The underpayment of restricted players in North American sports leagues.
Krautmann, Anthony C. ; von Allmen, Peter ; Berri, David 等
Introduction
One of the most widely held notions in sports economics is that
owners of professional sports teams exercise monopsony power whenever
and wherever they can. To create countervailing power, players have
responded by forming labor unions to bargain with owners on a more level
plane. But most collective bargaining agreements favor veteran players,
leaving younger players to the mercy of owners. In Major League Baseball
(MLB), for example, most players with three or less years of experience
are subject to the reserve clause which allows owners to unilaterally
determine their salaries. Only with experience comes eligibility for
arbitration, free agency, and a more equal bargaining relationship.
While the particular rules pertaining to eligibility differ, similar
bargaining rights exist in the National Football League (NFL) and the
National Basketball Association (NBA).
In this paper, we survey the three largest sports leagues in North
America to see the extent to which the underpayment of restricted
players is common across these leagues. While a similar study was
conducted on MLB (Krautmann et al., 2000), the other sports leagues have
been largely ignored. As such, we hope to provide sports economists with
evidence of how common such a practice is and to provide a comparison of
the size of such underpayments across leagues.
Our results indicate that the underpayment of restricted players is
a common practice among all three leagues. For those restricted players
with the least degree of negotiating power, this underpayment (or
surplus) ranges from about $492,000 for football players to more than
$2.7 million for starting basketball players. As a player's
negotiating power increases, the surplus extracted from him falls--in
the case of baseball players, it falls from $1.2 million to less than
$250,000. Finally, we find that the best players are underpaid the
most--in the case of restricted baseball players, the surplus extracted
from starters is more than five times that extracted from utility
players.
Literature Background
It is not surprising that fans appear resentful toward professional
athletes given that player salaries typically run into the millions of
dollars. But regardless of how large salaries are in professional
sports, economists tend to be more concerned with an athlete's
salary in relation to the value he generates for his team. If a player
generates $3 million for his team, yet is paid only $1 million, we would
still consider him underpaid.
Most of the prior work on this topic has concentrated on MLB.
Rottenberg (1956) was one of the first to discuss the monopsonization of
baseball talent arising from the reserve clause. He reasoned that
profit-maximizing owners would pay a salary somewhere between the
player's Marginal Revenue Product (MRP) and his non-baseball
salary. Scully (1974) devised a novel method for estimating a baseball
player's MRP by separately estimating the player's Marginal
Product (MP) and the team's Marginal Revenue (MR). By comparing
this imputed MRP to the player's salary, Scully concluded that
players from the pre-free agency era (i.e., prior to 1976) were paid
only about 10 to 20 percent of their MRP. He later applied his
methodology to the salary conspiracy of the mid-1980s and found that
wages of free agents had fallen to about 30 percent of MRP (Scully,
1989). Subsequent studies applying the Scully method have come to a wide
variety of conclusions regarding whether free-agent baseball players are
paid their MRPs. (1)
In a paper addressing the role of training costs and player
salaries, Krautmann et al. (2000) proposed a free-market approach to
assess the MRP of baseball players restricted by the reserve clause. By
assuming that a competitive labor market would result in free agents
being paid their MRP, these authors substituted free-agent wages for
MRP, then estimated the determinants of MRP in a standard wage
regression model. Applying the estimated coefficients from this
regression to the performance statistics of a restricted player gives
this player's imputed MRP (or alternatively, what the restricted
player would have been paid if he was a free agent). Comparing this
estimate of MRP to the player's actual wage would yield an estimate
of the amount by which he is underpaid. These authors found that the
average "Journeyman" (i.e., an arbitration-eligible player) is
essentially paid his MRP, while the average "Apprentice"
(i.e., an arbitration-ineligible player) is paid only about 25 percent
of his MRP. These results parallel the conclusions reached in Zimbalist
(1992a).
On the whole, the literature seems fairly unanimous in its
conclusion that restricted baseball players have been, and continue to
be, underpaid. While the notion of underpaying restricted players is
widely held, there has been very little analysis done on other sports
leagues. (2) In this paper, we update the literature by looking at the
underpayment of restricted players across the three largest sports
leagues. In addition, we hope to explain the size of the underpayment by
such things as characteristics of the player and his team, as well as
the idiosyncrasies of the particular league.
Estimating the Surplus Using the Free-Market Approach
While the Scully approach to estimating MRP is quite innovative, it
is limited when it comes to a cross-league comparison of salary
determination. For one, some leagues share broadcast revenues equally
across all teams, meaning that this important component of revenues is
essentially fixed. Since fixed revenues are completely win-inelastic,
this component of revenues should not enter into the computation of a
team's MR. Yet studies suggest that teams do share some portion of
these fixed revenues with players, which creates problems for defining
and estimating the MR component of MRP. (3) A further problem can arise
in identifying a particular player's MP. It is well-known that
player-productivity in some sports is highly interdependent, making it
nearly impossible to completely separate out the individual's
contribution to team wins.
One advantage of using the free-market approach is that it does not
entail the need to explicitly estimate a team's MR nor the
player's MP. Given the intensity of the bidding process for free
agents, this approach assumes that a free agent's wage reflects his
marginal value to his team (regardless of whether this value comes from
the gate, from broadcasting, or from concessions). As such, this
approach skirts the need to explicitly compute the marginal revenue of a
win. Furthermore, one would expect a team's bid to reflect a free
agent's contribution to winning in conjunction with the other
players on the team. For example, consider the bidding process for a
free-agent NFL running back. A rational bid for a running back would
surely internalize the particular characteristics of the team's
offense. If a team's offensive line is geared for run blocking,
then a running back with exceptional running skills will receive a high
bid from this team's GM. But if the offensive line is geared for
pass protection, then we would expect the GM to look for a running back
that is able to take on a blitzing linebacker and/or is especially adept
at receiving the dump-off pass. An explosive running back on a team set
for pass protection is less valuable (hence, will be offered a lower
wage) than a running back who is more proficient at blocking. Similar
arguments can be made for baseball and basketball as well. The same type
of allocative efficiency we traditionally ascribe to competitive markets
applies here as well--that is, competitive bidding results in
heterogeneous talent being allocated to its best-fit team. As such, the
free-market approach should be impervious to the empirical limitations
of fixed revenues and interdependency.
Because there are many characteristics that might make a player
valuable to his team, this approach suggests that the analyst uses a
sufficiently broad measure of the player's productivity, one which
spans many facets of performance. (4) In MLB, a broad and popular metric
of a player's offensive productivity is his OPS (equal to the sum
of his On-Base Percent and Slugging Average). In basketball, the NBA
Efficiency metric has been shown to be a good representation of how
player performance is compensated by decision makers. Because the NFL
does not compute and publish a composite metric of productivity for
offensive players (other than for quarterbacks), we use instead two
independent measures designed to capture the offensive productivity of
football players: total yards and touchdowns from passing, rushing, and
receiving.
Economic theory suggests that a player's MRP is determined by
his contribution to team success (i.e., his performance), as well as
other factors affecting the team's marginal revenue:
[MRP.sub.i] = f([Perf.sub.i], [Z.sub.i) (1)
The free-market approach begins by assuming that the competitive
bidding process for a free agent ultimately aligns his wage to his MRP.
Because our interest is in estimating the value of a player's
productivity to his team, we substitute the free agent's wage for
his MRP in (1) and run a standard regression of wages on expected
performance, E(Perf), and other variables, Z:
[wage.sub.i] = [alpha] + [[beta].sub.1] E([Perf.sub.1]) +
[[beta].sub.2] [Z.sub.i]] + [[epsilon].sub.i] ([for all]i[member of]
free agents) (2)
Expected or ex ante performance is used in (2) because new free
agent contracts are signed before the beginning of the season. Finally,
the wage data used in this analysis includes a prorated value of all
signing bonuses and other compensation components.
Since the coefficients in (2) are estimates of the marginal returns
to the right-hand side variables (especially productivity) on MRP, we
can apply these estimates to the restricted player's data to get
his imputed MRP:
?? = [alpha] + ??([Perf.sub.i]) + ?? {[[for all]j[member of]]
restricted players) (3)
Finally, to estimate the underpayment (SURPLUS), one simply
compares the restricted player's imputed MRP to his actual wage:
SURPLUSj = (?? - [wage.sub.j]) (4)
where SURPLUS > 0 implies that the restricted player is
underpaid (relative to a comparable free agent) and SURPLUS < 0
implies that he is overpaid.(5)
We then examine whether the surplus extracted from restricted
players varies systematically with characteristics of the player, team,
or league. In MLB, for example, arbitration-ineligible Apprentices have
less bargaining power than arbitration-eligible Journeymen. As such, one
would expect Apprentices to be more susceptible to exploitation, thus
generate a larger surplus. Further, starting (or full-time) players
contribute more to team wins than utility (or part-time) players; thus
the surplus extracted from starting restricted players may be larger
than that extracted from utility players. (6)
In addition to these player characteristics, there are a number of
differences between the leagues which could also have an impact on the
size of the surplus. For example, owners may be more willing to exercise
their monopsony power if they can justify extracting a surplus from
their restricted players to help them recoup their player development
expenses associated with the minor-league system. In this regard, we
would expect the surplus of restricted baseball players to be large
given the degree to which MLB teams depend upon its minor leagues teams
for developing players (Krautmann et al., 2000). The same possibility
existed in the NFL during the years included in our sample. For example,
in 2006, 226 players in the NFL had played in the NFL Europa League.
That said, the league also acknowledged that NFL Europa was also
designed to market American professional football in Europe. (7) As
such, while attributing the recovery of training and development costs
of NFL Europa may be legitimate in part, to attribute all costs
associated with NFL Europa to player development ignores the marketing
mission of that league. Given that NFL Europa was discontinued in 2007,
we see the investigation of this question as a fruitful area for future
research. While a development league does exist in the NBA (i.e., the
D-League), teams in the NBA do not rely heavily upon (nor do they have
much of a financial commitment to) this minor league. NBA teams
typically only allocate one or two players to their affiliated D-League
team. (8) In this regard, owners of NBA teams may not be able to justify
recouping training expenses in the same manner as do owners of MLB (and
possibly NFL) teams. Another reason to expect the surplus in MLB to be
larger arises from the fact that there is a large supply of reserve
players residing in the minor leagues. Such a large reserve of
substitutable players yields MLB owners a credible alternative which may
be used at the negotiating table. Finally, the surplus may vary across
leagues simply because of differences in the degree of risk associated
with highly paid draft picks that never end up producing for their team.
The manner in which initial salaries are determined also differs
dramatically across the leagues. Though drafted baseball and football
players can negotiate their salaries with the teams which drafted them,
no such negotiating takes place for draftees in the NBA. The Collective
Bargaining Agreement (CBA) in the NBA establishes fixed league-wide
salaries for all first-round draft picks regardless of the particular
player's value.
Finally, with the exception of place kickers, injuries would be
expected to play a more critical role in terms of the expected careers
of football players. If this greater propensity for injury leads to
shorter expected careers, then one can hardly fault NFL players for
getting as much money as they can early in their careers. As such,
restricted NFL players may be less willing to be underpaid than players
in the NBA and MLB.
Underpayment in Major League Baseball
Free Agent Wage Equation
We begin by gathering a sample of baseball players who were
eligible for free agency during the 1997 to 2002 seasons; this sample
consists of 308 potential free agents. Given the empirical problems
incumbent with the specialization of pitchers, we focus our analysis on
just free agent position players (i.e., hitters). The primary
performance statistic used here is an ex ante estimate of the
player's OPS, equal to the sum of on-base percent (OBP) and
slugging average (SA). (9) This metric is preferred over either of the
other two measures individually in that it recognizes the player's
ability to get on base in any manner together with his ability to move
around the base path. Forecasts of this performance statistic are
calculated yearly in the "Projections for Batters" Appendix in
Bill James' Major League Handbook. The vector of control variables,
Z, includes the player's primary position played, the population of
the metropolitan area in which his team is located (POP), and a dummy
variable which captures whether he is a starter or utility player
(UTILITY). (10)
As is standard procedure in this type of analysis, we estimated
equation (2) in terms of the natural log of salary (where salaries have
been measured in constant 2004 dollars). The Ordinary Least Squares
(OLS) estimates of free agents' wages are presented in Table 1.
According to Table 1, teams in larger cities pay higher wages, utility
players get paid less, and those players who are generally valued for
their defensive productivity get paid a higher salary. (11) A free
agent's wage also rises with his performance--the coefficient on
OPS is positive and significant. To get an idea of the economic
significance of performance on salary, we evaluated (2) at the point of
means and found that a starting second baseman whose OPS rises from the
mean (i.e., 0.734) to two standard deviations above the mean (i.e.,
0.896) would result in a threefold increase in his real salary--rising
from $1.6 million to $4.6 million.
Surplus of Restricted Players in MLB
To calculate the underpayment of restricted baseball players, the
estimates from Table 1 were applied to a sample of restricted baseball
players in the 2002 and 2003 seasons. This sample consists of 165
Apprentices and 78 Journeymen. Table 4 contains the median values of the
SURPLUS (in $2004), segmented into Apprentices and Journeymen, as well
as starters versus utility players. (12)
Not surprisingly, Table 4 shows that bargaining power is a very
important determinant of SURPLUS. Regardless of how one separates the
data, the median surplus extracted from Apprentices is positive and many
magnitudes larger than that extracted from Journeymen. Table 4 shows
that the median surplus extracted from Apprentices is $1.2 million, more
than five times larger than that extracted from the typical Journeyman.
On a relative basis, this means that the wage paid to a typical
Apprentice is less than 20 percent of his MRP, while the typical
Journeyman is paid over 85 percent of his MRP. Not only do owners
extract the greatest surplus from those with the least bargaining power,
but they also extract the greatest surplus from the best players. In the
case of Apprentices, the surplus extracted from starters is over five
times larger than that extracted from utility players.
Underpayment in the National Football League
Free Agent Wage Equation
For football players, equation (2) was estimated using salary data
based on a sample of 308 free agents from the 2004 and 2005 seasons. Due
to rules restrictions pertaining to which players can legally advance
the ball during a typical play, our sample contains only offensive
players at the quarterback, tight end, wide receiver, and running back
positions. For purposes of identifying the productivity metrics
associated with salary, we tested a variety of common measures including
total yards, touchdowns scored, fumbles, and interceptions. While we did
not find any significant relationship between salaries and either type
of turnover, we did find that total yardage and touchdowns were
significantly related to salary. We also found that the quarterback
position is fundamentally different from any of the other offensive
positions considered (perhaps due to the fact that quarterbacks are
involved in every offensive play). As a result, our final set of
productivity measures separate out the quarterback from the other
offensive positions. In particular, the productivity metrics used here
include: rushing and passing touchdowns for quarterbacks (QBTD); rushing
and receiving touchdowns for non-quarterbacks (NONQBTD); total yards
from rushing and passing for quarterbacks (QBYD); total yards from
rushing and receiving for non-quarterback (NONQBYD). (13) We also
included dummy variables for the quarterback (QB), wide receiver (WR),
and running back (RB) positions.
To estimate the wage equation, the ex ante measure of a
player's productivity is based on his performance in the prior
season (i.e., E([Perf.sub.t]) = [Perf.sub.t-1]). The primary reason for
using the prior season is that player contracts in the NFL are rarely
guaranteed for more than one year; as such, we would expect a
player's salary to be closely aligned with his performance from the
year before. Salary data are the official cap values (salary plus any
prorated signing and other bonuses), obtained from USA Today's
online database. (14) We recognize that the inclusion of amortized
signing bonuses mean that annual cap values are based in part on a
team's forecasted valuation at the time of the signing as opposed
to spot wages for current productivity. However, to include only the
non-guaranteed portion of a player's salary would significantly
underestimate payments to players for the productivity they provide.
While the use of non-guaranteed payments could constitute a test of some
form of reservation payment (wage), it would be a strongly inferior
choice in our effort to estimate the relationship between total payments
to labor and productivity. As was the case for MLB, equation (2) was
estimated in terms of the natural log of salary, where the salary
variable was measured in constant 2004 dollars.
One feature of football that makes it particularly difficult to
determine which players should be considered "starters" versus
"utility players" is that players are often substituted on a
play-by-play basis (depending on the situation; e.g., short yardage,
third down and long, etc.). If we had data which measured the number (or
percentage) of plays the player was involved in, then we could
potentially use this to delineate starters from utility players. But
absent such information, we are left to separate these two types of
players using a more generic measure of participation. In this study,
the criteria we used to identify starters are: quarterbacks with more
than 100 passes; running back with more than 75 rushes; wide receivers
with more than 35 receptions; and, tight ends with more than 25
receptions. In each case, players with less than the threshold were
considered utility players. We acknowledge that any division of this
type is at some level arbitrary. Yet, absent data at the individual play
level, we lack a continuous measure of participation.
Because the NFL has no local television revenues, and because gate
revenues are shared extensively, one would not expect market size to
have the same impact on NFL salaries as it does in MLB. (15) To allow
for this possibility, however, we include the population (POP) of the
metropolitan area, as measured in hundreds of thousands. Finally, we
have included positional dummy variables to control for quarterback
(QB), running backs (RB), wide receivers (WR), and tight ends. The
omitted dummy variable in our estimation is the tight-end position.
The results of running OLS on equation (2) are reported in Table 2.
Not surprisingly, we found that market size is not an important
determinant of players' salaries. The point estimate on UTILITY is
negative, but insignificant, meaning that utility players are not paid
less for the productivity that they generate than starters. Although we
find this result a little surprising, it may be due to the criterion
used to delineate starters from utility players.
Of particular interest are the coefficients on the productivity
measures. Table 2 shows that the coefficients on NONQBYD and QBTD are
both significant and positive, suggesting that more productive players
receive higher salaries. Though the coefficients on NONQBTD and QBYD are
both insignificant, this is likely due to the high correlation between
touchdowns scored and total yards gained. (16)
Surplus of Restricted Players in the NFL
Applying the results of the estimation in Table 2 to the 198
Apprentices (reserved players) and 86 Journeymen (restricted free
agents) in 2004 and 2005 allows us to examine the underpayment of
restricted players in the NFL. These results appear in Table 4. While
not as dramatic as was the case in MLB, we find that the surplus
extracted from restricted players again varies by the degree of
negotiating power. Table 4 shows the median surplus for Apprentices is
over $492,000, while the median surplus for Journeymen is only $264,000.
These results imply that the typical Apprentice in the NFL receives
about 50% of his MRP, while the typical Journeyman is paid over 75% of
his MRP. Consistent with our expectations, those players who generate
the largest productivity tend to have the greatest surplus extracted
from them. In Table 4, starters generate a larger surplus than that
generated by utility players (although the difference is not as severe
as that seen in MLB).
Underpayment in the National Basketball Association
Free Agent Wage Equation
For basketball players, equation (2) was estimated using a sample
of free agents who signed multi-year contracts from the 2000-01 through
2005-06 seasons. This sample consists of 378 player-observations. We
estimate free agent salaries in the NBA as a function of three key
factors--player performance, market size, and position played. The key
variable, player performance, is measured by the official NBA Efficiency
metric (NBAEFF) because this appears to be the primary statistic used in
the salary determination decision. (17) Because a player's
contribution to the team varies across position played (i.e., big men
tend to get rebounds and not commit turnovers, guards do the opposite),
this performance measure is calculated relative to the average
performance at each position. This relative performance measure is then
adjusted to reflect the NBA Efficiency on a per-game basis. (18)
In addition to this performance metric, we included the population
(POP) of the metropolitan area of the player's team to control for
possible market-size effects. To control for position-related effects on
salary, we included dummy variables for the center position (CENTER),
power forward (PWFORWARD), small forward (SMFORWARD), and point guard
(PTGUARD). The omitted dummy variable in our estimation is the
shooting-guard position. Finally, we included dummy variables to control
for bench player (UTILITY), here defined as those who averaged less than
24 minutes per game. The dependent variable used is the log of the
average salary on the newly signed contract, measured in constant 2004
dollars.
The OLS estimates of equation (2) are reported in Table 3. Table 3
also shows that neither market size nor bench players are related to
free agent salaries. Our results also suggest that teams pay a premium
for centers and forwards (relative to shooting guards). In regards to
performance, our results are not surprising. We find that a
player's productivity has a significantly positive impact on his
salary. To get the economic impact of this effect, consider a shooting
guard whose productivity rises from the mean (10.4) to two standard
deviations above the mean (20.8). (19) The estimates in Table 3 predict
that such a player would see over a 300 percent rise in his
salary--going from $3.1 million to $13.8 million.
Surplus of Restricted Players in the NBA
The results reported in Table 3 were applied to a collection of
restricted NBA players. Given that NBA rosters contain only 12 players,
for the most part, only first-round draft picks make the team that
drafted them. Furthermore, the collective bargaining agreement (CBA)
during the sample period specified the salaries for these draftees and
locks in those players for the first three years of their career. (20)
As such, those players on NBA rosters with less than four years
experience are almost entirely composed of players whose salaries were
determined by the terms of the CBA. For this reason, we defined the set
of restricted players as those with less than four years of NBA
experience. Our sample contains all such players during the 2005-06 and
2006-07 seasons.
Our results indicate a substantial level of underpayment of
restricted NBA players. Table 4 shows that the median surplus extracted
from all restricted basketball players was $732,000, implying that the
typical player received only about two-thirds of his MRP. Furthermore,
in comparing restricted starters to restricted utility players (where a
starter is defined as a player who averaged at least 24 minutes per
game), we find that starters generate nearly five times the surplus
generated by utility players.
Cross-League Comparisons and Concluding Observations
Altogether, our results are consistent with the hypothesis that
owners of professional sports teams exercise monopsony power whenever
and wherever they can. Although the absolute size of the surplus, and
the potential justification for doing so, may differ across the three
sports, the following similarities are more striking:
* restricted players are significantly underpaid,
* the surplus falls with the negotiating power of the player,
* and the largest surpluses are extracted from those players who
create the greatest value.
We entered this research project expecting Apprentices in MLB to
generate the largest surplus of all three sports. For one, owners spend
a much greater amount on their minor leagues, and thus need to use this
surplus to recoup as much of their training expenses as possible. While
development leagues do exist in the NFL and NBA, the commitment to these
minor leagues is inconsequential compared to that seen in MLB. In
addition, the large supply of replacement players residing in
baseball's minor leagues give MLB owners many more options than in
the NFL or NBA, thus yielding owners even more negotiating power.
Indeed, we found that the average Apprentice in MLB is paid only
about 19% of his MRP--the smallest percent across all three sports. But
in an absolute sense, the size of the surplus extracted from starting
NBA Apprentices was the largest of all three sports. This might be
explained in large part by the wage-determination process in the NBA.
Apprentices in MLB and the NFL are free to negotiate their initial
salaries when they are first drafted (although, most Apprentices in MLB
are paid the Major League minimum salary). But the salary of a
first-round draft choice in the NBA (who is often a starter) is
completely determined by the terms specified in the CBA. This is
consistent with the major conclusion we find across all three
sports--owners extract surplus wherever and whenever they can. Since the
greatest value is generated by starters, and these players have the
least amount of countervailing power, it is not surprising to find that
the largest surplus is extracted from the young restricted superstars.
Acknowledgments
We would like to thank the participants at the 2007 Western
Economics Association meetings in Seattle for their many helpful
comments. In particular, we would like to thank Elizabeth Gustafson for
her many insightful suggestions, and to Michael Leeds for his empirical
suggestions. All the usual caveats apply.
References
Baldinger, B. (2007). The passing of NFL Europa shouldn't be
taken lightly. Retrieved March 6, 2009, from
http://www.nfl.com/nflnetwork/story?id=09000d5d8014a7d4
&template=with-vi
Berri, D. (2007). Back to back evaluation on the gridiron. In J. H.
Albert & R. H. Koning (Eds.) Statistical thinking in sport (pp.
235-256). Boca Raton, FL: Chapman & Hall/CRC
Berri, D., & Krautmann, A. C. (2006). Shirking on the court:
Testing for the incentive effects of guaranteed pay. Economic Inquiry,
44, 536-546.
Berri, D., Schmidt, M. B., & Brook, S. L. (2006). The wages of
wins: Taking measure of the many myths in modern sport. Palo Alto, CA:
Stanford University Press.
Berri, D., Schmidt, M. B., & Brook, S. L. (2004). Stars at the
gate: The impact of star power on NBA gate revenues. journal of Sports
Economics, 5(1), 33-50.
Blass, A. (1992). Does the baseball labor market contradict the
human capital model of investment? Review of Economics and Statistics,
74, 261-268.
Bradbury, J. C. (2007). The Baseball Economist. New York: Dutton.
Cassing, J., & Douglas, R. (1980). Implications of the auction
mechanism in baseball's free agent draft. Southern Economic
journal, 47, 110-121.
Hill, J. (1985). The threat of free agency and exploitation in
professional baseball: 1976-1979. Quarterly Review of Economics and
Business, 25, 68-82.
Krautmann, A. C., Hadley, L., & Gustafson, E. (2000). Who pays
for minor league training costs? Contemporary Economic Policy, 18,
37-47.
NFL Europa Closes. (2007). Retrieved March 6, 2009, from
http://www.nfl.com/news/
story?id=09000d5d801308ec&template=without-video&confirm=true
Oorlog, D. (1995). Marginal revenue and labor strife in Major
League Baseball. Journal of Labor Research, XVI, 25-42.
Rottenberg, S. (1956). The baseball players' labor market.
Journal of Political Economy, 64, 242258.
Scott, F., Jr., Long, J., & Sompu, K. (1985). Salary vs.
marginal revenue product under monopsony and competition: The case of
professional basketball. Atlantic Economic Journal, 13(3), 50-59.
Scully, G. (1974). Pay and performance in Major League Baseball.
American Economic Review, 64, 915-930.
Scully, G. (1989). The business of Major League Baseball. Chicago:
University of Chicago Press.
Sommers, P., & Quinton, N. (1982). Pay and performance in Major
League Baseball: The case of the first family of free agents. journal of
Human Resources, 17, 426-436.
USA Today salaries databases: Football. Retrieved March 6, 2009,
from http://content.usatoday.com/sports/football/nfl/salaries/default.aspx
Von Allmen, P., McGlinn, G., & Brul, R. (2006). Wages,
productivity and monopsony power in the NFL. Working paper presented at
2006 WEA meetings.
Zimbalist, A. (1992a). Salaries and performance: Beyond the Scully
Model. Diamonds are forever: The business of baseball. Washington, DC:
Brookings Institute.
Zimbalist, A. (1992b). Baseball and billions. New York: Basic
Books.
Endnotes
(1) See Casing and Douglas (1980), Sommers and Quinton (1982), Hill
(1985), Zimbalist (1992a, 1992b), Blass (1992), Oorlog (1995), and
Bradbury (2007).
(2) A recent working paper by von Allmen et al. (2006) did look at
the underpayment in the NFL, although the issue has not been applied to
the NBA in over two decades (see Scott, Long, and Sompu, 1985).
(3) Berri, Brook, and Schmidt (2004) introduced a model of gate
revenue for the NBA, a model that was expanded for Berri, Schmidt, and
Brook (2006). When total revenue is used as the dependent variable, each
win was found to be worth (i.e., MR) about $540,000. Yet NBA teams paid
out a total of $1.8 billion to their players in 2006-07, which works out
to about $1.5 million per victory. The reason the value per victory is
so much higher than the MR is that the Collective Bargaining Agreement
specifies that players receive a share of the national broadcasting
revenues. As such, sharing these fixed revenues makes deriving an
estimate of a team's MR very difficult.
(4) In labor economics, tenure is an important control variable
used to impute a worker's MRP primarily because analysts typically
do not have direct measures of productivity. In sports economics, on the
other hand, the analyst is able to directly measure the player's
performance, as long as the analysis proxies MP using reasonable and
sufficient statistics. As such, we do not need to include experience
(and possibly, its square) as we are directly measuring this component
of productivity.
(5) Note that our use of the variable SURPLUS is a measure of what
the restricted player would have received if he were a member of the
free agent class (instead of the disadvantaged class). Whether this
underpayment arises from the monopsonistic exploitation of owners, or is
directly a result of terms specified in the CBA (which allows for such
exploitation), our measure of SURPLUS is simply a proxy for the
difference between what such a player is worth and what he is paid.
(6) This may be particularly likely given that most Apprentices
(especially in MLB and the NBA) are paid the minimum salary stipulated
in the Collective Bargaining Agreement.
(7) Data on NFL Europa alumni are from Brian Baldinger, "The
Passing of NFL Europa Shouldn't be taken Lightly:' At
http://www.nfl.coin/nflnetwork/
story?id=09000d5d8014a7d4&template=with-vi. In this article,
Baldinger argues strongly for the development role of the league. The
marketing function of the league is acknowledged in the announcement of
the league's closure in "NFL Europa Closes" at
http://www.nfl.coin/news/
story?id=09000d5d801308ec&template=without-video&confirm=true.
(8) An owner of a local D-League team told one of the co-authors
that the primary function of the D-league was to create a supply of
non-playing labor (e.g., referees, sports marketing, etc.).
(9) When it comes to the production of team wins, the OPS metric
does a reasonable job in predicting wins as any other metric or set of
metrics. In an auxiliary regression of team wins on ERA and OPS, we
found that the adjusted R-square was 0.86. When we ran the regression of
wins on ERA and SA and OBP, the adjusted R-square remained at 0.86.
Furthermore, by summing SA and OBP together, this metric implicitly
weighs each productivity component equally. This is particularly
appealing given that a simple regression of free-agent salaries on SA
and OBP revealed that the regression coefficients on these two
productivity measures were not significantly different from each other.
Thus, since both measures are equally valued when it comes to
compensation, and OPS weighs the two measures equally, we believe OPS
provides a reasonable productivity measure to determine salaries.
(10) A utility player is defined as one who is expected to appear
in fewer than half of the games played over the entire season (i.e.,
less than 81 games).
(11) The defensive positions refer to the catcher, shortstop, and
centerfielder positions. In Table 1, all three positions are paid
significantly more than the default position (i.e., second base).
(12) Median, rather than mean, values are reported given the
typically skewed nature of income-related data. We would like to thank
Michael Leeds for making this suggestion to us.
(13) In some way, our measures of productivity appears to double
count the yards produced by players on the field. That is, yards passing
by a QB must be equal to the yards receiving by a receiver. This is not,
however, a problem in the analysis because yards produced by QB and
receivers is a joint product which necessitates both sides of the pass.
If a pass is thrown, but no player receives it, it does not produce
wins. Clearly, general managers understand this joint production aspect
of NFL players, and their wage bids for players should be an efficient
reflection of this recognition. As such, there should be no problem of
"doubling counting" when it comes to the determination of
salaries.
(14) The USA Today database cap value for each player
"represents the player's pro-rated signing bonus, plus salary
and other bonuses for the season ... [O]ther Bonuses includes roster,
report, workout and other bonuses, plus any likely-to-be-earned
bonuses:' Source: "USA Today Salaries Databases:
Football:' http://content.usatoday.coin/sports/football/
nfl/salaries/default.aspx
(15) In the NFL, the home team keeps 60% of the gate, while the
remaining 40% goes into a pool shared by all teams.
(16) In our sample, the correlation coefficient between NONQBYD and
NONQBTD was greater than 0.80, while the correlation between QBTD and
QBYD was greater than 0.90.
(17) The NBA Efficiency metric is given by: (Points + Rebounds +
Steals + Assists + Blocked Shots--All Missed Shots--Turnovers). Although
the work of Berri et al. (2006) offered evidence that this measure is
not the best metric of a player's impact on wins, it is a very good
measure of how player performance is evaluated by coaches and general
managers (hence closely related to a teams' salary bids). A similar
story was told in Berri and Krautmann (2006).
(18) Specifically we determined each free agent's per-minute
NBA Efficiency value. We then subtracted the average at each position,
and then added back the average value for NBA Efficiency across all
positions, or 0.45. Once we took these steps, we then multiplied what we
had by the number of minutes a player played.
(19) To give an example of a shooting guard performing around the
mean NBA Efficiency per game is Bryant Stith in the 2001-02 season. A
player performing around two standard deviations above the mean is Allen
Iverson in the 2003-04 season.
(20) The CBA was updated in 2005 so that first-round draft picks
were automatically signed to a two-year contract, with the team having
an option for the third and fourth years.
Anthony C. Krautmann [1], Peter von Allmen [2], and David Berri [3]
[1] DePaul University
[2] Moravian College
[3] Southern Utah University
Anthony C. Krautmann is a professor of economics at DePaul
University. His primary research interest is in the field of sport
economics, where the range of topics studied include the Rottenberg
Invariance Principle, shirking and long-term contracts, competitive
balance, and the wage determination process in professional sports.
Peter von Allmen is a professor of economics at Moravian College.
His research focuses on labor-related issues in the professional sports
industry.
David J. Berri is an associate professor of economics in the
Department of Economics and Finance at Southern Utah University. His
current research focuses on the economics of sport, specifically the
topics of consumer demand, competitive balance, and worker productivity.
Table 1: Free Agent Wages in MLB
($2004)
Dependent variable: In(wages)
Variable Coefficient T-STAT
Constant 9.488 *** 19.91
OPS 6.428 *** 9.80
POP 0.000014 * 1.72
CAT 0.287 ** 2.09
FIRST 0.121 0.71
SS 0.731 *** 4.45
THIRD 0.185 1.22
LF -0.091 -0.51
CF 0.668 *** 3.54
RF 0.219 1.19
UTILITY -0.524 *** -3.73
[Rsup.2] 0.48
# observations 224
*** significant at 1% level
** significant at 5% level
* significant at 10% level
Table 2: Free Agent Wages in the NFL
($2004)
Dependent variable: In(wages)
Variable Coefficient T-STAT
Constant 13.55 *** 119.6
NONQBYD 0.001 *** 6.03
NONQBTD 0.014 0.90
QBYD 0.0001 0.63
QBTD 0.043** 2.20
POP 0.001 0.57
QB 0.22 1.30
RB -0.27 * -1.90
WR 0.04 0.38
UTILITY -0.02 -0.21
[R.sup.2] 0.46
# observations 308
*** significant at 1% level
** significant at 5% level
* significant at 10% level
Table 3: Free Agent Wages in the NBA
($2004)
Dependent variable: In(wages)
Variable Coefficient T-STAT
Constant 13.36 *** 75.33
NBAEFF 0.139 *** 15.39
POP 1.13 x [10.sup.-8] ** 1.98
CENTER 0.624 *** 6.34
PWFORWARD 0.323 *** 3.17
SMFORWARD 0.210 ** 2.00
PTGUARD 0.166 1.64
UTILITY -0.071 -0.713
[R.sup.2] 0.64
# observations 378
*** significant at 1% level
** significant at 5% level
* significant at 10% level
Table 4: Median Values of Surplus (in $2004)
Restricted Players
(Number of observations in each cell)
All Players Starters Utility
Wages as a
SURPLUS % of [??] SURPLUS SURPLUS
MLB Apprentices (1) $1,217,000 19% $1,676,000 $311,000
(165) (114) (51)
Journeymen (2) $221,000 86% $304,000 -$158,000
(78) (64) (14)
NFL Apprentices (3) $492,000 50% $575,000 $482,000
(198) (71) (127)
Journeymen (4) $264,000 77% $551,000 $178,000
(86) (59) (27)
NBA Apprentices (5) $732,000 66% $2,700,000 $564,000
(272) (83) (189)
Notes:
(1) For MLB, Apprentices refers to arbitration-ineligible players
(mostly those with less than four years of experience)
(2) For MLB, Journeymen refers to arbitration-eligible players (those
with between four and six years of experience)
(3) For the NFL, Apprentices refers to reserve players (those with
less than three years experience and playing under the reserve clause)
(4) For the NFL, Journeymen refers to restricted free agents (those
with three years of experience, and whose team can match any
free-agent offer)
(5) For the NBA, Apprentice refers to players with less than four
years of experience