首页    期刊浏览 2024年11月30日 星期六
登录注册

文章基本信息

  • 标题:Investment in stadia and regional economic development--evidence from FIFA World Cup 2006.
  • 作者:Feddersen, Arne ; Grotzinger, Andre Leao ; Maennig, Wolfgang
  • 期刊名称:International Journal of Sport Finance
  • 印刷版ISSN:1558-6235
  • 出版年度:2009
  • 期号:November
  • 语种:English
  • 出版社:Fitness Information Technology Inc.
  • 摘要:A series of studies on Metropolitan Statistical Areas (MSAs) in the USA revealed that new sport stadiums do not generate significant income and/or employment effects in their host cities,1 challenging the "boosters" view of many politicians and sport officials who claim beneficial effects for the local economy (and hence, a justification for public financial support).
  • 关键词:Economic development;Sports associations;Stadiums

Investment in stadia and regional economic development--evidence from FIFA World Cup 2006.


Feddersen, Arne ; Grotzinger, Andre Leao ; Maennig, Wolfgang 等


Introduction

A series of studies on Metropolitan Statistical Areas (MSAs) in the USA revealed that new sport stadiums do not generate significant income and/or employment effects in their host cities,1 challenging the "boosters" view of many politicians and sport officials who claim beneficial effects for the local economy (and hence, a justification for public financial support).

Using the case of the new stadiums for the 2006 FIFA World Cup in Germany, this paper is the first multivariate work that examines the potential income and employment effects of new stadiums outside of the USA. Such a study is generally interesting because it is set against the background of the different urban structures in the USA and Europe. In addition, a non-US study is especially interesting because of decade-long US tradition of allocating the stadiums in suburban areas, whereas European stadiums are mostly located near to the city center. Nelson (2001) argued that (US-)studies concluding insignificant effects on the home cities of stadiums are misleading because the data are based on stadia built in the 1960s-1980s. Stadiums in inner cities might be more efficient for the regional development of the cities, although for suburban stadiums the effects on regional economic development are insignificant or even negative (Melaniphy, 1996; Santee, 1996).

This study is the first work on this topic that conducts tests on the basis of Difference-in-Difference (DD) model with levels and trends. To address the problem of potential serial correlation in DD models (Bertrand, Duflo, & Mullainathan, 2004), we use a serial correlation consistent arbitrary variance-covariance matrix. As robustness check we use the ignoring time series information (ITSI) model in a form that is modified for non-synchronous interventions.

The aim of this paper is to isolate the effects of the construction and use of modern sports stadiums built in connection with the 2006 FIFA World Cup in Germany on income and employment at a regional scale. Our analysis distinguishes between effects in the short term (period of planning and construction, ending with the inauguration of the stadium) and long term (afterwards). Our study adds evidence on the economic impact of sport facilities built for mega-sports events, like the FIFA World Cup, Olympic Games, or professional sports leagues, and to the political debate on financing sports facilities and mega-sports events.

Background and Literature Review

"And the winner is ... Deutschland!" On June 6, 2000, these were the words of FIFA President Joseph Blatter, announcing the host of the 2006 FIFA World Cup. Following the (widely supported) bid by the German Football Association (DFB), this was the starting signal for a period of stadium construction (building new stadiums or major renovations of existing stadiums). All in all, about 20 cities built new stadiums before the decision of DFB and FIFA on the host cities was published. FIFA and the local organizing committee fixed the number of World Cup venues to 12 by means of an open tendering procedure. Thereby, the DFB forced the competition between applying cities, encouraging them to build a modern stadium to increase their chances to be elected as a match venue. Finally, the 2006 FIFA World Cup in Germany was held in Berlin, Cologne, Dortmund, Frankfurt, Gelsenkirchen, Hamburg, Hannover, Kaiserslautern, Leipzig, Munich, Nuremberg, and Stuttgart. The investment costs for new construction or major renovations totaled an amount of nearly 1.6 billion [euro] for these 12 stadiums (Fifa, 2006). (2) An additional 1.6 billion [euro] was invested into stadia-related infrastructure in these cities. In the other cities, another 515 million [euro] was spent for stadium construction work only.

The size of the cities elected as match venues for the FIFA World Cup varies strongly. Many of the biggest German cities were among the list, like Berlin (3.4 million/No. 1), Hamburg (1.7 million/No. 2), Munich (1.2 million/No. 3), Cologne (1.0 million/No. 4), Frankfurt (0.65 million/No. 5), Dortmund (0.59 million/No. 7), and Stuttgart (0.57 million/No. 8). Also, medium sized cities were named as match venues, like Gelsenkirchen (0.28 million / No. 21), and one small city with less than 100,000 habitants (Kaiserslautern) was elected. The cases of Leipzig and Kaiserslautern are special due to a strong political influence in the selection process. Leipzig was chosen because at least one city from eastern Germany should become a match venue, even if no professional soccer team is located in the city. Kaiserslautern, on the other hand, has a long tradition in professional soccer in Germany, and it is the only venue in the federal state of Rhineland-Palatine.

Before the 2006 World Cup in Germany, a series of analyses was published, according to which, the investments connected with staging the World Cup as well as the expenditure of the expected 1-2 million foreign visitors would markedly affect income and employment. As usual for ex-ante impact studies, the predictions were optimistic. The estimates fluctuated between a 2 billion [euro] and a 10 billion [euro] increase in income or up to 10,000 additional jobs (see e.g., Deutsche Industrie- und Handelskammer, 2006; Deutsche Postbank AG, 2005a, 2005b, 2006).

In some of the above studies, positive long-term effects are also mentioned resulting from (1) consumer spending due to sports events staged in the new stadiums including multiplier effects or (2) intangible benefits like increased image, happiness, or feel-good--and potentially inducing further investment.

Until now, only few ex-post analysis of the economic impact of the 2006 FIFA World Cup exist. The descriptive analyses of Brenke and Wagner (2007) and Maennig (2007) found no effect of the event in countrywide macroeconomic time series but mention feel-good effects and beneficial effects on the economic structure toward a more service oriented economy. Time series analyses of Allmers and Maennig (in press) isolate a significant increase of overnight stays at hotels by foreigners (approximately 700,000) and an additional 600 to 700 million [euro] (US $830 to 970 million) in net national tourism income. (3) The only econometric analysis on the 2006 World Cup using regional data by Hagn and Maennig (2007)--concentrating on the event itself and not considering effects during the construction period--finds no significant job market effects of the 2006 World Cup.

The econometric ex-post studies published so far that elaborate on other soccer World Cups do not form a contradiction to such a pessimistic view. Szymanski (2002) collected data on the 20 largest economies measured by current GDP over the last 30 years. Many of these countries have hosted the Olympic Games or the World Cup at least once in the past 30 years. Using a simple regression, he concluded that the growth of these countries is significantly lower in World Cup years. (4) Sterken (2006) finds that World Cups have a positive effect, which is quite limited. Hagn and Maennig (2008) showed that the 1974 World Cup, which was held in Germany, did not generate significant short- or long-term employment effects in that country. Baade and Matheson (2004) show that, for the 1994 World Cup in the USA, nine of the 13 host cities suffered falls in growth. Overall, the 13 locations suffered losses on balance of over US $9 billion.

Such findings are paralleled by studies on other large sport events. Only few studies have found significant positive effects of sports facilities and sports events ex-post. Baim (1994) found positive employment effects for Major League Baseball (MLB) and the National Football League (NFL) for 15 cities in the USA. Hotchkiss, Moore, and Zobay (2003) found significant positive effects on employment in regions of Georgia, affiliated or close to activities of the Atlanta Olympic Games in 1996, but they did not find significant effects on wages. Feddersen and Maennig (2009) rejected their findings on employment after checking for serial correlation and allowing for a simultaneous test of level and trend effects. Carlino and Coulson (2004) found positive effects of NFL teams on central on housing rents but no significant increase in wages, and they interpreted this finding as positive effects of the NFL. Tu (2005) found significant positive effects of the FedEx Field (Washington) on real estate prices of its neighborhood, as did Ahlfeldt and Maennig (2008, 2009) for three arenas in Berlin, Germany. Kasimati and Dawson (2009) simulated positive short-term income effects of the 2004 Olympic Games in Greece. Finally, Jasmand and Maennig (2008) found (limited) long-term positive income effects for German regions which hosted the 1972 Olympic Games but no employment effects. (5)

The majority of studies suggest that sporting events or sports stadia have little or no significant effect on regional wages, income, and/or employment (e.g., Baade, 1987, 1994; Baade & Dye, 1990; Baade & Sanderson, 1997). A number of works, particularly those of Coates and Humphreys (1999, 2000, 2001, 2003) or Teigland (1999), have even arrived at significant negative effects.

Coming back to the case of 2006 FIFA World Cup, Preuss, Schutte, and Kurscheidt (2007), in a survey based analysis, estimated a primary economic impact of about 3 billion [euro], resulting mainly from foreign visitors. Compared with the German GDP of 2,303 billion [euro] in 2006, this primary economic impact is 0.13%. Thus, it is not surprising that econometric estimates from countrywide impact studies do not find a significant effect.

The need for additional analysis on the basis of more disaggregated and regionalized data is obvious.

Data

The analytical framework for this study comprises data of the 118 most populated large urban districts ("Kreisfreie Stadte") in Germany in 1995, as reported by the Arbeitskreis Volkswirtschaftliche Gesamtrechnung der Lander (2007b). (6) As variables for the regional economic development, the income of private households per capita (Arbeitskreis Volkswirtschaftliche Gesamtrechnungen Der Lander, 2007b) as well as the number of people employed (Arbeitskreis Volkswirtschaftliche Gesamtrechnungen Der Lander, 2007a) in these 118 large urban districts are considered.

[FIGURE 1 OMITTED]

For the income of private households, the period of observation is 1995 to 2005 (a time span of 11 years). A time span of 10 years is considered for employment data (1996 to 2005). As the data availability starts in 1995 or 1996, respectively, no structural breaks due to German reunification have to be considered. (7)

The considered urban districts vary in employment and income size. Employment numbers varies between about 15,500 and 1.5 million employed persons. Income disperses between 10,833 [euro] and 23,615 [euro] per capita with a mean income of 715,868. Due to this variation, we take the logarithms of income and employment figures; coefficients can be interpreted as a percentage impact.

Several additional indicators of the regional economic development could be considered. Hotchkiss, Moore, and Zobay (2003), for instance, suggested that the DD equation could be estimated for population. Or, a sport venue or sport franchise (sport club) might increase the attractiveness of a city from a resident's point of view. As a consequence, ceteris paribus, migration into the city may occur. Even if real wages are lower in a city offering such an attractive benefit than in other cities that have no such sports facilities, some people might move to this city because the attraction (compensating differentials). Thus, initially, it might be appropriate to test for a population effect. However, because it is difficult to assume that unemployed persons will migrate due to the increased attractiveness of a city, we can assume that most migrants will be working in their new city. Thus, a strong correlation between population and employment exists, and an additional DD analysis on population is unnecessary.

Method and Results

DD Model with Level and Trend

The aim of this paper is to examine if stadium construction projects in Germany--especially those of the 2006 FIFA World Cup--had a significant impact on the economic development of the regions in which they are located. For this purpose, we use a DD estimation. This is a common approach for identifying the effect of a specific intervention or treatment. Therefore, one has to compare the differences in outcome before and after an intervention for groups affected by the intervention to the difference for unaffected groups (Bertrand, Duflo, & Mullainathan, 2004).

The 12 cities elected as match venue will be used as the treatment group in the DD model. During the period of observation, several additional stadium construction projects were undertaken in Germany. To avoid biased results, in addition to the FIFA World Cup stadiums, all relevant stadium construction projects were used as the treatment group in a second DD regression.

We focus our interest on differences in levels and trends for two variables: employment and income. Because the stadium construction work did not start at the same point in time for all cities (see Table 1), the pre-period and the post-period are not the same for all cities of the treatment group, and they are not even defined for the control cities. Thus, in contrast to many DD models8, no dummy variable for the post-period of all cities will be included. Equation (1) and (2) contain the modified DD model:

[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] (1)

where [Z.sub.it] is the income of private households in city i in year t or the employment in city i in year t, respectively. [alpha] denotes the intercept term. trend is a trend variable for all 118 large urban districts starting with the value of one in year 1995 (1996) and ends with a value of 11 (10) in year 2005. No dummy variable for the treatment group is included because our model is a fixed effects model (9) with separate dummies for all large urban districts capturing the treatment group effects. [PT.sub.it] is a dummy for the post intervention phase of the treatment group. It takes the value of one for cities with relevant stadia construction projects from the year of the start of the construction work (10) and zero otherwise. [TT.sub.it] is a dummy variable indicating an overall trend for the treatment group, which measures the difference in the growth trend between the treatment group and the control group for the observation period. It is the product of the variable trend and a binary variable taking the value of one if a city belongs to the treatment group. [PTT.sub.it] denotes a variable that covers a post period trend for the treatment cities. It is the product of the variables [PT.sub.it] and trend. In the years before the start of the construction project, it takes the value of zero, and afterwards, it displays the corresponding value of the trend variable. [[beta].sub.1], [[beta].sub.2], [[beta].sub.3], and [[beta].sub.4] are coefficients to be estimated. [m.sub.i] covers the unobserved individual specific effects (fixed effects), while [n.sub.it] denotes the remainder disturbance.

The coefficients of interests are [[beta].sub.1] and [[beta].sub.4] because they are measuring the level and trend effect of the intervention (stadia construction project) of the treatment cities. If a stadium construction project has positive regional effects, significant positive signs should be found in the employment model.

In per capita models, positive short-term effects might result from the direct spending for the construction work, especially if a sizable amount of investment is financed from outside the city (e.g., by the regional or federal government) and if price effect of the construction demand is absent.

In the long run, the sign of coefficients of income is theoretically ambiguous in the case positive economic effects of stadium construction projects. If we assume that the attractiveness of a city increases in the eyes of residents and non-residents (e.g., because of an eye-catching new stadium and its associated feel-good effects), then migration into the city may occur. If the population increases, the labor supply might increase, potentially leading to decreasing wages ("compensating differentials;" Carlino & Coulson, 2004).

A separation of short-run and long-run effects is thus indicated, but the model specification chosen in equation (1) does not allow isolating short-run effects of the construction work.

To isolate the effect of the pure construction phase, a second variant of the model (1) will be estimated:

[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] (2)

The variables trend, [TT.sub.it], and [PT.sub.it] are identical to those in model (1). To isolate the effects of the construction phase, the dummy variable C takes the value of one during the construction work and the value of zero otherwise. (11) [PTTC.sub.it] is a post intervention trend for the treatment group that starts after the construction work has finished because we expect that changes in the growth trend will occur not due to the construction but, rather, due to advancements in the attractiveness of the city that are derived only from the completed stadium. It has to be admitted, though, that, due to data limitations, for some stadia projects (e.g., Kaiserslautern or Stuttgart), only a few observations are available for [PTTC.sub.it], making it statistically demanding to isolate any post-construction effects for these cities.

As shown by Bertrand, Duflo, and Mullainathan (2004), DD models are frequently subject to serial correlation, which might lead to an overestimation of the significance of the "intervention" dummy. To check for such problems, we performed an LM test for serial correlation in a fixed effects model as suggested by Baltagi (2001, p. 94-95). (12) This test is performed on the residuals of standard fixed effects regressions of the above described models (1) and (2) for income and employment. (13)

The LM statistic indeed rejects the null hypothesis of no serial correlation in each case.

For such a case, Bertrand, Duflo, and Mullainathan (2004) suggest using an arbitrary variance-covariance matrix, which is consistent in the presence of any correlation pattern within cross section over time. Table 6 and Table 7 show the regression results of the DD coefficients and the corresponding t-statistics computed using an arbitrary variance-covariance matrix.

In all eight estimated models, the trend variable trend is significant at least at the 10% level. This means that there is a positive trend in income and employment for all regarded 118 German large urban districts. (14) The treatment trend dummy is insignificant in almost all models, with the exception of model (1) in the employment regression, implying that there is no systematic difference between the treatment and control groups in the growth pattern of urban districts. The coefficients of the post-period dummy [PT.sub.it] of the treatment urban districts and the respective coefficient of the post-trend dummy [PTT.sub.it]--the objects of interest--are insignificant for all estimations. The results are not affected by accounting for a special construction effect, as shown in model (2) of the income and employment regressions. Thus, the hypothesis of no income and employment effect of the stadia construction projects in the 12 and 20, respectively, urban districts with completed stadia construction cannot be rejected.

Ignoring Time Series Information DD Model

To check robustness, we will use the ignoring time series information (ITSI) model in its modification for non-synchronous interventions (Bertrand, Duflo, & Mullainathan, 2004). In a first step, [Z.sub.it] (equation 1 and 2) was regressed on city fixed effects, time fixed effects, and relevant covariates. (15) In the second step, the residuals of only the treatment group will be taken into account. These residuals will be divided into two groups: (1) residuals from years before the start of a stadia construction project and (2) residuals from years after the start of a stadia construction project. The stadia effect can then be analyzed by an OLS regression of a two-period regression of the residuals from the treatment cities only. Consistent t-statistics can be obtained from this OLS regression. (16)

The results of the ITSI models as shown in Table 8 and Table 9 confirm the findings of the DD model estimated earlier. No coefficient in the ITSI models is significant on any conventional level. The results of the robustness check support the results from the DD model using an arbitrary variance-covariance matrix.

Conclusion

This is the first study to analyze the impact of the 2006 FIFA World Cup or the construction work of the respective stadiums on both employment and income. Using the method of difference-in-difference estimation, we were not able to identify income or employment effects of the construction of the new stadiums for the 2006 World Cup that are significantly different from zero in the urban districts with completed new stadiums in the period leading up to and after the 2006 FIFA World Cup. In line with recent literature on DD estimates (Bertrand, Duflo, & Mullainathan, 2004), we estimated serial correlation consistent DD models if appropriate.

Our empirical results are well backed by theoretical considerations. The absence of positive short-term effects might be explained by crowding-out effects on "normal" investment and/or tourism, including a "time-switching effect" of tourism and a "carnival effect," describing increased travels abroad by locals to avoid noise, traffic jams, and other turbulences that are caused by the FIFA World Cup (Allmers & Maennig, in press). Also, for the long-term, "booster" arguments suffer from a list of methodological and theoretical problems (Coates & Humphreys, 2008, pp. 298-299). Only the spending of true "foreigners" (17) could be counted, and their share is often small for league matches. Furthermore, much of the sport event related spending by local residents comes out of their "entertainment or leisure budget." Thus, from the viewpoint of a city's economy, this would be identical to a merely substitution of consumer spending from entertainment to sports, and no economic impact would be expected from this source. Unfortunately, the multiplier of sport spending is likely to be smaller than the multiplier for entertainment. In contrast to owners and employees in the entertainment sector (e.g., theatres, cinemas, bowling halls), owners and players from professional sports teams often do not life within the city. Thus, regarding the high wages of professionals, the multiplier of entertainment spending should be much higher than the corresponding multiplier on sports spending. Finalizing this argumentation, one might say that having a sports stadium and a professional club might even decrease local income and employment rather than boost it. Second, the transmission process from happiness to fundamental economic indicators like income and employment seems to be weak. So, additional economic growth due to the intangible benefits is rather unlikely to occur. Third, if the expenditures of the city government are financed by debts, classical crowding-out effects might occur, which erase any positive long-term economic impact of a stadium.

We are thus unable to support local, state, or federal subsidies for sports stadiums and sport events if a "booster effect" on employment and income is the reasoning. Furthermore, we hesitate to share the concern expressed both implicitly and explicitly in many of the comparable sports economic studies that the positive effects of new stadiums claimed by many sports protagonists are not true for two reasons. Firstly, other effects such as the feel-good benefit for the population and/or image effects that are difficult to quantify, may be sufficiently important to justify major new stadiums and/or subsidies for them via public funds. With image effects and feel-good effects, economic empiricism in regards to sports is still in its infancy. (18) Thus, further research on this topic is needed. Secondly and more technically, the treatment group variables in the selected form of municipality areas might still be too large and too highly aggregated to statistically prove significant effects. Studies on the effects of major sports venues on property values in surrounding areas indicate a maximum affect area of some 3,000 meters (Ahlfeldt & Maennig, 2008, 2009; Tu, 2005).

Appendix
Table A1. Population of the 118 largest urban districts
("kreisfreie Stadte") in Germany in 1995

No.    City                           Population in 1995

1      Berlin                         3,471,003
2      Hamburg                        1,707,251
3      Munchen                        1,240,465
4      Koln                           964,597
5      Frankfurt am Main              651,097
6      Essen                          616,340
7      Dortmund                       599,966
8      Stuttgart                      586,954
9      Dusseldorf                     572,171
10     Bremen                         549,157
11     Duisburg                       535,473
12     Leipzig                        524,870
13     Hannover                       523,574
14     Dresden                        496,863
15     Nurnberg                       493,940
16     Bochum                         400,608
17     Wuppertal                      382,600
18     Saarbrucken Stadtverband       358,365
19     Bielefeld                      324,115
20     Mannheim Universitatsstadt     313,880
21     Gelsenkirchen                  292,061
22     Bonn                           291,863
23     Chemnitz                       291,331
24     Halle (Saale)                  287,052
25     Karlsruhe                      276,544
26     Wiesbaden                      266,532
27     Monchengladbach                266,095
28     Munster                        264,696
29     Magdeburg                      262,557
30     Augsburg                       260,952
31     Braunschweig                   253,513
32     Krefeld                        249,821
33     Aachen                         247,460
34     Kiel                           246,595
35     Rostock                        230,768
36     Oberhausen                     224,896
37     Lubeck Hansestadt              216,933
38     Hagen                          212,909
39     Erfurt                         212,532
40     Kassel                         201,628
41     Freiburg im Breisgau           198,394
42     Mainz                          184,329
43     Hamm                           183,734
44     Herne                          179,973
45     Mulheim an der Ruhr            176,602
46     Osnabruck                      168,106
47     Ludwigshafen am Rhein          167,872
48     Solingen                       165,794
49     Leverkusen                     162,051
50     Oldenburg (Oldenburg)          150,540
51     Potsdam                        144,941
52     Darmstadt                      138,973
53     Heidelberg                     138,612
54     Bremerhaven                    130,720
55     Cottbus                        127,791
56     Wurzburg                       127,627
57     Wolfsburg                      126,782
58     Regensburg                     125,809
59     Gera                           124,971
60     Remscheid                      122,710
61     Heilbronn                      121,745
62     Bottrop                        120,008
63     Pforzheim                      118,460
64     Salzgitter                     117,776
65     Schwerin                       116,876
66     Offenbach am Main              116,460
67     Ulm Universitatsstadt          115,379
68     Zwickau                        112,646
69     Ingolstadt                     111,626
70     Koblenz                        109,292
71     Furth                          108,011
72     Kaiserslautern                 101,970
73     Jena                           101,724
74     Erlangen                       101,372
75     Trier                          99,379
76     Dessau                         92,030
77     Wilhelmshaven                  90,944
78     Brandenburg an der Havel       87,713
79     Flensburg                      87,642
80     Neumunster                     82,030
81     Neubrandenburg                 81,786
82     Frankfurt (Oder)               81,633
83     Worms                          79,737
84     Delmenhorst                    78,079
85     Plauen                         73,318
86     Bayreuth                       72,692
87     Bamberg                        69,901
88     Gorlitz                        68,773
89     Stralsund                      66,944
90     Aschaffenburg                  66,339
91     Weimar                         62,257
92     Greifswald                     61,688
93     Kempten (Allgau)               61,494
94     Hoyerswerda                    61,441
95     Landshut                       59,257
96     Rosenheim                      58,704
97     Schweinfurt                    55,598
98     Suhl                           53,986
99     Neustadt an der Weinstrasse    53,828
100    Baden-Baden                    52,677
101    Hof                            52,628
102    Emden                          51,653
103    Passau                         51,035
104    Wismar                         50,870
105    Speyer                         49,575
106    Pirmasens                      48,562
107    Frankenthal (Pfalz)            47,946
108    Eisenach                       45,642
109    Amberg                         44,177
110    Straubing                      44,022
111    Coburg                         43,948
112    Weiden i.d.OPf.                43,171
113    Kaufbeuren                     42,694
114    Memmingen                      40,492
115    Ansbach                        39,638
116    Landau in der Pfalz            39,632
117    Schwabach                      37,564
118    Zweibrucken                    36,039

Source: Arbeitskreis Volkswirtschaftliche Gesamtrechnung
der Lander (2007b).


References

Ahlfeldt, G., & Maennig, W. (2008). The impact of sports arenas on land values: Evidence from Berlin. The Annals of Regional Science. Retrieved from http://dx.doi.org/10.1007/s0016800008-00249-00164

Ahlfeldt, G., & Maennig, W. (2009). Arenas, arena architecture and the impact on location desirability: The case of 'Olympic arenas' in Prenzlauer Berg, Berlin. Urban Studies, 46(7), 13431362.

Allmers, S., & Maennig, W. (in press). Economic impacts of the FIFA soccer World Cups in France 1998, Germany 2006, and Outlook for South Africa 2010. Eastern Economic Journal.

Arbeitskreis Volkswirtschaftliche Gesamtrechnungen der Lander. (2007a). Compensation of employees, gross wages and salaries in Germany on Nuts3-Level 1996 to 2005 [Electronic Version]. Retrieved from http://www.vgrdl.de/Arbeitskreis_VGR/R2B2.zip

Arbeitskreis Volkswirtschaftliche Gesamtrechnungen der Lander. (2007b). Income of private households in Germany on Nuts3-Level 1995 to 2005 [Electronic Version]. Retrieved from http://www.vgrdl.de/Arbeitskreis_VGR/R2B3.zip

Atkinson, G., Mourato, S., Szymanski, S., & Ozdemiroglu, E. (2008). Are we willing to pay enough to 'back the bid'?: Valuing the intangible impacts of London's bid to host the 2012 Summer Olympic Games. Urban Studies, 45(2), 419-444.

Baade, R. A. (1987). Is there an economic rationale for subsidizing sports stadiums? Heartland Policy Study No.13.

Baade, R. A. (1994). Stadiums, professional sports, and economic development: Assessing the reality. The Heartland Institute Policy Study, No. 62.

Baade, R. A. (1996). Professional sports as catalysts for metropolitan economic development. Journal of Urban Affairs, 18(1), 1-17.

Baade, R. A., & Dye, R. F. (1990). The impact of stadiums and professional sports on metropolitan area development. Growth and Change, 21(2), 1-14.

Baade, R. A., & Matheson, V. (2004). The quest for the Cup: Assessing the economic impact of the World Cup. Regional Studies, 38(4), 343-354.

Baade, R. A., & Sanderson, A. R. (1997). The employment effect of teams and sports facilities. In R. G. Noll & A. Zimbalist (Eds.), Sports, jobs, and taxes: The economic impact of sports teams and stadiums (pp. 92-118). Washington, D.C.: Brookings Institution Press.

Baim, D. V. (1994). The sports stadium as a municipal investment. Westport and London: Greenwood Press.

Baltagi, B. H. (2001). Econometric analysis of panel data (2nd ed.). New York: Wiley & Sons.

Bertrand, M., Duflo, E., & Mullainathan, S. (2004). How much should we trust differences-indifferences estimates? Quarterly Journal of Economics, 119(1), 249-275.

Brenke, K., & Wagner, G. G. (2007). Zum volkswirtschaftlichen Wert der Fussball-Weltmeisterschaft 2006 in Deutschland. DIW Berlin Research Notes 19.

Buttner, N., Maennig, W., & Menssen, M. (2007). Relationships between investment costs for infrastructure and sport stadia: The case of the World Cup 2006 in Germany. Verkehrswissenschaft, 78(3), 145-175.

Carlino, G., & Coulson, N. E. (2004). Compensating differentials and the social benefits of the NFL. Journal of Urban Economics, 56(1), 25-50.

Coates, D., & Humphreys, B. R. (1999). The growth effects of sport franchises, stadia, and arenas.

Journal of Policy Analysis and Management, 18(4), 601-624.

Coates, D., & Humphreys, B. R. (2001). The economic consequences of professional sports strikes and lockouts. Southern Economic Journal, 67(3), 737-747.

Coates, D., & Humphreys, B. R. (2003). Professional sports facilities, franchises and urban economic development. Public Finance and Management, 3(3), 335-357.

Coates, D., & Humphreys, B. R. (2008). Do economists reach a conclusion on subsidies for sports franchises, stadiums, and mega-events? Econ Journal Watch, 5(3), 294-315.

Deutsche Industrie- und Handelskammer. (2006). Fussball-WM 2006, Auswirkungen auf die Unternehmen. Retrieved from http://www.dihk.de/index.html?/inhalt/themen/branchen/ tourismus/fussball/wirtschaft.html

Deutsche Postbank AG. (2005a). FIFA Fussball-Weltmeisterschaft 2006--Deutsche Wirtschaft steht als gewinner bereits fest. Retrieved from http://www.postbank.de/Datei/R SpezialFebruar05.pdf

Deutsche Postbank AG. (2005b). FIFA Fussball-Weltmeisterschaft 2006--Signifikante Arbeitsplatz- und Beschaftigungszuwachse in einzelnen Branchen. Retrieved from http://www.post bank.de/Datei/RSpezialJuli05.pdf

Deutsche Postbank AG. (2006). FIFA Fussball-Weltmeisterschaft 2006--Kleine und "Armere" Austragungsorte profitieren am meisten. Retrieved from http://postbank.de/Datei/ RSpezialJanuar06.pdf

Feddersen, A., & Maennig, W. (2009). Wage and employment effects of the Olympic Games in Atlanta 1996 reconsidered. Hamburg Contemporary Economic Discussions, No. 25.

FIFA. (2006). World Cup 2006 in Germany, stadia [Electronic Version]. Retrieved from http://fifaworldcup.yahoo.com/06/de/d/stadium/index.html

Hagn, F., & Maennig, W. (2007). Labour market effects of the 2006 Soccer World Cup in Germany. Applied Economics, iFirst. Retrieved from http://dx.doi.org/10.1080/ 00036840701604545

Hagn, F., & Maennig, W. (2008). Employment effects of the football World Cup 1974 in Germany. Labour Economics, 15(5), 1062-1075.

Heyne, M., Maennig, W., & Sussmuth, B. (2007). Mega-sporting events as experience goods.

Hamburg Contemporary Economic Discussions, No. 05.

Hotchkiss, J. L., Moore, R. E., & Zobay, S. M. (2003). Impact of the 1996 Summer Olympic Games on employment and wages in Georgia. Southern Economic Journal, 69(3), 691-704.

Jasmand, S., & Maennig, W. (2008). Regional income and employment effects of the 1972 Munich Summer Olympic Games. Regional Studies, 42(7), 991-1002.

Kasimati, E., & Dawson, P. (2009). Assessing the impact of the 2004 Olympic Games on the Greek economy: A small macroeconometric model. Economic Modelling, 26(1), 139-146.

Kavetsos, G., & Szymanski, S. (2008). National wellbeing and international sports events. IASE Working Paper, No. 0804.

Kim, H. J., Gursoy, D., & Lee, S.-B. (2006). The impact of the 2002 World Cup on South Korea: Comparisons of pre- and post-games. Tourism Management, 27(1), 86-96.

Kim, S. S., & Petrick, J. F. (2005). Residents' perceptions on impacts of the FIFA 2002 World Cup: The case of Seoul as a host city. Tourism Management, 26(1), 25-38.

Maennig, W. (2007). One year later: A re-appraisal of the economics of the 2006 soccer World Cup. Hamburg Contemporary Economic Discussions, No. 10.

Melaniphy, J. C. (1996). The impact of stadiums and arenas. Real Estate Issues, 21(3), 36-39.

Nelson, A. C. (2001). Prosperity or bligth? A question of major league stadia locations. Economic Developmet Quarterly, 15(3), 255-265.

Preuss, H. (2006). The economics of staging the Olympics: A comparison of the Games 1972-2008. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.

Preuss, H., Schutte, N., & Kurscheidt, M. (2007). Measuring the primary economic impact of visitors to mega-sport events--A case study at the FIFA World Cup 2006. Paper presented at the AK Sportokonomie, Magglingen / CH, May 11, 2007.

Santee, E. E. (1996). Major league cities. Real Estate Issues, 21(3), 31-35.

Skrentny, W. (2001). Das Grosse Buch der Deutschen Fussball-Stadien [the Allmanach of the German Soccer Stadia] (2 ed.). Gottingen: Verlag Die Werkstatt.

Stadionwelt. (2007). Stadium. Neu- Und Umbau [Stadia. New and Reconstruction] [Electronic Version]. Retrieved from http://www.stadionwelt.de/neu/sw_stadien/index.php? folder=sites&site=neubau_d

Sterken, E. (2006). Growth impact of major sporting events. European Sport Management Quarterly, 6(4), 375-389.

Szymanski, S. (2002). The economic impact of the World Cup. World Economics, 3(1), 169-177.

Teigland, J. (1999). Mega-events and impacts on tourism; The predictions and realities of the Lillehammer Olympics. Impact Assessment and Project Appraisal, 17(4), 305-317.

Tu, C. C. (2005). How does a new sports stadium affect housing values? The case of Fedex Field. Land Economics, 81(3), 379-395.

Endnotes

(1) See Baade (1987, 1994, 1996); Baade & Dye (1990); Baade & Sanderson (1997); Coates & Humphreys (1999, 2000, 2001, 2003).

(2) Every World Cup stadium was at least renovated. The average expenditure per city was 116.7 million [euro], with a minimum investment of 736.0 million (Dortmund) and a maximum investment of 280.0 million [euro] (Munich). The volume of transport infrastructure investment was even larger (Buttner, Maennig, & Menssen, 2007).

(3) Allmers and Maennig (in press) also analyze the effects of 1998 Football World Cup in France on overnight stays, national income from tourism, and retail sales and find significant effects at all.

(4) No significant effects at all are registered for the Olympic Games.

(5) In addition to econometric analysis with "realized data," there are studies for perceived benefits, see Kim and Petrick (2005) and Kim, Gursoy, and Lee (2006) for the 2002 World Cup.

(6) See Table A1 in the appendix for a complete list of the large urban districts.

(7) Start and end of the observation periods are determined by data availability from EUROSTAT and VGRDL.

(8) See e.g., Hotchkiss, Moore, and Zobay (2003) for the use of a general post period dummy.

(9) The F-tests of the significance of the fixed effects reject the null hypothesis that all equals zero.

Thus, we consider a fixed effects model as appropriate.

(10) As the employment and income data are on a yearly basis and as the construction work does not always starts at the beginning of year, no effect could be found for a year in which a construction project starts at the year's end. To deal with this problem, stadia constructions will be considered only for a specific year if the start of work lies in first three quarters of this year. If the construction work started in the last quarter of a year, the following year will be treated as starting point.

(11) The periods of construction can be found in columns 6 and 7 of Table 1. As construction work is not always started at the beginning of a year, the dummy takes the value of one if the works starts before October or does not end before April of the respective year.

(12) The LM test statistic is [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII], which is asymptomatically distributed N (0,1).

(13) The "intervention" coefficients of these regressions are often significant. But, in line with Bertrand, Duflo, and Mullainathan (2004), the estimates might be inefficient.

(14) Substituting the time trend by time invariant fixed effects does yield comparable results. The variables of interest ([PT.sub.it], [PTT.sub.it]) change only marginal and are still insignificant.

(15) As done in the previous section, two different variants have been analyzed: (1) no covariates are considered; (2) only a construction dummy is considered.

(16) As the numbers of cities is not small, the t-statistics don't have to be adjusted.

(17) "Foreigners" are defined as consumers coming from outside of the city for a visit in the city.

In the framework of economic impact studies, the requirements to be named a foreigner are even stronger. If they switched only the time of their visit to a date when a match will be played, no additional money and thus no economic impact will be generated ("time switchers"). For this and further methodological problems concerning "foreigners" see e.g., Preuss (2006).

(18) For the measurement of the benefit of the 2012 Olympic Games in London see Atkinson et al. (2008). Heyne, Maennig, and Sussmuth (2007) show a study of intangible effects of the 2006 FIFA World Cup. For a first attempt to measure the impact of sports events as well as success of a national team on happiness, see Kavetsos and Szymanski (2008).

Arne Feddersen [1], Andre Leao Grotzinger [1], and Wolfgang Maennig [1]

[1] University of Hamburg

Arne Feddersen is a research fellow in the Department of Economics. His research interests include sports economics, applied regional economics, and media economics.

Andre Leao Grotzinger is an associate director in private banking. His research interests include sports economics and regional economics.

Wolfgang Maennig is a professor and the chair for Economic Policy in the Department of Economics. His research interests include sports economics, transportation economics, and real estate economics.
Table 1: Relevant Stadia Construction Projects in Germany,
1996 to 2005

City           Stadium               Capacity      Team(s)

Berlin#        Olympiastadion#       74,000#       Hertha BSC
                                                   Berlin#

Bremen         Weserstadion          42,100        Werder Bremen

Cologne#       RheinEnergy-          50,374#       1. FC Koln#
               Stadion#

Cottbus        Stadion der           22,746        FC Energie
               Freundschaft                        Cottbus

Dortmund#      Signal Iduna Park#    83,000#       Borussia
                                                   Dortmund#

Dusseldorf     LTU arena             52,000        Fortuna
                                                   Dusseldorf

Duisburg       MSV-Arena             31,514        MSV Duisburg

Frankfurt#     Commerzbank-          51,500#       Eintracht
               Arena#                              Frankfurt#

Gelsen-        Veltins-Arena#        61,524#       FC Schalke 04#
kirchen#

Hamburg#       HSH-Nordbank-         57,000#       Hamburger SV#
               Arena#

Hannover#      AWD-Arena#            49,000#       Hannover 96#

Kaisers-       Fritz-Walter-         48,500        1, FC#
lautern#       Stadion#                            Kaiserslautern#

Leipzig#       Zentralstadion#       44,193#       Sachsen Leipzig#

Magdeburg      Stadion Magdeburg     27,000        1, FC Magdeburg

Monchen-       Borussia-Park         54,057        Borussia
gladbach                                           M'gladbach

Munich#        Allianz Arena#        69,901#       FC Bayern
                                                   Munchen#

Nuremberg#     easyCredit-Stadion#   46,780#       1, FC Nurnberg#

Rostock        DKB-Arena             30,000        FC Hansa Rostock

Stuttgart#     Gottlieb-Daimler-     55,896#       VfB Stuttgart#
               Stadion#

Wolfsburg      Volkswagen Arena      29,161        VfL Wolfsburg

City           Costs                 Construction

                                     Start         End

Berlin#        242.0#                Aug 2000#     Aug 2004#

Bremen         18.0                  May 2003      Jul 2004

Cologne#       117.5#                Jan 2002#     Jul 2004#

Cottbus        12.0                  Apr 2002      Jul 2003

Dortmund#      36.0#                 May 2002#     Jul 2003#

Dusseldorf     218.0                 Sep 2002      Jan 2005

Duisburg       43.0                  Oct 2003      Jan 2005

Frankfurt#     126.0#                Jul 2002#     May 2005#

Gelsen-        192.0#                Nov 1998#     Jul 2001#
kirchen#

Hamburg#       97.0#                 Jun 1998#     Aug 2000#

Hannover#      63.0#                 Feb 2003#     Jan 2005#

Kaisers-       48.3#                 Aug 2004#     Apr 2006#
lautern#

Leipzig#       90.6#                 Dec 2000#     March 2004#

Magdeburg      30.9                  March 2005    Dec 2006

Monchen-       87.0                  Jan 2002      Jul 2004
gladbach

Munich#        280.0#                Feb 2002#     May 2005#

Nuremberg#     56.0#                 Nov 2003#     Jul 2005#

Rostock        55.0                  May 2000      Aug 2001

Stuttgart#     51.6#                 Jan 2004#     Jan 2006#

Wolfsburg      51.0                  May 2001      Nov 2002

Source: Skrentny (2001); FIFA (2006); Stadionwelt (2007);
FIFA World Cup 2006 stadia are marked in bold letters.

Note: FIFA World Cup 2006 stadia are marked indicated
with #.

Table 2: Descriptive Statistics (nominal values)

                                Income
                  All           Control        Treatment
                                 Group           Group

N                 118             106             12
Mean            15,868          15,786          16,266
Median          15,773          15,769          15,881
Std. Dev.        2,192           2,086           2,619
Min             10,833          10,833          11,287
Max             23,615          23,615          22,908

                              Employment
                  All           Control        Treatment
                                 Group           Group

N                 118             106             12
Mean            128,122         76,558          380,784
Median          67,543          56,938          281,361
Std. Dev.       186,240         55,618          336,195
Min             15,477          15,477          57,189
Max            1,436,573        290,340        1,436,573

Table 3: Descriptive Statistics (logarithms)

                                Income
                  All           Control        Treatment
                                 Group           Group

N                 118             106             12
Mean            9.6626          9.6582          9.6840
Median          9.6661          9.6658          9.6728
Std. Dev.       0.1378          0.1324          0.1600
Min             9.2904          9.2904          9.3314
Max            10.0696         10.0696         10.0392

                              Employment
                  All           Control        Treatment
                                 Group           Group

N                 118             106             12
Mean            11.2501         11.0018         12.4668
Median          11.1205         10.9497         12.5458
Std. Dev.       0.9210          0.7003          0.9063
Min             9.6471          9.6471          10.9541
Max             14.1778         12.5788         14.1778

Table 4: Test for Significance of the Fixed Effects

Endogenous               Model (1)
variable      Treatment WC      Treatment ALL

Income         319.16 ***        321.34 ***

Employment    4,690.77 ***      4,567.26 ***

Endogenous               Model (2)
variable      Treatment WC      Treatment ALL

Income         318.57 ***        322.20 ***

Employment    4,584.37 ***      4,499.86 ***

Notes: *** p <0.01, ** p <0.05, * p <0.10.

Table 5: Test for Serial Correlation

Endogenous                Model (1)
variable       Treatment WC      Treatment ALL

Income          23.411 ***        23.413 ***
Employment      33.964 ***        23.186 ***

Endogenous                Model (2)
variable       Treatment WC      Treatment ALL

Income          23.249 ***        23.251 ***
Employment      23.367 ***        23.371 ***

Notes: *** p <0.01, ** p <0.05, * p <0.10.

Table 6: DD Model with Fixed Effects for Income of Private Households

                               Model (1)

                      Treatment          Treatment
                        WC_12              ALL_20

Constant              9.551 ***          9.550 ***
                     (3,539.662)        (3,663.220)

PT                [-6.109e.sup.-4]         -0.008
                      (-0.432)            (-0.820)

C                        --                  --

trend                 0.019 ***          0.019 ***
                      (38.905)            (37.428)

TT                     -0.005         [6.297e.sup.-4]
                      (-0.465)            (0.733)

PTT                [8.260e.sup.-4]    [-7.980e.sup.-5]
                       (0.201)            (-0.018)

PTTC                     --                  --

[R.sup.2]               0.881              0.881
adj. [R.sup.2]          0.881              0.881
F-Stat               441.250 ***        550.130 ***
N                        118                118
T                        11                  11
N*T                     1298                1298

                                Model (2)

                      Treatment          Treatment
                        WC_12              ALL_20

Constant              9.551 ***          9.551 ***
                     (3,502.198)        (3,594.649)

PT                     -0.017             -0.020 *
                      (-1.257)            (-1.787)

C                      -0.005             -0.008 *
                      (-0.694)            (-1.742)

trend                 0.019 ***          0.019 ***
                      (38.897)            (37.413)

TT                 [8.063e.sup.-4]    [2.243e.sup.-4]
                      (-0.528)            (0.213)

PTT                      --                  --

PTTC                    0.010              0.009
                       (1.365)            (1.228)

[R.sup.2]               0.882              0.882
adj. [R.sup.2]          0.881              0.881
F-Stat                 352.928          374.450 ***
N                        118                118
T                        11                  11
N*T                     1298                1298

Notes: *** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.10. t-statistics are in
parentheses. Standard errors are computed using an arbitrary
variance-covariance matrix as suggested by Bertrand, Duflo,
& Mullainathan (2004, pp. 270-272).

Table 7: DD Model with Fixed Effects for Employment

                              Model (1)

                     Treatment          Treatment
                       WC_12              ALL_20

Constant             11.244 ***         11.245 ***
                    (1,804.627)        (1,954.357)

PT                     0.006              0.015
                      (0.723)            (1.106)

C                        --                 --

trend             [2.189e.sup.-4]    [3.647e.sup.-4]
                      (0.222)            (0.375)

TT                     0.006              0.005
                      (1.494)            (1.224)

PTT                    -0.008             -0.006
                      (-1.523)           (-1.146)

PTTC                     --                 --

[R.sup.2]              0.979              0.979
Adj.[R.sup.2]          0.979              0.979
F-Stat             10,256.240 ***     10,330.930 ***
N                       118                118
T                        10                 10
N*T                    1,180              1,180

                              Model (2)

                     Treatment          Treatment
                       WC_12              ALL_20

Constant             11.245 ***         11.244 ***
                    (1,950.524)        (1,868.912)

PT                     0.015              0.002
                      (0.623)            (0.100)

C                      -0.009             -0.010
                      (-1.159)           (-1.371)

trend             [9.702e.sup.-4]    [2.189e.sup.-4]
                      (0.003)            (0.222)

TT                     0.004              0.005
                      (1.089)            (1.413)

PTT                      --                 --

PTTC                   -0.001             -0.007
                      (-0.071)           (-0.525)

[R.sup.2]              0.979              0.979
Adj.[R.sup.2]          0.978              0.978
F-Stat             9,620.552 ***      9,596.174 ***
N                       118                118
T                        10                 10
N*T                    1,180              1,180

Notes: *** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.10. t-statistics are in
parentheses. Standard errors are computed using an arbitrary
variance-covariance matrix as suggested by Bertrand, Duflo,
& Mullainathan (2004, pp. 270-272).

Table 8: ITSI DD Model for Income of Private Households

                           Model (1)

                  Treatment WC    Treatment ALL

Constant              0.046           0.020
                     (1.081)         (0.596)

POST                 -0.006           -0.001
                    (-0.102)         (-0.030)

[R.sup.2]             0.045           0.019
adj. [R.sup.2]        0.001           0.007

                           Model (2)

                  Treatment WC    Treatment ALL

Constant              0.047           0.022
                     (1.111)         (0.635)

POST                 -0.005           -0.001
                    (-0.084)         (-0.020)

[R.sup.2]             0.030           0.024
adj. [R.sup.2]        0.014           0.002

Notes: *** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.10. t-statistics
are in parentheses. Coefficients are from a two-step
process using OLS.

Table 9: ITSI DD Model for Employment

                            Model (1)

                  Treatment WC    Treatment ALL

Constant            1.573 ***       1.192 ***
                     (6.016)         (5.734)

POST                 -0.008           -0.004
                    (-0.022)         (-0.013)

[R.sup.2]             0.095           0.057
adj. [R.sup.2]        0.054           0.032

                            Model (2)

                  Treatment WC    Treatment ALL

Constant            1.577 ***       1.196 ***
                     (6.050)         (5.760)

POST                 -0.014           -0.003
                    (-0.039)         (-0.010)

[R.sup.2]             0.035           0.016
adj. [R.sup.2]        0.009           0.010

Notes: *** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, *p<0.10. t-statistics
are in parentheses. Coefficients are from a two-step
process using OLS.
联系我们|关于我们|网站声明
国家哲学社会科学文献中心版权所有