clubs richer
and large-market clubs poorer improves the competitive balance because
win-maximizing clubs spend all their (net) revenue on talent.
In an earlier study, Falconieri, Palomino and Sakovics (2004)
investigated the welfare effects of collective versus individual sale of
television rights, and conclude that the collective sale is socially
preferable if leagues are small and homogenous, and if teams receive
little performance-related revenues. Our analysis only concentrates on
the impact of selling and sharing broadcast rights on competitive
balance, because the need for a competitive balance in a sports league
has always been the main argument to justify the monopolization of
broadcast rights. This competitive balance is only one of the variables
that positively affect the demand for broadcast games in the Falconieri
et al. (2004) paper. However, these authors do not consider the
possibility that the broadcasting money can be distributed if it has
been collected individually by the clubs. The conclusion of our paper is
that the best guarantee to improve the competitive balance is the
individual sale of the rights with a performance-related sharing system.
In the Model Specification section, a simple 2-club Nash
equilibrium model is specified with the demand for talent as the only
decision variable. Following that, four different scenarios are compared
regarding the selling of broadcasting rights and the distribution of the
rights among the clubs. The final section includes the discussion and
conclusion.
Model Specification
Some studies start from the equilibrium where the only club revenue
are gate receipts and then analyze the impact on the competitive balance
of sharing broadcast rights. But they do not consider how this money is
collected; the money seems to appear out of nowhere. In our opinion,
these approaches do not adequately analyze the impact of pooling and
sharing broadcast rights; sharing means that money is taken away from
somebody and given to somebody else. So, if one wants to analyze the
impact of pooling and sharing broadcast rights, one has to start from
the benchmark case of a non-pooling/non-sharing equilibrium.
We start from a 2-club league with x being the large-market club
and y the small-market club. Each club has two basic sources of season
revenue: gate receipts and broadcast rights. We assume that the
broadcast revenue of each club, in the benchmark case, is proportional
to the number of stadium spectators with a different proportionality
factor in each club. See Garcia and Rodriguez (2002) and Forrest and
Simmons (2006) for useful empirical evidence on the relationship between
broadcasting and gate attendances in Spanish La Liga and English
Championship, respectively. In our reference or benchmark case, the sale
of broadcast rights is decentralized without any sharing. So, if R is
season revenue, p the ticket price, A season attendances, B the
broadcasting rights, and k the proportionality factor, total season
revenue of each club can then be written as:
[R.sub.i] = [[p. sub.i][A.sub.i]] + [B.sub.i] with [B. sub.i]]=
[k.sub.i][A.sub.i]
i : x, y
so : [R.sub.i] = ([p.sub.i] + [k.sub.i]) with [p.sub.x] >
[p.sub.y] and [k.sub.x] > [k.sub.y] (1)
It is reasonable to assume that the ticket prices are higher in the
large-market clubs. Also, the proportionality factor is higher for
large-market clubs because broadcast games of successful teams have a
larger drawing potential for spectators than just local supporters. We
further assume that televising the games does not affect stadium
attendances. Season attendance depends on the size of the market
([m.sub.i]) of the club, which cannot be changed by club management, and
on the winning percentage ([w.sub.i]) of the team because spectators
prefer winning teams. Following Szymanski (2003), we start from a very
simplified attendance function which is linear in winning percentage,
but concave in talent:
[A.sub.x] = [[m.sub.x][w.sub.x]] and [A.sub.y] =
[[m.sub.y][w.sub.y]]
with [w.sub.x] = [t.sub.x]/[t.sub.x] + [t.sub.y], [w.sub.y] =
[t.sub.x]/[t.sub.y] + [t.sub.y], and [m.sub.x] > [m.sub.y] (2)
The season winning percentages of a team depend on their relative
playing strength, where the number of talents in a team, not the number
of players, is given by [t.sub.i].
This specification implies a positive but decreasing marginal
effect of talent on attendance. The total supply of talent ([t.sub.x] +
[t.sub.y]) is flexible or fixed.
On the cost side, we only consider a variable player cost and a
flied capital cost [c.sub.i.sup.0], so the total cost can be written as:
[C.sub.1] = [ct.sub.i] + [c.sub.i.sup.0] i: x, y (3)
where c is the equilibrium unit cost of talent in a competitive
player market where all teams are wage takers.
In this partial approach, we assume that all clubs, at the start of
the season, decide on the number of talents, with an exogenously given
ticket price and proportionality factor ([k.sub.i]). Clearly, in this
model, the winning percentage of one team also depends on the talents of
the other team. We therefore derive the non-cooperative Nash
equilibrium, assuming Nash conjectures, to derive the clubs'
reaction functions and the competitive balance in the league. If clubs
are profit maximizers, the optimum is found where the marginal revenue
of talent equals the marginal cost. So the benchmark (no-sharing)
solution of the model can be found by deriving the two reaction
functions:
[partial derivative][R.sub.x][t.sub.x], [t.sub.y]/[partial
derivative][t.sub.x] = ([p.sub.x] + [k.sub.x])[m.sub.x]
[t.sub.y]/[([t.sub.x] + [t.sub.y]).sup.2] - c = 0
[partial derivative][R.sub.y][t.sub.x], [t.sub.y]/[partial
derivative][t.sub.y] = ([p.sub.y] + [k.sub.y])[m.sub.y]
[t.sub.x]/[([t.sub.x] + [t.sub.y]).sup.2] - c = 0 (4)
Solving this system of reaction equations results in the
competitive balance:
[W*.sub.x]/[W*.sub.y] = [t*.sub.x]/[t*.sub.y] = ([p.sub.x] +
[k.sub.x])[m.sub.x]/([p.sub.y] + [k.sub.y])[m.sub.y] (5)
Based on (1) and (2), it can be derived that [t.sub.x] >
[t.sub.y], or the large-market club is more talented and successful than
the small-market club.
Comparing Four Different Scenarios
Starting from this benchmark case above, different scenarios
regarding the selling and distribution of broadcast rights can be
distinguished:
1. Centralized selling and equal sharing (some US major leagues)
2. Centralized selling and performance-related sharing (most EU
football leagues)
3. Decentralized selling and equal sharing
4. Decentralized selling and performance-related sharing.
We will consider these scenarios one by one and compare their
impact on the competitive balance.
In reality, however, the sharing and selling of broadcast rights in
the North American major leagues and the national football leagues in
Europe follow more complicated lines then any of the four extreme
scenarios in our simplified model.
In some countries like Spain, the selling of broadcast rights is a
mixture of the two extreme scenarios considered in this model. In Spain,
the largest and richest clubs sell their broadcast rights individually,
while the smaller teams pool their rights and share the money among each
other. Also the distribution of the pooled broadcast rights is more
complicated than just equal sharing or just performance-related sharing.
In England's Premier League, 50% is equally distributed, another
25% is related to the television appearances of the teams, and the other
25% depends on the performances of the teams or their ranking in the
championship at the end of the season. In France, 75% is equally shared
and 25% is split according to the last season's nnal ranking. We
will not consider these mix systems in the model below, because we think
it is worthwhile, first of all, to see and understand the impact of the
extreme scenarios.
1. In the case of centralized selling of broadcast rights by the
league and equal sharing of the total broadcast revenue (B), the total
revenue of each team after sharing (indicated by the superscript a),
with lump-sum broadcast revenue B, is then:
[R.sub.i.sup.a] = [p.sub.i][A.sub.i] + B/2 i : x,y with [B.sub.y]
< B/2 < [B.sub.x] (6)
where B is the total broadcast revenue of the league. In this case,
the Nash equilibrium [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]
results in the following competitive balance:
[t.sub.x.sup.a]/[t.sub.y.sup.a] =
[p.sub.x][m.sub.x]/[p.sub.y][m.sub.y] (7)
Compared with the benchmark in (5), this is only an improvement of
the competitive balance if [k.sub.x] / [k.sub.y] > [p.sub.x] /
[p.sub.y]. This selling and sharing arrangement worsens the competitive
balance if [k.sub.x] / [k.sub.y] > [p.sub.x] / [p.sub.y]. Which
inequality holds is an empirical question; a first quick check of the
figures shows that the difference between the proportionality factors is
larger than the differences in ticket prices between large- and
small-market clubs. Theoretically, however, the outcome is
indeterminate.
2. The centralized broadcast rights B can also be distributed
depending on the performance of the teams. Performance can be measured
by the winning percentage, but the league can choose to take season
attendances. The advantage of using season attendances is that it also
creates an incentive for the price-setting clubs to keep their (local
monopoly) ticket prices low.
If we assume that the broadcast rights each club receives from the
league's sharing arrangement are proportional to attendances with a
fixed proportionality factor [beta], as decided by the league, club
revenue after sharing will be:
[R.sub.i.sup.a] = ([p.sub.i] + [beta])[A.sub.i] i : x,y
with [beta] = B / ([A.sub.x] + A.sub.y]), because [beta] ([A.sub.x]
+ A.sub.y]) [less than or equal to] B (8)
So, the win or talent ratio after sharing is now:
[t.sub.x.sup.a*]/[t.sub.y.sup.a*]=
([p.sub.x][beta])[m.sub.x]/([p.sub.y][beta])[m.sub.y] (9)
which can be an improvement of the distribution of talent compared
with the benchmark (5). Indeed, it can be shown that ([p.sub.x] +
[beta]) ([p.sub.y] + [k.sub.y]) < ([p.sub.y] + [beta]) ([p.sub.x] +
[k.sub.x]) for whatever value of [beta], if [k.sub.x]/[k.sub.y] [greater
than or equal to] [p.sub.x]/[p.sub.y]. So basically, the outcome is
again theoretically indeterminate.
3. In the case of decentralized selling of the broadcast rights,
the broadcasting revenue of the league is no longer lump-sum, but based
on the individual rights collection of each team. With equal sharing,
the teams' revenue after sharing can now be written as:
[R.sub.i.sup.a] = [p.sub.i][A.sub.i] + 1/2 ([k.sub.x][A.sub.x] +
[k.sub.y][A.sub.y] i : x,y (10)
The reaction functions can now be derived as:
[partial derivative][R.sub.x.sup.a][[t.sub.x],[t.sub.y]]/[partial
derivative][t.sub.x] = (2[p.sub.x][m.sub.x] + [k.sub.x][m.sub.x] -
[k.sub.y][m.sub.y])[t.sub.y]/2([t.sub.x] + [t.sub.y] - c = 0
[partial derivative][R.sub.y.sup.a][[t.sub.x],[t.sub.y]]/[partial
derivative][t.sub.y] = (2[p.sub.y][m.sub.y] + [k.sub.x][m.sub.x] +
[k.sub.y][m.sub.y])[t.sub.x]/2([t.sub.x] + [t.sub.y] - c = 0 (11)
In order to find the Nash equilibrium, we equalize the two reaction
functions and can find the following competitive balance:
[t.sub.x.sup.a*]/[t.sub.y.sup.a*] = ([p.sub.x] +
[k.sub.x])[m.sub.x] - 1/2 ([k.sub.x][m.sub.x] +
[k.sub.y][m.sub.y])/([p.sub.y] + [k.sub.y])[m.sub.y] - 1/2
([k.sub.x][m.sub.x] + [k.sub.y][m.sub.y]) (12)
Compared with the benchmark in (5), this is clearly a worse
competitive balance. This connrms the finding of Szymanski and Kesenne
(2004) regarding the impact of revenue sharing on competitive balance.
4. Finally, with decentralized selling of the rights, the league
can also redistribute the broadcasting money based on the season
attendances of the teams. It follows that after-sharing revenues can be
written as:
[R.sub.x.sup.a] = [p.sub.x][A.sub.x] + [[beta].sub.x][A.sub.x]
[R.sub.y.sup.a] = [p.sub.y][A.sub.y] + [[beta].sub.y][A.sub.y]
with [[beta].sub.x][A.sub.x] + [[beta].sub.y][A.sub.y] [less than
or equal to] [k.sub.x][A.sub.x] + [k.sub.y][A.sub.y] (13)
Comparing club revenues after sharing in (13) with club revenues
before sharing in the benchmark case (1), it is obvious that it must
hold that [[beta].sub.y] > [k.sub.y] and [[beta].sub.x] >
[k.sub.x]. Otherwise, the small-market club would be worse off after
sharing than before sharing. Under these conditions, the Nash
equilibrium can be found to be:
[t.sub.x.sup.a]/{t.sub.y.sup.a] =
[p.sub.x][[beta].sub.x][m.sub.x]/[p.sub.y][[beta].sub.y][m.sub.y] (14)
which is a more balanced distribution of talent than the benchmark
case in (5), because ([p.sub.x][[beta].sub.x])[p.sub.y] + [k.sub.y])
< ([p.sub.y] + [[beta].sub.y])[p.sub.x] + [k.sub.x]).
Discussion and Conclusion
Comparing the outcomes of the Nash equilibrium scenarios in the
previous section, decentralized selling with equal sharing worsens the
competitive balance, whereas the impact of centralized selling with
equal or performance-related sharing is theoretically indeterminate.
Only the individual selling and performance-related sharing of broadcast
rights seems to improve the competitive balance.
A simple numerical example can illustrate this point. In Table 1,
the benchmark case is compared with the four scenarios in this paper. It
shows that the case of decentralized selling with performance-related
sharing offers the best guarantee to improve the competitive balance.
Also, centralized selling and performance-related sharing has a, albeit
smaller, positive effect on competitive balance, because in the
numerical example [k.sub.x]/[k.sub.y] = [p.sub.x]/[p.sub.y]. It can also
be seen in Table 1 that a more equal distribution of the collected
broadcast money does not necessarily result in a better competitive
balance.
However, one can expect that the total amount of broadcast revenue
collected by a monopolist will be higher than the sum of the rights that
can be collected by decentralized selling. The reason is that a
profit-maximizing league will maximize total broadcast revenue given
that the marginal cost is close to zero. Moreover, the transaction costs
of an intensive decentralized bargaining process between all clubs and
all broadcasters will be higher (see also Andreff & Bourg, 2006). To
the extent that more club revenue increases the absolute quality of the
games, this can also be favorable for the spectators. On the other hand,
an important advantage of decentralized selling is that it does not
cause the welfare loss one can expect in a monopoly market, with
broadcast rights (and pay-per-view) that are too high and the number of
broadcast games that is too low. If the televised sports are
free-to-air, the higher broadcast rights do not result in any
pay-per-view, but then again, consumers have to pay higher taxes to
finance public television or higher prices given the marketing cost of
the products that are advertised on television. What is good for the
clubs and the league is not necessarily good for the spectators. So, a
welfare economic approach is appropriate to find the optimal
arrangement.
If improving the competitive balance is important, the analysis in
this paper shows that the case for pooling and sharing broadcast rights
in a sports league with profit-maximizing clubs is not very strong.
References
Andreff, W., & Bourg, J-F. (2006). Broadcasting rights and
competition in European football. In C. Jeanrenaud & S. Kesenne
(Eds.), Sports and the media (pp. 37-70). Cheltenham, UK and
Northampton, MA: Edward Elgar.
Falconieri, S., Palomino, F., & Sakovics, J. (2004). Collective
versus individual sale of television rights in league sports. Journal of
the European Economic Association, 2(5), 833-862.
Forrest, D., & Simmons, R. (2006). New issues in attendance
demand: The case of the English Football League. journal of Sports
Economics, 7(3), 247-266.
Fort, R. (2003). Sports economics. Englewood Cliffs, NJ: Prentice
Hall.
Garcia. J., & Rodriguez, P. (2002). The determinants of
football match attendance revisited: Empirical evidence from the Spanish
Football League. Journal of Sports Economics, 3(1), 1838.
Jeanrenaud, C., & Kesenne, S. (Eds). (2006). Sports and the
media. Cheltenham, UK and Northampton, MA: Edward Elgar.
Neale, W. (1964). The peculiar economics of professional sports.
Quarterly journal of Economics, 78(1), 1-14.
Noll, R. (1999). Competition policy in European sports after the
Bosman Case. In C. Jeanrenaud & S. Kesenne (Eds.), Competition
policy in professional sports, (pp. 17-43). Antwerp: Standaard Editions
Ltd.
Szymanski, S. (2003). The economic design of sporting contests.
journal of Economic Literature, XLI, 1137-1187.
Szymanski, S., & Kesenne, S. (2004). Competitive balance and
gate revenue sharing in team sports. journal of Industrial Economics,
51(4), 513-525.
White paper on sports. (2007). Commission of the European
Communities, Brussels, COM(2007) 391 final.
Stefan Kesenne, University of Antwerp
Stefan Kesenne is an economics professor in the Department of
Economics. His research interests include labor economics and sport
economics.
Table 1. Numerical Example (Performance-Related Sharing)
[A.sub.x] [p.sub.x] [m.sub.x] [B.sub [B.sub B [T.sub.x]/
= 500 = 10 = 8 .x] .y] [t.sub.y]
[A.sub.y] [p.sub.Y] [m.sub.y]
= 100 = 9 = 6
0.Benchmark [k.sub.x] [k.sub.y] 10000 1800 11800 1.48
case = 20 = 18
1. Collective
sale and 5900 5900 11800 1.48
equal sharing
2. Collective
sale and
performance-- [beta] = 19.66 9833 1967 11800 1.38
related
sharing
3. Individual
sale and 5900 5900 11800 4.07
equal sharing
4. Individual
sale and [[beta]. [[beta]. 9000 2800 11800 1.01
performance-- sub.x] sub.y
related = 18 = 28
sharing