Presidents and the political economy: the coalitional foundations of presidential power.
Hacker, Jacob S. ; Pierson, Paul
Presidents shape the economy; the economy shapes presidencies. If
anyone doubted this, the first three years of the Obama presidency
offered a stark reminder. Swept into office on a tide of discontent
prompted by the worst financial crisis since the Great Depression,
President Obama promised to create a "new foundation" for
economic growth and shared prosperity (Jacobs and Skocpol 2011). After
three decades in which the richest of Americans had gained dramatically,
yet middle-class Americans had seen their wages and economic security
stagnate, Obama offered an ambitious domestic agenda: health care
reform, financial reform, energy reform, political reform. But while he
achieved notable victories, his first three years ended with the nation
beset by devastating unemployment, economic inequality widening, his
congressional majorities gone, and conservative activists and
resourceful interest groups waging a highly successful battle against
his now-crippled agenda.
President Obama's rocky experience indicates both how central
and how perilous long-term economic reform is to presidential
leadership. The president is widely recognized as a manager of
prosperity, the elected official with the greatest incentive and
capacity to focus on the economy as a whole (Weatherford 2009). And yet,
the prospects for presidential leadership in the economic realm depend
heavily on the president's relationship to broader partisan and
interest-group forces over which presidents have only partial control.
In contrast to other areas of presidential responsibility, the scope for
unilateral executive action in domestic economic policy is inherently
limited. Moreover, the ability of presidents to change the deeper
contours of the economy hinges on sustained, coordinated action over
substantial periods of time. As President Obama learned to his regret,
the conditions for such ongoing influence are difficult to cultivate.
This tension--between presidential ambitions and presidential
authority--is at the core of the presidents' role in the ongoing
organized struggle to create durable changes in the American political
economy. And yet it is curiously lacking in most social science analyses
of presidents and the economy. Instead, this scholarship has focused
much of its attention, and increasingly high-powered technical
ammunition, on a far narrower topic: presidents' ability to shape
the economy in ways that influence the prospects for their own
reelection (e.g., Abrams and Iossifov 2006; Alesina and Rosenthal 1995;
Erikson 1989; Hibbs 1987; Nordhaus 1975). This, in turn, usually boils
down to studying presidents' effects on selected economic
indicators shortly before the presidential election, the period in which
the effects of the economy on voters' choices appear strongest. As
James Campbell (2011, 3) puts it, in a recent addition to this
literature to which we shall return, these studies do not tackle
"the monumental challenge of measuring the economic impact of
presidential policies beyond the immediate terms of a presidency."
Rather, "they are content, as most voters seem to be, to assess the
more limited and proximate records of the presidents around their time
in office."
This narrow focus reflects an understandable wariness about the
ability of social scientists to link enduring economic shifts to
specific presidents. More fundamentally, as Campbell's quote
suggests, it flows naturally from a long tradition of emphasizing
voters' capacity to reward or punish presidents for the
economy's performance. Yet this constricted focus has several
debilitating consequences. First, it draws attention away from more
fundamental questions of political economy, which revolve around how
governing coalitions shape economic structures and rewards over the
long-term. Second, the central theoretical orientation of existing
research toward unilateral presidential action and elections provides a
very shaky starting point for advancing such a broader discussion.
Finally, this perspective results in a conception of presidential power
that is at once too capacious and too cramped--capacious, in that it
overstates the scope for unilateral presidential action, and cramped in
that it misses the durable impacts that presidents can have when
operating as part of governing coalitions seeking to institutionalize a
policy agenda. A convincing account of the American political economy
will have to be built on a very different foundation.
To introduce this argument we examine a particularly prominent
recent attempt to link presidential leadership to changes in the
American economy--that of Larry Bartels (2008) in his recent book
Unequal Democracy. We use Bartels' analysis as an entryway into our
own perspective not because it is especially vulnerable. Quite the
opposite: It is, justly, both highly regarded and highly influential.
That it nevertheless remains fragile and incomplete speaks volumes about
the limits of the reigning scholarly focus. After outlining the problems
with Bartels' account, we introduce an alternative framework that
situates presidents within "durable policy coalitions"
dedicated to the advancement of favorable policy regimes. Finally, we
discuss the evolution of tax policy to illustrate the operation of a
durable coalition that includes presidents but extends well beyond them.
Presidents, Partisanship, and Rising Inequality
Since the late 1970s, income and wealth gaps have grown
dramatically in the United States--far more than in other advanced
industrial nations and to far higher levels. (1) The share of pretax national income accruing to the richest 1% of Americans increased from
less than 9% in the mid-1970s to 23.5% on the eve of the financial
crisis in 2007. The share accruing to the richest 0.1% rose even more
spectacularly. In 2007, the richest one in 1,000 households took home
one in eight dollars of American income, the highest proportion since
the creation of the income tax in 1913. These developments pose a stark
explanatory challenge for political scientists, given their apparent
inconsistency with standard, median-voter-focused models of political
economy, which predict that middle-income voters will seek
redistribution through government when market inequality rises
(particularly if its rise disadvantages all but the richest [Meltzer and
Richard 1981]). And yet only in the last half-decade have political
scientists devoted any real attention to the link between this
remarkable transformation of the American economy and patterns of
American governance, much less to the role of presidents in mediating
this link.
One of the most prominent and sophisticated of these pioneering
contributions is Larry Bartels' (2008) Unequal Democracy. Bartels
argues that, since World War II, Republican and Democratic presidents
have had starkly different effects on the income
distribution--Republican presidents have increased inequality;
Democratic presidents have reduced it. This is not an entirely new
claim: Douglas Hibbs (1977) long ago argued that, for distributional
reasons, Democratic presidents focused more on boosting employment while
GOP presidents focused on fighting inflation. Yet far more than Hibbs,
Bartels links his findings directly to the massive secular trend toward
increased inequality and the attendant reshaping of the American
political economy. For this reason, Barrels provides an excellent
starting point--but not, we shall see, ending point for considering
presidents' role in shaping how the economy distributes its
benefits.
The President's Role in Unequal Democracy
Unequal Democracy is by no means a book just about presidents and
inequality. It ranges widely, from public opinion to elections to the
politics of the minimum wage. (2) Still, Barrels' (2008) most
provocative argument concerns the very different effects of Republican
and Democratic presidents on the economy since World War II. (3) As
Hibbs did, Barrels contends that employment and growth are substantially
lower under Republican presidents, and that this weak performance
especially hurts less affluent citizens. Over time, the consequence is
rising inequality. Indeed, Bartels suggests that the behavior of
Republican presidents largely accounts for the very dramatic rise in
inequality over recent decades. According to Bartels (2008, 61), if his
results are projected over the postwar period, "continuous
democratic control would have produced an essentially constant level of
economic inequality."
Furthermore, in a crucial nod to the literature on political
business cycles, Bartels argues that Republicans manage to create higher
growth in election years, while Democrats actually tend to produce lower
growth in this crucial period. Because voters are myopic, Bartels
argues, this last-minute economic burst allows Republicans to produce
subpar outcomes for most voters yet still do well at the polls.
Is this a persuasive account of president's role in rising
inequality? In the rest of this part, we argue that for all the virtues
of Barrels' analysis, it falls short in three revealing respects.
First, it largely misses the true contours of rising inequality, and
thus misses key policy mechanisms and partisan dynamics that help us
understand what has happened to the American political economy and why.
Second, Bartels' basic account of fiscal and monetary policies
during the era of sharply rising inequality grants presidents much
greater and more immediate influence over government policy and the
economy than the historical record warrants. Finally, even if one could
sustain his account, many of the short-term economic policies that he
emphasizes cannot easily be extended to explain long-term economic
shifts of the type that the United States has witnessed; other policy
mechanisms about which Barrels says little or nothing need to be brought
into the analysis.
To avoid misunderstanding, we want to make clear that we agree with
Barrels that presidents play an important role in shaping the
macroeconomy. We also think it undeniable that the parties--and their
presidential standard-bearers--have differing distributional priorities.
Yet neither the huge presidential effects that Bartels identifies nor
the main mechanisms he sees as driving those outcomes convincingly
explain the distinctive way in which the distribution of American
economic rewards has changed since the 1970s. This is not just a problem
with Bartels' account. More broadly, it suggests that the reigning
focus on how presidents bolster short-term growth (and their reelection
prospects) is a mistake. A more convincing analysis will need to move
away from the emphasis on unilateral presidential action and short-term
economic policies to examine durable policy shifts grounded in long-term
coalitional conflict.
The Mystery of Winner-Take-All Inequality
To explain the dramatic increase in income inequality in the United
States over the last generation, we need at a minimum to describe it
properly. Much of the writing on rising inequality implies that the
rungs on the economic ladder are moving farther apart all along its
span. Yet this is not what has happened. Instead, as noted, the very top
of the ladder has pulled sharply away from all the rungs below it.
Though inequality has risen across the board, the main story is the
sharp concentration of gains at the very top.
The subtitle of Unequal Democracy properly describes America's
recent economic history as a "New Gilded Age." Yet
Bartels' analyses of partisan presidential effects largely ignore
the spectacular rise of high-end incomes. In fact, his main measure of
inequality is the 80/20 ratio, the ratio of income at the 80th and 20th
percentiles. Yet the 80/20 ratio leaves out most of the post-1970s spike
in inequality. The Congressional Budget Office (CBO; 2010) has assembled
the best data on household disposable income for the 1979 to 2007 period
(after federal taxes and including public transfers and private
employment-based benefits). Its numbers show that the 80/20 ratio rose
from just over 3 in 1979 to 3.64 in 2007--a roughly 20% increase. Over
the same period, however, the ratio of the 99th percentile to the 20th
percentile rose from 9.62 to 17.21--an almost 80% increase. Of course,
the 99/20 ratio is greater than the 80/20 ratio; the point is that it
has risen much more sharply, indicating that income gains since 1979
have been highly concentrated at the top. Indeed, according to a recent
CBO report (CBO 2011), fully half of the post-1979 rise in the Gini
index (a common inequality metric) is due to the pulling away of the
richest 1%. (4) And, in fact, a very large share of America's
growing income concentration has occurred above the 99th percentile. The
last generation has truly been a "New Gilded Age."
Once we shift our gaze to the biggest fact about American
inequality--the steady upward rise of the share of income going to the
very richest--a simple partisan story becomes harder to sustain.
Instead, as Figure 1 suggests, something happened around 1980 that
resulted in a fairly consistent upward trend in the fortunes of those at
the very top, regardless of the partisan identity of the president.
(Because the CBO data go back only to 1979, we present pretax data,
including capital gains, from Piketty and Saez [2003].) As we will see,
Bartels' (2008) argument has surprisingly little to say about this
trend--one that, as we have seen, is at the heart of the stunning rise
in American inequality and deeply puzzling according to standard
median-voter accounts.
Revisiting the Story of Partisan Pump-Priming
How do presidents produce the changes in the 80/20 ratio that
Bartels finds--and produce them quickly enough that stark partisan
differences emerge on their watch? Barrels suggests that a key mechanism
is fiscal and monetary interventions designed to boost growth or fight
inflation. Contrasting distributional outcomes, he argues, flow from
"surprisingly consistent partisan differences in the macroeconomic policies and priorities of Democratic and Republican presidents in the
post-war era" (Bartels 2008, 47).
[FIGURE 1 OMITTED]
This focus makes intuitive sense, since Bartels' main findings
concern quite rapid changes in market income before taxes and transfers.
(Unequal Democracy does present a more limited data series on posttax
and posttransfer income changes from 1980 to 2003, which we shall
discuss shortly.) Bartels argues that presidents primarily influence the
distribution of market income by affecting rates of growth and
unemployment, which in turn influences patterns of income change. In a
nutshell, Democrats adopt expansionary macroeconomic policies and
Republicans contractionary ones (at least before they prime the pump in
the run-up to the election), with the consequence that income growth for
less affluent citizens is higher under Democrats than under Republicans.
Indeed, once levels of growth and unemployment are controlled for, the
partisan differences in income growth at different points in the income
distribution disappear.
Bartels presents some historical evidence for this pattern. He
notes, as Hibbs (1987) did before him, that both Dwight D. Eisenhower
and Richard Nixon were more concerned about inflation than John F.
Kennedy, Lyndon Johnson, and Harry Truman. Yet his historical review of
broad macroeconomic policies more or less stops with Ronald
Reagan's first term. This is revealing, for presidents since Reagan
have simply not followed Hibbs's partisan script. Jimmy Carter
first reduced, then increased the deficit, leaving it at almost exactly
the initial level. Bill Clinton launched a massively contractionary
fiscal policy at the outset of his presidency, shifting the federal
budget from hundreds of billions in the red to hundreds of billions in
the black. (Barack Obama, a Democrat who pursued an expansionary fiscal
policy, postdates Bartels' analysis.)
By contrast, each of the post-1980 Republican presidents--Reagan,
George H. W. Bush, and George W. Bush--oversaw substantial increases in
the deficit. For Reagan and George W. Bush, the increases were large,
rapid, and early in the president's term. Of course, the Reagan and
George W. Bush deficits were driven by large tax cuts--an important fact
that we return to in the final part of this article. But they surely
represented expansionary policies
If the partisan fiscal story does not work after the late 1970s,
neither does the partisan monetary story. Indeed, the strongest
conclusion to come out of research on the Federal Reserve (or Fed) is
the persistent shift toward an anti-inflation stance that began with
Paul Volcker in the late 1970s. In the wake of the high inflation of the
decade, the Fed achieved even greater political independence--in turn,
reinforced by presidential and congressional concerns that acting too
aggressively toward the Fed would spook financial markets. With a
decision-making committee stacked with representatives of the financial
sector (federal reserve banks appoint five of the 12 members of the
committee), increased independence has allowed the chair of the Fed to
pursue a more consistently hard-money stance focused on price stability.
This increased independence is strongly suggested by the apparent
incapacity of presidents to aggressively use their appointment powers to
shift the Fed's direction. Clinton, after all, quickly reappointed
Reagan appointee Alan Greenspan as head of the Fed, despite
Greenspan's strong conservative leanings. Reagan reappointed
Volker, a Democratic appointment. More recently, Obama reappointed Ben
Bernanke, an appointee of George W. Bush. This is not to suggest the Fed
has played no role in rising inequality. Later, we will present a
distinct argument about the Fed, linked to the secular shift in its
stance after Volcker. But it is extremely hard to find Fed-driven
partisan differences in monetary policy after 1980 (see, e.g., Abrams
and Iossifov 2006; Mayer 1990).
In short, the partisan account for pretax income changes that
Barrels offers falls short precisely during the era in which inequality
exploded. Since the late 1970s, presidents have not used fiscal and
monetary policies to put their foot on the gas or the brake to quickly
influence employment and growth. Bartels clearly recognizes this: He
argues (Bartels 2008, 58) that it has "become much more difficult
in the past quarter century for presidents to influence the distribution
of pretax income," due to the globalization of the economy and the
increased independence of the Fed. And he argues that, as a result,
presidents are more reliant on tax and transfer changes. Yet, in a
careful reanalysis of Barrels' data, Lane Kenworthy (2010) finds
that even after 1980, virtually all of the partisan differences in the
80/20 ratio are due to changes in pretax inequality, particularly in the
bottom half of the distribution. The puzzle remains how presidents have
so quickly produced such large changes in the economic fortunes of less
affluent Americans, even before taxes and transfers take effect.
From Political Business Cycles to Long-Term Economic Change
Thus, Bartels' (2008) argument has problems explaining changes
in inequality since 1980, the period during which Americans'
economic fortunes became most starkly divergent. But even if presidents
had behaved as Bartels' account implies, priming the pump or
fighting inflation according to the Hibbsian partisan script, we would
be skeptical of the emphasis on short-term fiscal and monetary policies
as an instrument of long-term economic transformation. Put simply, these
policies seem poor candidates for explaining durable changes in the
income distribution. After all, expansionary policies rest on the
availability of macroeconomic slack that stimulative policies can
activate. Indeed, Bartels' argument about Republican success in
producing growth just before elections rests on exactly this
bust-then-boom dynamic: prior periods of restraint create output gaps
that well-timed expansionary policies can close. (5)
By contrast, long-term shifts in the income distribution are more
plausibly linked to changes in the structure of the economy, not whether
policy makers are keeping the economy operating at its peak at any time.
Thus Bartels' projection that "continuous democratic control
would have produced an essentially constant level of economic
inequality" rests on more than the "arguably unrealistic
assumption" that "either party would actually have the
political will or the political power to produce economic redistribution
of the cumulative magnitude suggested by these projections"
(61-62). It also rests on the certainly unrealistic assumption that one
could sustain expansionary fiscal policy year in and year out for three
decades.
To be sure, for the post-1980 period, Bartels shifts his emphasis
from general macroeconomic policies to taxes and transfers, which could
produce such durable shifts. We have already noted Kenworthy's
(2010) objection that virtually all the partisan differences in income
growth even after 1980 occur before taxes and transfers. Nonetheless, we
are extremely receptive to Bartels' argument that it is in transfer
programs and, in particular, tax policies where we should see the
biggest contrasts in partisan presidential priorities. To account for
the stark run-up in inequality since the 1970s, however, these contrasts
need to explain the massive hyperconcentration of income at the top, not
just different patterns of income growth below the 80th percentile. As
Figure 1 shows, the pace of this hyperconcentration does not seem to
vary substantially between Republican and Democratic presidents. Indeed,
Kenworthy (2010) finds almost no difference between Republicans and
Democrats when using data that include the top 1%.
This is not to suggest that tax policy changes have not helped the
top 1% since 1980. As the final section of this article shows, they
have--mightily so. These changes, however, have proved much more
enduring across Republican and Democratic presidential administrations
than Bartels' partisan account would predict. Shifting the focus
from general macroeconomic policies to tax and transfer changes makes
sense. But there is also a need to look beyond short-term effects and
consider the durable policy changes that presidents have pursued to
alter the American political economy.
The short-term focus of Bartels' argument is driven home by a
recent critique by Campbell (2011), who shows that Bartels' finding
of partisan effects depends highly on the time lags in his model.
Specifically, Campbell finds that Bartels' core results depend
heavily on when the president is presumed to start having an effect on
the economy and whether the rate of economic growth in the prior six
months is taken into account. If, for example, economic growth in the
previous six months is included in the model, economic growth at various
income levels is not significantly different between Democratic and
Republican presidents. The same is true, according to Campbell, if
presidents are presumed to start affecting the economy just a quarter of
a year later than Barrels' model assumes.
Campbell uses these findings to argue that Republican and
Democratic presidents have not differed on the crucial dimensions that
Bartels identifies. The conclusion that we draw is quite different: it
is that we should be skeptical of arguments that emphasize
presidents' ability to quickly and durably affect inequality
through short-term macroeconomic policies. Theories that hinge on small
changes in the modeling of prior growth or the lag in presidential
effects are not likely to be very fruitful in explaining the massive,
long-term transformation of the structure of economic rewards since the
1970s.
All this is not to argue that presidents are powerless to shape the
economy. Far from it: the president is surely the elected official with
the greatest incentive and capacity to remake the economy in enduring
ways. Yet we would expect that the kinds of policy changes that have
contributed to the growing skew of economic rewards toward the very top
would generally not be those caused by new presidents seeking a
short-term boost to growth or reduction in inflation. Rather, they are
likely to take the form of major shifts in large-scale public policies
governing the market--from tax policy to the regulation of finance,
corporate governance, and industrial relations. It is to these policies,
and presidents' role in shaping them, that we now turn.
Policy, Durable Coalitions, and Economic Restructuring
Our perspective on presidential leadership is grounded in a simple
observation: long-term policy developments are rooted in organized
struggles to remake the economy and society in durable ways. Politics is
a contest where some gain the authority to make decisions of fundamental
significance for others. Especially in the modern era of activist
government, those in positions of power can have an enormous influence
on the distribution of valued goods. For many political actors, policy,
not elections, is the ultimate prize. While elections are a critical
instrument for gaining and exercising political authority, they are only
part of a broader political battle that involves competing attempts to
determine what that authority is used to do.
Viewing politics this way leads to a focus on different actors,
interactions, and relationships (Bawn et al. 2011; Hacker and Pierson
2010; Moe 1990, 2005; Skowronek 1993). It highlights the role of
organized groups (or, as Bawn and her colleagues nicely put it,
"intense policy demanders"). It reconceives political parties
as vehicles that may foster long-term coalitions among interest groups
and between those groups and ambitious politicians (Cohen et al. 2008).
It sees many of these actors as focused less on the desire to please
voters and more on trying to consolidate policy victories or undercut
those of their opponents (Patashnik 2008). It views politics as a battle
over the long haul to influence how political authority is used to
change the contours of the economy and society. In this part, we explore
these points in more detail before outlining their consequences for how
we see the role of presidents within the political economy.
In contrast with standard work on American politics, which has
tended to highlight the centrality of politicians and voters, conceiving
politics as a struggle over policy places organized groups closer to the
heart of the analysis. In contrast to voters, who have very limited
information and are typically inattentive to politics, organized groups
are highly informed and extremely vigilant. Not only are these the
actors with the most intense interest in policy outcomes, they are also
the actors with the greatest capacity to monitor and exert influence
over those outcomes in a sustained way and across multiple venues.
This is critical, because the substance of policy is usually a
product of concerted action over time. American politics specialists
typically focus on the production of laws, with "laws"
understood in the highly decontextualized form of specific bills or
votes. Yet public policy in the real world generally results from the
interacting content of multiple laws and other exercises of political
authority. In most cases, policy is (as Kenneth Shepsle [1992] once said
about legislatures) not an "it," but a "they," a set
of authoritative decisions emerging from the intersecting activities of
multiple actors operating in multiple sites, often over extended periods
of time. While this is true of policy making in all political systems,
it is especially true of American policy making given the acute
fragmentation of political institutions in the United States
(Baumgartner and Jones 1993; Melnick 1994; Teles 2008).
Durable Coalitions, Durable Victories
Thinking about long-term policy development also points to the
prospect that particular political actors may win durable victories. A
peculiar characteristic of most American politics scholarship is that
its depictions of politics involve no durable winners and losers.
Elections follow a Downsian logic; this cycle's loser adjusts and
becomes the next cycle's winner. Take out incumbency, David Mayhew
observes, and presidential elections over the past century or so have
been essentially a coin-toss between the two parties (2002).
Legislatures are under the sway of Arrow's (1951) paradox of
voting, so that losers in any legislative struggle are well positioned
to cycle back into the winner's position. The electorate, whose
views are usually regarded as a binding constraint on policymakers,
fluctuate back and forth over a moderate policy space and typically
operate to bring the political system back to the middle (Erikson,
MacKeun, and Stimson 2002). Throughout this vision, temporary, not
durable, advantages are the rule.
The situation looks fundamentally different when one considers
politics as a contest among intense policy demanders who are engaged in
struggles over the exercise of authority for substantive purposes. In a
political world with policy rather than elections at its core, durable
outcomes are not just possible; they are frequently the main objective.
Winners get to impose their policy preferences on losers. Often, this
means imposing arrangements to which losers must adjust even if their
side wins future elections (Moe 1990, 2005). Policies may create facts
on the ground, durably altering resources and incentives. Policies can
strengthen supporters and weaken losers. In extreme cases, policies can
effectively eliminate the losers altogether.
Studies that examine policy making over time rather than the
electoral see-saw have been much more likely to appreciate this crucial
political dynamic. Patashnik (2008) offers the simple example of how
airline deregulation quickly drove its biggest opponents (the high-cost
airlines) out of business, durably shifting the character of both policy
and the industry it regulated. On a grander scale, the collapse of
Reconstruction led to the consolidation of a Jim Crow regime that locked
Southern blacks (and many poor whites) out of politics for nearly a
century.
A final example captures the heart of our argument. Consider the
letter a savvy (and personally popular) President Eisenhower wrote to
his brother, concerning the desire of conservatives to roll back the New
Deal:
Should any political party attempt to abolish social security,
unemployment insurance, and eliminate labor laws and farm programs, you
would not hear of that party again in our political history. There is a
tiny splinter group, of course, that believes you can do these things.
Among them are H.L. Hunt (you possibly know his background), a few other
Texas oil millionaires, and an occasional politician or business man
from other areas. Their number is negligible and they are stupid.
(Eisenhower 1954)
Eisenhower's point was that the New Deal had achieved durable
victories. Despite his own electoral success, he and other Republicans
now operated within a policy space that the consolidation of prior
Democratic victories had durably altered. There was no going back.
Eisenhower's observation remains fundamental to understanding
the behavior of organized political actors as well as the potential
contributions of presidents to the development of the American political
economy. Precisely because policy, rather than electoral triumph, is
often the ultimate prize, durable victories are possible. And because
such victories are possible, actors seek to bring them about. To do so
requires a durable policy coalition--a set of actors who are
sufficiently dedicated to the goal that they will stay in the fight for
the long term and who have the political and organizational resources
that give them a capacity to make a difference (Sundquist 1968). (6)
Durability is a defining feature of these coalitional actors. They
cultivate allegiance over time, while learning about effective political
strategy and the feasibility of alternative policy designs and framings.
They remain organizationally ready to seize moments of political
opportunity that are, within American politics, rare and fleeting. And
their durability gives them unusual capacity to sustain or extend their
victories once won.
Central to the study of political economy is the study of durable
policy coalitions. This insight--so deeply held that analysts once felt
little need to make it explicit--is at the heart of long traditions of
work in both comparative politics and American political development.
Shifting coalitions of interests battle to exercise authority in order
to impose their preferences through governance. The potential for policy
trajectories to be highly path dependent (Pierson 2000) makes these
efforts profoundly important. It is why comparativists can identify
highly distinct "regimes" covering huge areas of public life
like the welfare state (Esping-Andersen 1990; Huber and Stephens 2001)
and a nation's model of capitalism (Hall and Soskice 2001). These
regimes are grounded in durable policy arrangements, resulting from
fierce contestation among organized interests. They are sustained by
supportive coalitions that typically transcend any specific electoral
majority.
One of the powerful insights of this work is that durable policy
coalitions do indeed have the capacity to carve a huge and lasting
imprint on national economies. Even in an era of globalization, national
economic regimes, all operating in broadly similar contexts of
affluence, open trade and democratic politics, vary tremendously on a
wide range of critical features. Among these are unionization rates,
systems of corporate governance and financial regulation, the scale and
design of social welfare policies, the extent and terms on which women
are incorporated in the paid labor market, and the scope and
distribution of taxation. These enduring differences are grounded not in
some timeless national comparative advantage but in the consequences of
more than a century of ongoing contestation among organized interests
and their partisan allies.
The question then is not whether policy makers can substantially
shape long-term economic outcomes. They can. The question is how they do
so. Specifically, what role do presidents play within these broader
struggles?
Presidential Power and Durable Coalitions
Political scientists have shown growing interest in the capacity of
presidents to engage in unilateral action (Moe and Howell 1999; Howell
2003). In a context of executive-inspired military adventures, this
interest is understandable, and these inquiries have suggested
interesting extensions to realms of domestic policy as well. Yet a quick
examination shows that in the economic sphere, the president's
capacity for unilateral action is generally limited. Almost always, when
he acts effectively to influence long-term economic development, the
president does so as part of a durable coalition that both advances his
policy agenda and helps to sustain or extend it over time.
A primary reason for this is the interbranch character of the
president's domestic policy powers--the fact just noted that
sustained policy change generally requires action across multiple venues
of American government. Another, however, is that presidents simply do
not have a huge amount of time to achieve their goals. Since the 22nd
Amendment, the outer limit has been two terms. Despite their prominence
on the political stage, presidents as solo performers only get two acts.
Their chances for durable accomplishments thus depend crucially on how
the stage has been set, and on who remains on the scene after they have
left the stage.
We clarify this claim by briefly examining four crucial powers of
the presidency: appointment powers, the veto, the capacity to influence
the policy agenda, and the president's central role as a party
leader and coalition builder. Though our list of presidential powers is
conventional, we emphasize the coalitional foundations of most
presidential authority over the economy. Presidents are far weaker in
the absence of strong support within Congress and the community of
organized interests.
Appointments. Subject to congressional approval, presidents appoint
all the nation's key economic officials: the Treasury secretary,
the head of the Securities and Exchange Commission and other regulatory
agencies, and, most important, the chair of the Federal Reserve. In most
respects, these appointees and their activities can be expected to
largely follow a policy course the president favors (subject to
congressional oversight). The biggest exception, however, is a critical
one: the chair of the Federal Reserve.
We have already discussed several revealing features of the recent
history of the Fed. First, over the last three decades, presidents have
routinely reappointed current occupants of this extremely powerful
position, even though those occupants were originally chosen by a
president of the other party. This has happened, moreover, within a
context of growing political polarization--that is, as the economic
policy preferences of presidents from different parties seem to be
diverging. To see how remarkable this is, imagine any current president
voluntarily agreeing to reappoint a Supreme Court justice originally
appointed by the other party.
Second, Fed policy in recent decades (at least, that is, until the
recent economic crisis) appears to have converged on a consensus giving
consistent weight to controlling inflation rather than maintaining high
employment. It is no coincidence that in the voluminous cross-national
literature on monetary policy of the last two decades, the United States
is typically held up as a model of a hard-money regime based on central
bank independence (Iversen 1999).
There are different possible interpretations of this striking
removal of the Fed from partisan politics even as polarization has
grown. One would be that it reflects the extent to which the Federal
Reserve's practices have become a technocratic exercise, about
which there is simply very little partisan disagreement. A second would
be that organized interests, especially financial ones, represent the
most powerful constituency of the Federal Reserve (see, e.g., Epstein
and Schor 1990). On this account, policy makers of either party are
highly constrained in their appointment choices by the need for a
favorable reception within the financial community. Either way, at least
in the contemporary period, the president's appointment power with
regard to the Federal Reserve has provided him with limited independent
capacity to reshape economic practices.
Of course, other presidential appointees have influence over the
economy. And presidents can be expected to use these appointments--and
the unilateral powers of the presidency more broadly--to change the
contours of governing economic policy. Even so, the executive branch is
not the president's alone to guide. Through oversight, budgeting,
legislation, and suasion, members of Congress also leave their own
imprint on its actions. More important, the scope for long-term
restructuring of the economy through unilateral executive action is
inherently limited. The domestic powers of the executive are best suited
for delaying or watering down laws or pushing their boundaries--not for
fundamentally shifting the economic policy landscape. As William Howell (2003, 121) puts it, in a book that generally plays up the
president's unilateral powers, "The president's powers of
unilateral action are greatest when they do not require Congress to take
any subsequent action... But where funding is involved, and nonaction on
the part of Congress spells the demise of an agency or program, the
president's powers of unilateral action diminish
significantly." And funding is only one constraint: Sustained
economic policy shifts usually require the ongoing deployment of
government power to either construct new policy regimes or dismantle
existing ones. These are precisely the sorts of presidential policies
that necessitate legislative as well as executive action.
The Veto. The president's great unilateral policy weapon is
the veto (Cameron 2000). Requiring that vetoed laws achieve a two-thirds
vote in both houses not only gives the president the power to block
legislation, it also creates strong pressures for Congress to move
policy in the direction of the president's wishes. As Alexander
Hamilton explained, in a deft summary of anticipated reactions over two
centuries ago, "When men ... are aware that obstructions may come
from a quarter which they cannot control, they will often be restrained
by the apprehension of opposition, from doing what they would with
eagerness rush into, if no such external impediments were to be
feared" (Hamilton 1787, quoted in Cameron 2000, 18).
These are powerful effects. When presidents are far from the center
of congressional opinion, they can forestall policy shifts by vetoing
laws that lack supermajority support. Through anticipated reactions,
this in turn discourages lawmakers from seeking such changes in the
first place. And even when presidents cannot block legislation, the veto
may pull lawmaking toward presidents, as members of Congress seek to
head off vetoes. Here, as Hamilton foresaw, just the existence of the
veto gives the president leverage to obtain concessions.
The power to stop legislation, moreover, can have larger effects
than often supposed. Failure to enact a new law is not the same as
freezing the existing state of affairs in place. In many areas of
domestic policy, failure of the government to act can lead to major
changes in economic outcomes over time--a process we have elsewhere
termed "policy drift" (Hacker 2004; Hacker and Pierson 2010).
If, for example, unions are losing ground in the face of changing
patterns of production or shifting corporate strategies, a successful
veto of labor reform does not mean unions hold their ground. It means
that organized labor increasingly lacks presence or clout. The
transformation of the American financial sector reflects a similar
process. Rules governing dynamic markets must be regularly updated to
reflect changing financial strategies--or they become ineffective. The
veto is one of the two major legislative sources of gridlock and,
thereby, drift in contemporary American politics. (The other, of course,
is the Senate filibuster.)
Still, the power of the veto should not be overstated. First, the
veto is a reactive power--Hamilton called it a "qualified
negative." In exercising it, presidents respond to what Congress
does. The veto does not make Congress act on specific initiatives or
take up specific issues. It gives presidents a qualified power to say
no.
Second, developments in Congress over the last generation have
tended to make the veto less potent while increasing the overall tilt
toward legislative gridlock. Once rare, the filibuster has become a
routine part of lawmaking on all domestic policy matters besides the
budget (Mayhew 2008). Meanwhile, Congress has become dramatically more
polarized, with centrist members of Congress giving way to more
ideological partisans on the left and, especially, the right (McCarty,
Poole, and Rosenthal 2006). Both shifts have chipped away at the
leverage that presidents gain by virtue of the veto. Unless presidents
are extremely far from the center of congressional opinion, the pivotal
sixtieth senator (who can end a potential filibuster) occupies the
deal-making position in most legislative fights. And with Congress more
polarized, the chance that this pivotal senator is more extreme than the
president increases.
A third limitation, however, is the most important for
understanding long-term policy development: the veto is not simply a
reactive power; it is an oppositional power. That is, the veto gains
significance and heft when presidents are in opposition to congressional
majorities. But these are precisely the conditions most inimical to
presidents' ability to undertake sustained projects of policy
reform. Precisely when the veto power expands, the presidents'
power to remake the economy through long-term governance shrinks. George
W. Bush failed to cast a veto until the sixth year of his presidency;
when he did so, it clearly reflected the waning of his power. Yet his
impact on economic governance, we stress later in this article, was
substantial.
For all these reasons, the veto is a powerful but blunt instrument for economic policy making. If transforming governance involves the
encouragement of policy drift, it can be extremely valuable. More often,
however, presidents seeking fundamental policy change in a polarized
environment with increased tendencies toward gridlock need to move from
a reactive and oppositional role to a proactive and coalitional role. It
is here that the president's role as an agenda-setter and
party-builder becomes vital.
Agenda-Setting and Party-Building. On nearly all important matters
of economic policy, presidents share power with other institutional
actors--notably Congress. This is the basis for Neustadt's (1960)
famous observation that presidential power rests not on authority but
persuasion. Yet in this persuasive role, the president has some
formidable institutional advantages. First, the occupant of the oval
office has the biggest megaphone in American politics--Teddy
Roosevelt's "bully pulpit." Second, presidents play a
central role in organizing and shaping the activities of their parties,
both within and outside government. If the power of the president is the
power to persuade, presidents have a powerful platform for persuasion.
They also have a special position relative to a large cadre of
already-persuaded politicians, activists, interest groups, and voters.
Certainly, the agenda-setting power of presidents is substantial. A
large literature (see, e.g., Edwards 2003; Hill 1998) indicates that
presidents can move issues already in play higher up the legislative
agenda and sometimes even bring relatively neglected issues to the fore.
A Democrat wins the presidency and the subject is health care. A
Republican wins and the subject is tax cuts. In particular, as Matthew
Beckmann (2010) convincingly argues, presidents' greatest source of
influence is their ability to work with leaders of their party to
advance issues and alternatives that are congruent with their policy
agenda, while keeping unfavorable issues and alternatives off the
agenda.
Presidents have generally been far less successful, however, in
determining how citizens or legislators respond to these issues. George
C. Edwards III (2003) has compiled an impressive amount of polling
suggesting that presidential public statements have modest effects on
public opinion. President Obama, for example, proved consistently unable
to shift public opinion on health care reform in 2009 and 2010, despite
success in raising health care to the top of the legislative agenda.
Of course, public opinion is not the only target of presidential
persuasion. Indeed, given the increased polarization of Congress and the
president's central role as a party builder, it may not even be the
most important. As Edwards suggests, much of what presidents do amounts
to preaching to the converted, or more accurately, helping the converted
figure out how exactly to get to the promised land--as President Obama
eventually did in unifying Democrats behind a health care bill despite
bitter internal disagreements. Moreover, while the ranks of the
converted may be relatively fixed over the short term, presidents can
build party-based alliances in Congress and the electorate over the
longer term. As Daniel Galvin has argued, Republican presidents, in
particular, have invested in long-term party-building in ways that have
conduced to the benefit of their successors (2010).
Yet in both these roles--agenda setter and party leader--presidents
are most influential when they are allied with regnant congressional
factions whose leadership shares overlapping goals with the White House.
And as with other aspects of the president's political environment,
these deeper partnerships cannot be forged by presidents on the day they
come into office. They depend heavily on the formation and endurance of
coalitions that predate the president's inauguration.
This is the essential insight of Stephen Skowronek's notion of
"political time"--presidents' fortunes hinge in crucial
part on whether they are opposed to or aligned with the existing
"regime" and the legitimacy of this reigning order (Skowronek
1993). Presidents who stand in opposition to a discredited set of ideas
and leadership commitments have the greatest leeway to innovate and
remake politics and policy. Yet this process is hardly automatic.
Historically, presidents could innovate at these moments because the
discrediting of the losing coalition gave rise to large legislative
majorities aligned with the president. This was less true under Reagan
and even more so under Obama--despite these presidents' ability to
capitalize on the weakness of the opposition and of prior governing
principles.
In addition, political time may be less relevant in the era of
activist government and, more recently, institutionalized supermajority
requirements (Skowronek 1993). With many governing commitments deeply
embedded, the opportunity for decisive breaks with prior policy requires
more than an oppositional stance and a weakened set of adversaries.
Instead, opportunities for reform are dependent on the place of
presidents within durable coalitions of activists, interest groups, and
congressional partisans that can push back relentlessly against
established policies over the long term.
Presidents and the Transformation of American Taxation
If parties are sustained by intense policy demanders, who seek to
balance the need for votes with the desire to remake governance, they
will embody distinctive networks of interest-group supporters and
activists. Presidents rely on these networks for support and success.
Thus, one reason we should expect partisan differences in economic
governance is that presidents can rarely change domestic economic policy
in lasting ways without the support of other actors.
Moreover, presidents have limited time. Their efforts to achieve
lasting change depend not only on their own efforts and skill, as well
as that of their allies, but also on their coalitional partners'
ongoing capacities to make those reforms stick or expand. The success of
presidents in reshaping governance thus rests on their place within
durable coalitions dedicated to shared aims and capable of long-term
mobilization.
Precisely because presidents act within such coalitions, the
relative resources and mobilization of competing political forces matter
enormously for their influence. Partisan differences can therefore exist
side-by-side with enduring shifts in the center of gravity on contested
issues--shifts that affect both parties. Over the last generation, for
example, business groups have become more organized and mobilized, while
organized labor and broad civic groups have lost ground. This shift
altered incentives for both parties, but its effects have not been
identical on each or consistent across issues. Some increasingly
powerful groups, like the financial industry, have worked closely with
allies in both parties. Overall, however, the major shift in the balance
of organized economic power has encouraged Republicans to move sharply
to the right, while cross-pressuring Democrats. Although Democrats still
rely heavily on the organizational support of unions and the votes of
less affluent citizens, the organization and resources of mobilized
business groups have exerted a powerful pull on the party as money has
become more important for campaigns and lobbying more pervasive. (7)
We can see these contrasting effects in many of the major policy
shifts of the last generation that have been linked to the
hyperconcentration of income at the top (Hacker and Pierson 2010).
Republicans presidents and members of Congress often spearheaded
financial deregulation; they were far more aggressive toward unions and
more fiercely protective of the pay and prerogatives of corporate
executives. Yet Democratic political leaders were not consistently on
the other side. Most notably, President Clinton and leading
congressional Democrats actively cultivated the support of the financial
industry. Revealingly, Democrats tended to adopt lower-profile policy
strategies than did Republicans, blocking or watering down proposed
regulatory actions or reform proposals, rather than leading the charge
for new laws, which could create greater tension with traditional
supporters.
Yet the domain of economic policy that most demands attention is
taxation. As Figure 2 shows, changes in taxation have powerfully
reinforced the concentration of economic rewards at the very top. The
effective federal tax rate paid by the richest 0.1% of households has
fallen by around half since the 1970s, even as the share of income
earned by this rarified group has skyrocketed (Piketty and Saez 2007).
Tax policy also provides a clear window into the distributional
struggles between the parties and the role of the president within those
fights. In a careful review of tax policy debates from 1950 to 2000,
Jeff Stonecash and Andrew Milstein (2001) note a profound and revealing
transformation beginning around 1980. The main object of party
contestation shifted from tax levels and structure to distribution. At
the same time, the divisions between the parties become much more
pronounced. Since 1990, a Republican-centered durable coalition has
fought tenaciously and effectively for two principles: revenues should
be as low as possible, and taxes on the wealthiest should be reduced
whenever possible.
[FIGURE 2 OMITTED]
Tax policy also commands attention because it represents a
challenging case for our argument. Tax changes are highly visible and
their first-order effects relatively transparent. They would thus seem
less favorable to organized political actors with specialized knowledge
and inside access than many complex areas of regulatory and economic
policy. No less important, taxes are a budget matter, and since Reagan
used the budget process to push through his agenda in 1981, budgetary
procedures have provided a streamlined path to presidential legislative
success on tax policy issues. (In particular, the budget is not subject
to the Senate filibuster.) If, as we argue, this success has nonetheless
been heavily shaped and constrained by the place of presidents within
durable policy coalitions, then the case for seeing these influences and
constraints as more general is all the stronger.
In the remainder of this section, we examine the struggles over
taxation since the late 1970s, situating the president's role
within this crucial battle to remake the American political economy. The
almost uninterrupted decline in federal taxes on the highest earners
actually began in the late 1970s under President Carter, though not at
his behest. Since then, however, Republican presidents (with the
exception of the first president Bush) have played their appointed role
as leaders of a durable policy coalition committed to high-end tax cuts.
While Democratic presidents have pushed back, the tax-cutting
forces--mobilized, resourceful, organized, and more internally
unified--have been winning the war. Perhaps their greatest victory came
in the early 2000s when President George W. Bush successfully championed
massive tax cuts for the well off. As we shall see, however, Bush's
ability to achieve this dramatic breakthrough rested on the construction
of a powerful antitax coalition that predated his arrival in office and,
equally important, has continued to shape policy even after Democrats
regained the White House in 2008.
Our point is not to deny Bush's role; his administration
played a vital part in shaping the agenda, coordinating initiatives, and
mobilizing support for tax cuts in 2000 and beyond. Our point is that
the presence of an effective, durable coalition was essential. Success
depended on the sustained strength of this coalition, not just in the
White House, but on Capitol Hill, and among a set of committed and
organized actors who worked effectively to discipline and focus the
actions of politicians on both ends of Pennsylvania Avenue. Indeed, it
is difficult to imagine any GOP president at this juncture behaving very
differently than Bush did. And without that coalition's continuing
efforts over more than a decade since the first Bush tax cuts were
enacted, they would not have proven to be the watershed event they were.
The transformative potential of the presidency must be placed in the
context of shifting coalitional dynamics like these.
High-end Tax Cuts: A Durable Policy Coalition in Action
Almost immediately after entering office in 2001, President Bush
helped engineer a major shift in federal tax policy that dramatically
reduced the overall tax burden and shifted it away from asset holders
and the wealthy. In each of the next three years, President Bush
successfully pushed for additional cuts--first for businesses in 2002,
then for individuals in 2003, and then again for individuals in 2004.
The biggest of these post-2001 bills, the tax revision of 2003, was the
most remarkable. Roughly as tilted toward the affluent as the 2001 bill,
its estimated price tag exceeded $1 trillion over ten years, at a time
when budget projections showed a mounting tide of red ink.
All told, the 2001-04 tax cuts produced both a dramatic reduction
in revenues and a substantial shift in the distribution of tax burdens.
By the end of President Bush's first term, tax cuts and a weak
economy had helped reduce income tax revenues to their lowest level as a
share of the economy since 1942 and to their lowest level as a share of
all federal taxes since 1941. Between 2000 and 2004, the federal balance
sheet underwent an astonishing reversal, from officially projected
surpluses of more than $5 trillion over ten years to projected deficits
of more than $4 trillion (Kogan and Kamin 2004). These deficits were, in
substantial part, due to more generous treatment of higher-income
Americans even as their pretax incomes soared. In 1995, the top 400
taxpayers paid, on average, 30% of their income in federal income taxes;
by 2007, they paid 16.6% (Feller and Mart 2010).
That these fundamental policy shifts are often called the
"Bush tax cuts" constitutes a convenient but highly misleading
shorthand. The cuts--their massive scope, skewed distribution, and
political durability--reflected a decades-long struggle to make high-end
tax cuts a leading Republican priority. Although the antitax agenda had
popular as well as elite roots, the long-term project focused, first and
foremost, on bringing Republican political elites into line with the
policy preferences of "intense demanders" on taxation. The
primary mechanism was an increasingly effective system for recruiting
and monitoring GOP politicians to insure fealty on tax policy. This new
system assured that as turnover in the party took place, the
party's traditional attachment to fiscal conservatism would give
way to a zeal for tax cuts. The dramatic shift in taxation reflected the
success of this durable policy coalition. (8)
Building a Coalition for High-end Tax Cuts
Tax cuts emerged as a major issue in American politics in the late
1970s, before Ronald Reagan came to office. At the outset, the issue
lacked the clear partisan tenor that it would come to have. Responding
to political defeats in the early 1970s, business mobilized on an
unprecedented scale and made tax cuts (along with regulatory rollbacks)
a major priority (Vogel 1989). This intense organizational activity
targeted both parties, to major effect: even in the context of unified
Democratic control, business-led advocates successfully pushed for
dramatic reductions in capital gains taxation in 1978.
Ronald Reagan's tax-cut agenda picked up where these victories
left off. Yet in addition to strong business backing, Reagan's
efforts also had populist foundations, and they focused less than the
cuts to come on benefits for the wealthiest. To be sure, powerful
organized interests provided essential support for the Reagan campaign
and its 1981 tax cuts, but the push for lower taxation was also a mass
phenomenon, reinforced by key focusing events like the success of the
Proposition 13 campaign in California (Sears and Citrin 1982). Reagan
made tax cuts the centerpiece of his campaign, and survey data suggests
that this call resonated within the electorate.
In the wake of Reagan's rise, GOP elites embraced his tax cut
agenda. The depth of that commitment, however, was less certain.
Midwestern and Northeastern moderates made up a much larger share of the
Republican coalition 30 years ago. Views about government spending were
more tempered, and the desire for tax cuts coexisted with concern for
fiscal prudence. Reagan's first--and only--success in cutting
taxes, the massive reductions contained in the 1981 Economic Recovery
and Tax Act, combined with a recession to generate unprecedented
deficits.
What followed demonstrated that a durable tax-cutting coalition was
not yet in place. With the support of moderate Republican elites, Reagan
made a remarkable about-face. Amidst alarm about the deficit, he
supported large tax increases in 1982 and 1984. A major tax reform in
1986 was revenue neutral. His successor, George H. W. Bush, followed
suit by endorsing the 1990 budget agreement, which combined tax
increases and spending cuts in a major effort to reduce the budget
deficit (see Table 1).
In retrospect, however, 1990 was as much of a watershed in tax
politics as the much more politically successful (and thus much better
remembered) gambits of Reagan in 1981 and George W. Bush in 2001. It was
a watershed because it triggered a realignment among Republican elites,
consolidating a durable coalition committed to high-end tax cuts before
all other economic priorities. The year 1990 marked the key transition
from an old to a new Republican Party, from an older generation of
political moderates and fiscal conservatives to a new generation of
hard-line conservatives and committed tax cutters. In the face of a
Republican president's appeal for compromise to reduce the deficit
that included tax increases, Newt Gingrich and his allies led over half
the Republicans in the House to inflict a humiliating defeat on their
party's ostensible leader. Republican moderates in Congress never
recovered. Within two years, Gingrich and his allies swept into the
leadership and rapidly signaled a much more aggressive and radical
posture.
The impact of this transformation can be seen in Table 1. Prior to
the Gingrich revolt, Republicans accepted bipartisan agreements that
combined spending cuts and tax increases. After 1990, however, deficit
packages either contained no tax increases (the 1997 agreement actually
called for tax cuts)--or they received no Republican votes.
The trends that led to this leadership revolution accelerated after
1992, producing a thoroughgoing transformation of the Republican elite.
The central mechanism was replacement. As Southern Democrats in Congress
were defeated or retired, they were replaced by intensely conservative
Southern Republicans. Less frequently noted but equally significant was
what happened to the rest of the Republican caucus. Bastions of
Republican moderation in the Northeast slowly ceded ground to Democrats.
And where the GOP held seats outside the South, retiring incumbents were
typically replaced by much more conservative Republicans (Carmines 2011;
Theriault 2008).
Shifting elite preferences regarding taxation were an integral part
of this rightward shift. Though Republicans have long fought against
higher taxes, this goal was always in tension with, and sometimes
subordinated to, a commitment to fiscal conservatism. The traditional
attitude was well summarized in Gingrich's derisive description of
Senate leader Robert Dole as "the tax collector for the welfare
state" (Balz 1998, A1). After 1990, the new-line Republicans
reversed the priority between fiscal conservatism and tax cuts. For this
generation of politicians, reducing taxes--especially for those with the
highest incomes--was paramount.
Why did replacements in the Republican Party lead to far more
militant positions on taxation? A full explanation is beyond the scope
of this article, but there is good evidence that the emergence of a set
of durable organizations committed to the tax-cut agenda were a vital
part of the story. Activist pressures to promote a strong and consistent
antitax stance led to the emergence of a much more institutionalized
network of organizations dedicated to promoting this stance and
disciplining politicians who strayed from it. Heavily funded by the most
affluent elements of American society, these organizations exhibited and
encouraged a tenacious commitment to high-end tax cuts. In the process,
the energies of antitax advocates shifted from strategies of mass
mobilization focused on building broad public support to increasingly
sophisticated strategies of elite mobilization that focused on
recruiting and monitoring politicians. Well-funded organizations came to
play a key role in producing like-minded candidates--or at least
candidates who faced powerful incentives to behave as if they were like
minded. Thus, these organizations cemented a durable policy coalition by
strengthening the connections of GOP politicians to "extreme policy
demanders" on tax issues.
A central player in this transformation was Grover Norquist's
Americans for Tax Reform (ATR). (9) ATR began as a White House
operation, headed by Norquist, in the run-up to the Tax Reform Act of
1986 (ironically, given ATR's evolution, the last great attempt at
a revenue-neutral clean-up of the tax code). If one looked in the
dictionary for a definition of "extreme policy demander," it
would probably show a picture of Norquist. He equated taxation with
theft and the estate tax with the holocaust, and described his goal as a
50% reduction in government (and taxes) as a share of gross domestic
product ("down to the size where you could drown it in the
bathtub" [Franklin and Newmyer 2005])--roughly the state of
pre-World War II government. Befitting his decidedly noncentrist views,
the organization he created was an elite rather than mass operation. It
had a small membership, and relied heavily on large donations (including
sizable contributions from both major corporations and the Republican
Party). The "mass" element of this influential organization
was largely confined to electioneering rather than grassroots
mobilization. Instead ATR focused its efforts on insuring that GOP
elites signed on to an aggressive strategy of tax reduction and stayed
true to that commitment.
A central ATR innovation was the introduction of Tax Pledges, in
which elected officials and candidates for office made specific pledges
not to support tax increases. (10) Some Republican politicians, mostly
moderate incumbents, resisted these pledges for a time. For
nonincumbents, however, the logic of contemporary Republican primaries
made them a necessary component of any successful run for Congress.
Moderates wishing to shore up their position generally signed on as
well--if not, their successors did. By the end of 2003, ATR had pledges
from 216 members of the House (just two short of a majority), 42 U.S.
senators, as well as President Bush. Notably, signers of the pledge also
made up an absolute majority of members of Congress on the two crucial
House committees that shaped the 2001-04 tax cuts: Ways and Means, and
Budget (Gale and Orszag 2004).
These organized antitax forces often worked closely with Republican
leadership to build a durable coalition that benefited from the shifting
realities of American politics. Campaign and lobbying money was a big
part of these new realities, and it flowed disproportionately from the
affluent and ideologically extreme. Equally important, the coalition
benefited from the increased power of parties in government as agenda
setters, disciplinarians, and financers. Agenda-setting and financial
prowess, in particular, gave party leaders greater ability to provide
political cover for rank-and-file members who took positions that were
out of step with their constituents (Van Houweling 2003; Hacker and
Pierson 2005). The result was not just increasing polarization--a pull
toward the extremes on both sides of the aisle but especially on the
Republican side (McCarty, Poole, and Rosenthal 2006). It was also an
environment in which GOP politicians had increasing need, desire, and
capacity to respond to the most powerful organized force within the
party, the antitax base.
The New Republican Strategy
Advocacy groups seeking radical changes in tax policy not only
played an important role in recruiting and monitoring politicians, they
also helped develop a more sophisticated, coordinated, and effective
conservative strategy for durably changing policy. Indeed, a crucial
piece of the antitax story has been a striking shift in both the goals
and strategies of tax reduction. Policy battles reverberate through the
political system, and key actors derive lessons from those battles. One
of the attributes of a durable coalition is the capacity to learn (Teles
2008), and ATR and other elite organizations manning the antitax
barricades were quick to draw lessons and adapt.
The broadest and most bitter lesson that tax cutters derived from
the experience of the 1980s and early 1990s was that deficit reduction
too often trumped tax reduction. Many on the left argued that the
deficit was a Trojan Horse to launch an assault on social spending. To
the Right's dismay, however, deficits served at least as much to
undercut the tax-cutting agenda. Despite the centrality of tax cuts to
Reagan's agenda, no major tax cuts passed after 1981. Instead,
significant increases were introduced in 1982, 1984, 1990, and 1993 (see
Table 1). Indeed, it was this track record that triggered the creation
of the Club for Growth, another elite antitax organization. Cofounder Richard Gilder, an influential stockbroker, philanthropist, and ardent
supply-sider put it this way: "We would hear these great growth
ideas about how [the candidates] were going to cut taxes and push for
growth, and then they'd get down there [to Washington] and vote to
raise taxes" (Newlin 2002).
With the strengthening of "supply-side" advocacy groups
and a more radicalized Republican caucus, GOP leaders determined to make
tax cuts a priority regardless of whether they produced deficits or not.
In this respect, the contrast between the aftermaths of 1981 and 2001
could not be more striking. Congressional Republicans who eagerly
embraced the Reagan tax cuts rapidly changed course once large deficits
appeared. Twenty years later, however, a ballooning deficit had nothing
like the same effect. Republican politicians not only failed to reverse
course; they worked energetically to push the revenue line lower.
Sizable tax cuts were introduced in 2003 and 2004, overriding the few
remaining Republican moderates' muffled expressions of concern over
deficits. Ronald Suskind's recounting of his conversations with
then-Treasury Secretary Paul O'Neill captured the essence of a
durable policy coalition in action. When O'Neill expressed concern
about the scale and targeting of the tax cuts, Vice President Cheney was
insistent: "We won the mid-term elections; this is our due"
(Suskind 2004, 291).
Along with this broad reformulation of goals came important
strategic opportunities. Once the notion that tax cuts must be
"paid for" was rejected, Republicans learned that there were
enormous opportunities to push for tax cuts that were both larger and
more (upwardly) redistributive than anyone had previously thought
possible. Again, policy development reflected a process of political
learning, in which intense policy demanders experimented with various
tactics. The goal was to maximize their capacity to pursue their
ambitious policies in an institutional setting widely understood to
require compromise.
The success of these efforts rested on three broad tactics. (11)
The first was to use unified Republican command over the House, Senate
(where Republicans had the narrowest of possible margins), and White
House to dominate agenda setting. As both polls and prior experience
suggested, the biggest obstacle to successful tax cutting stemmed from
its unfavorable implications for deficits and popular government
programs. Procedural rules like the "Paygo" system that had
previously governed congressional budgeting (which required that all
spending and tax cuts be financed) made the opportunity costs of tax
cuts visible. (12) So did competing Democratic agenda setters,
especially during President Clinton's time in the White House.
Indeed, it was Clinton's success in emphasizing the high
opportunity costs of tax cuts (combined, of course, with his veto power)
that had held previous tax cut initiatives in check (Balz and Brownstein
1996). Bush's ascension to the White House eliminated this factor.
Yet while Bush's arrival triggered a sharp increase in agenda
control, the preconditions for this powerful tactic had, in fact, been
accumulating for almost two decades. Party leaders in Congress had
greatly increased their capacity to control the legislative agenda, and
they dictated the participants in conference committees, which in turn
control the proposals that will be brought to the floors of the House
and Senate for a final up or down vote. Robert Van Houweling has
persuasively argued that interventions of this kind have increased for a
very specific reason: they enable legislators to enact extreme policies
without courting electoral backlash by making it more difficult for
voters (but not highly informed "intense policy demanders") to
recognize and respond to policies they might otherwise regard as extreme
(Van Houweling 2003).
In both 2001 and 2003, Congressional Republicans worked
effectively, especially in the increasingly centralized House, to
translate narrow legislative majorities into effective agenda control.
In both cases, they pushed successfully for large tax cuts. In both
cases, they benefited from their ability to pursue tax cuts through the
budget reconciliation process--the streamlined procedure for enacting
annual budgets that, unlike all other normal Senate business, is not
subject to the Senate filibuster. The lack of a filibuster threat made
passing the tax cuts easier. But it does not explain why these
initiatives were so large, so skewed in favor of the affluent, or so
well insulated from serious contemplation of the implications for
deficits and government programs (Hacker and Pierson 2005). After all,
reconciliation has been the route for all the major deficit-reduction
packages of the 1980s and 1990s as well. What fundamentally changed in
the late 1990s (with the revenue-losing 1997 budget deal) and
accelerated in the early 2000s (with the 2001 and 2003 tax cuts) was the
pressure and policy strategies of the antirax coalition, not the
procedure that facilitated their aims.
The second tactic that was used was a systematic exploitation of
previously untapped political potential buried within the complex and
obscure processes of policy formulation (Arnold 1990). Over time, tax
cut advocates had learned how to design policies in ways that made tax
cuts look much smaller and more equitable than they actually were. By
employing phase-ins and "sunsets" of key provisions,
legislators could make the "official" cost of their proposals
much lower than the actual cost was likely to be. Legislators could also
make the benefits appear to be far more targeted on middle-income voters
than they really were. Most of the popular middle-class tax cuts were
phased in immediately, for instance, while the big cuts for the affluent
only took effect later--even though they comprised the lion's share
of the total cuts.
Third, tax cut advocates discovered new and powerful techniques to
control not just today's policy agenda but tomorrow's. Policy
features in the new legislation were designed not only to put the best
initial face on these initiatives; they were also structured to create
opportunities for legislators to set the agenda for further tax cuts
down the road. For example, the 2001 tax cuts included a "time
bomb" that would make a well-understood problem with the tax
code--the increasing number of middle-class Americans snared by the
alternative minimum tax--much worse over the medium run. This
"defect by design" strategy allowed tax-cut advocates to get
more tax cuts now and more tax cuts later when the alternative minimum
tax time bomb went off. At the same time, by scheduling features to
"sunset" at a future date, tax cut advocates structured the
future policy agenda in advance. With the sunset provisions, GOP leaders
were essentially prescheduling votes that could be framed as up-or-down
decisions on raising people's taxes.
The effectiveness of this strategy was immediately evident. In
2004, despite a deficit of almost half a trillion dollars, provisions of
the 2001 bill scheduled to expire were instead extended, by votes of
339-65 in the House and 92-3 in the Senate. It is not coincidental that
these provisions--the least skewed toward the rich of the 2001 and 2003
cuts--were set to expire right before the election. Nor, given what we
have shown, is it surprising that Republicans still managed to include
new tax breaks for higher-income groups in the legislation.
More telling still, Republicans were able to sustain most of their
tax cut victories, even when growth of the deficit revealed the
hollowness of claims that the cuts were affordable, even when the
GOP's political position weakened considerably after 2006, and even
after Democrats recaptured the White House in 2008. Democrats, despite
gaining a majority in Congress, proved unable to overcome a framing that
makes any failure to extend tax cuts tantamount to a tax increase. Even
President Obama's compromise strategy of curtailing the high-end
tax cuts alone failed. The administration sought to restrict expiration
to those tax cuts exclusively benefiting the very top income groups.
Despite polling that suggests strong public support for such a step,
unified and intense Republican opposition, combined with hesitancy among
a small but pivotal part of the Democratic caucus, proved sufficient to
block such an effort, according to Andrea Campbell (2011). Trapped in a
political cul de sac, it would not be hard to imagine a frustrated President Obama penning a private letter like Eisenhower's:
"There are those who think the Bush tax cuts can be undone; their
number is negligible and they are stupid."
Although journalists often treat George W. Bush as the author of
this remarkable GOP success, it would be more accurate to locate its
origin in a durable policy coalition centered in the congressional
leadership and elite organizations. Because of this coalition, any GOP
president would have pursued large tax cuts in the early 2000s. More
important, the coalition is a critical factor explaining the size,
distribution, and durability of the early 2000s tax cuts. Revealingly,
many of the core features of the GOP strategy were already apparent
before Bush entered office--notably, in the 1997 budget deal and in the
unified GOP opposition to the 1993 budget. These events under a
Democratic president signaled the demise of the old GOP handbook.
Henceforth, Republican officeholders in Congress and the Oval Office
would seek not just tax cuts, but large tax cuts focused on the well off
that were divorced from serious consideration of budget consequences.
The coalition's tenacity was equally evident in the sharply
contrasting reactions to huge deficits that emerged following the tax
cuts of 1981 and 2001. In the first instance, Republicans retreated; in
the second, they doubled down. Though new opportunities accompanied
unified control of Congress and the White House in 2001, their use was
guided by an ideologically committed, unusually disciplined, and
well-coordinated durable policy coalition.
In short, the passage of tax cuts in the early 2000s was the
culmination of a longer coalitional story. Yet, in many ways, it is the
endurance of these cuts in the years since--despite massive deficits,
despite the need for legislative renewal of the cuts, and despite the
election of a Democratic president--that represents the most powerful
indication of the antitax coalition's sway. Bush's leadership
on taxes was effective. Yet his administration was but one temporary
part of a broader coalition whose actions over time led to surprisingly
successful efforts to escape from the fiscal gridlock so evident in
American politics. These efforts revealed clearly how a focused and
determined coalition could activate long-held policy ambitions when the
opportune moment arrived.
Presidential Economics Revisited
It is frequently noted that when the worst financial calamity since
the Great Depression hit the United States, the discipline of economics
was ill prepared. The problem was not just a failure of prediction,
since prediction of singular events is a daunting task. It was more
deeply a failure to develop an intellectual architecture that would
focus attention on the relevant economic phenomena. Economists had other
preoccupations. Strikingly little in their vast research efforts spoke
to the question of what exactly had happened and why, or how to stop
such a crisis from happening again.
Though less commonly noted, the same is true of political science.
The political dimensions of our current crisis are increasingly
apparent--particularly its underpinnings in an array of shifting public
policies involving financial deregulation and lax oversight. Yet as
observers sought to make sense of these profoundly important
developments, political science had surprisingly little to offer--even
though more political scientists study contemporary American politics
than have studied any polity in human history. There had been, for
instance, no systematic studies of financial deregulation or detailed
analyses of the relationships between political leaders and increasingly
expansive, powerful, and reckless Wall Street actors. Nor were there
many serious efforts to study the contributions of the Federal Reserve,
whose powerful chair played a vital role in facilitating the
revolutionary transformation of American finance during the run-up to an
economic implosion. Like their economist brethren, political scientists
had other things on their minds.
In this article, we have explored this mismatch between the
preoccupations of political scientists and the substantive travails of
the American polity through an examination of the one area where
political scientists have actually focused on economic matters in a
sustained way: the study of the presidency. Though scholars have long
recognized the president's crucial role in shaping the economy,
much of the research on presidents and the political economy has
narrowly emphasized short-term relationships between macroeconomic
policies and economic outcomes and between those outcomes and
presidential election outcomes. This focus--evident, as we have seen, in
even the most sophisticated recent work--overstates the unilateral
economic powers of presidents, misses the deeper policy mechanisms
through which presidents can shape the character of the economy and the
distribution of economic rewards, and neglects the profound dependence
of these efforts on durable coalitions of organized interests seeking to
reshape governance over the long term. The post-1970s shift of American
tax policy toward tax cuts for the affluent shows the constraints and
opportunities that a durable policy coalition can create for presidents
of both parties--and the enduring changes in the American political
economy that can result.
By November 2010, the moment of greatest potential to reverse the
tax policy breakthrough of the early 2000s had passed. The GOP's
midterm victory transferred control of the House, ending any prospect
that a Democratic president could significantly scale back the tax-cut
triumphs of his Republican predecessor. GOP leaders strengthened their
resistance to tax increases, even as they adopted apocalyptic rhetoric
about the deficit and national debt. In a telling testament to the
strength of "intense policy demanders" within the modern GOP,
the Republican presidential candidates were asked in a televised debate
if they would "walk away" from a deficit reduction plan in
which spending cuts outweighed tax increases by 10 to 1. Despite
previous expressions of alarm about the "deficit crisis," all
the Republican candidates quickly raised their hands to indicate that
they would reject such a proposal.
If one of these candidates becomes president, the new Republican
occupant of the Oval Office will be both constrained and enabled by this
enduring coalition. It is a coalition that seeks not just electoral
victory, but substantive shifts in public policy. And it is a coalition
whose notable successes in recent years have fundamentally altered the
distribution of the economy's rewards. A revitalized study of the
president's role in shaping the political economy--so essential to
revitalizing the study of American political economy more broadly--will
need to focus on the capacity of government to shape long-term economic
outcomes through durable public policies and on the tenacious efforts of
organized actors to determine what those policies are.
References
Abrams, Burton, and Plamen Iossifov. 2006. "Does the Fed
Contribute to a Political Business Cycle?" Public Choice 129 (3):
249-62.
Alesina, Alberto, and Howard Rosenthal. 1995. Partisan Politics,
Divided Government, and the Economy. New York: Cambridge University
Press.
Arnold, R. Douglas. 1990. The Logic of Congressional Action. New
Haven, CT: Yale University Press.
Arrow, Kenneth. 1951. Social Choice and Individual Values. New
York: John Wiley & Sons.
Balz, Dan. 1998. "For GOP Fighter, A Confrontation He
Didn't Want." Washington Post, November 7.
Balz, Dan, and Ronald Brownstein. 1996. Storming the Gates: Protest
Politics and the Republican Revival. Boston: Little, Brown.
Bartels, Larry M. 2008. Unequal Democracy: The Political Economy of
the New Gilded Age. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.
Bawn, Kathleen, et al. 2011. "A Theory of Political
Parties." Unpublished manuscript.
Baumgartner, Frank, and Bryan Jones. 1993. Agendas and Instability
in American Politics. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.
Beckmann, Matthew N. 2010. Pushing the Agenda: Presidential
Leadership in U.S. Lawmaking, 1953-2004. New York: Cambridge University
Press.
Cameron, Charles M. 2000. Veto Bargaining: Presidents and the
Politics of Negative Power. New York: Cambridge University Press.
Campbell, Andrea. 2011. "Paying America's Way: The
Fraught Politics of Taxes, Investments, and Budgetary
Responsibility." In Reaching for a New Deal: Ambitious Governance,
Economic Meltdown, and Polarized Politics, eds. Lawrence Jacobs and
Theda Skocpol. New York: Oxford University Press, 386-422.
Campbell, James E. 2011. "The Economic Records of the
Presidents: Party Differences and Inherited Economic Conditions,"
Forum 9 (1): art. 7.
Carmines, Edward G. 2011. Contribution to Symposium on
"Winner-Take-All Politics." Perspectives on Politics 9 (3):
645-47.
Cohen, Marry, David Karol, Hans Noel, and John Zaller. 2008. The
Party Decides: Presidential Nominations Before and After Reform.
Chicago: University of Chicago Press.
Congressional Budget Office. 2010. "Average Federal Taxes by
Income Group." http://www.cbo.gov/
publications/collections/collections.cfm?collect=13 (accessed December
16, 2011).
--. 2011. Trends in the Distribution of Household Income between
1979 and 2007. Washington, DC: CBO.
http://www.cbo.gov/ftpdocs/124xx/doc12485/10-25-HouseholdIncome.pdf
(accessed January 6, 2011).
Edwards, III, George C. 2003. On Deaf Ears: The Limits of the Bully
Pulpit. New Haven, CT: Yale University Press.
Eisenhower, Dwight. 1954. Letter to Edgar Newton Eisenhower. The
Presidential Papers of Dwight David Eisenhower. Doc. No. 1147, November
8.
Epstein, Gerald A., and Juliet B. Schor. 1990. "Corporate
Profitability as a Determinant of Restrictive Monetary Policy: Estimates
for the Postwar United States." In The Political Economy of
American Monetary Policy, ed. Thomas Mayer. New York: Cambridge
University Press, 51-63.
Erikson, Robert S. 1989. "Economic Conditions and the
Presidential Vote." American Political Science Review 83: 567-73.
Erikson, Robert S., Michael B. MacKuen, and James A. Stimson. 2002.
The Macro Polity. New York: Cambridge University Press.
Esping-Andersen, Gosta. 1990. The Three Worlds of Welfare
Capitalism. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.
Feller, Avi, and Chuck Marr. 2010. Tax Rate for the Richest 400
Taxpayers Plummeted in Recent Decades, Even as Their Pre-Tax Incomes
Skyrocketed. Washington, DC: Center on Budget and Policy Priorities.
Franklin, Daniel, and A. G. Newmyer III. 2005. "Is Grover
Over?" Washington Monthly, March.
Gale, William G., and Peter R. Orszag. 2004. "The 'No New
Taxes' Pledge." Tax Notes 12: 197-209.
Galvin, Daniel. 2010. Presidential Party-Building: Dwight D.
Eisenhower to George W. Bush. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.
Hacker, Jacob S. 2004. "Privatizing Risk without Privatizing
the Welfare State: The Hidden Politics of Social Policy Retrenchment in
the United States." American Political Science Review 98 (2):
243-60.
Hacker, Jacob S., and Paul Pierson. 2005. "Abandoning the
Middle: The Bush Tax Cuts and the Limits of Democratic Control."
Perspectives on Politics 3 (1): 33-53.
--. 2007. "Tax Politics and the Struggle over Activist
Government." In The Transformation of American Government, eds.
Paul Pierson and Theda Skocpol. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University
Press, 256-80.
--. 2010. Winner-Take-All Politics: How Washington Made the Rich
Richer And Turned Its Back on the Middle Class. New York: Simon and
Schuster.
Hall, Peter, and David Soskice. 2001. Varieties of Capitalism.
Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Hamilton, Alexander. 1787. The Federalist Papers. No. 73. Columbus
OH: McGraw-Hill.
Hibbs, Douglas J. 1977. "Political Parties and Macroeconomic
Policy." American Political Science Review 71: 1467-87.
--. 1987. The American Political Economy. Cambridge, MA: Harvard
University Press.
Hill, Kim Quaile. 1998. "The Policy Agendas of the President
and the Mass Public: A Research Validation and Extension." American
Journal of Political Science 42 (4): 1328-34.
Howell, William G. 2003. Power without Persuasion. Princeton, NJ:
Princeton University Press.
Huber, Evelyn, and John Stephens. 2001. Development and Crisis of
the Welfare State: Parties and Policies in Global Markets. Chicago:
University of Chicago Press.
Iversen, Torben. 1999. Contested Economic Institutions: The
Politics of Macroeconomics and Wage Bargaining in Advanced Democracies.
New York: Cambridge University Press.
Isaac, Jeffrey C. 2009. "Review Editor's Introduction to
a Review Symposium on Unequal Democracy." Perspectives on Politics
7 (1): 143-44.
Jacobs, Lawrence R., and Theda Skocpol. 2011. Reaching for a New
Deal: Ambitious Governance, Economic Meltdown, and Polarized Politics.
New York: Oxford University Press.
Kenworthy, Lane. 2010. "How Much Do Presidents Influence
Income Inequality?" Challenge 53 (2): 90-112.
Kogan, Richard, and David Kamin. 2004. New Congressional Budget
Office Estimates Show Continued High Deficits and Further Fiscal
Deterioration. Washington, DC: Center for Budget and Policy Priorities.
http://www.cbpp.org/cms/index.cfm?fa=view&id=2208 (accessed January
6, 2011).
Leonhardt, David. 2008. "Insights Both Fresh and Tested."
New York Times, November 24.
Mayer, Thomas, ed. 1990. The Political Economy of American Monetary
Policy. New York: Cambridge University Press.
Mayhew, David R. 2002. Electoral Realignments: A Critique of an
American Genre. New Haven, CT: Yale University Press.
--. 2008. Parties and Policies: How American Government Works. New
Haven, CT: Yale University Press.
McCarty, Nolan, Keith T. Poole, and Howard Rosenthal. 2006.
Polarized America: The Dance of Ideology and Unequal Riches. Cambridge,
MA: MIT Press.
Melnick, R. Shep. 1994. Between the Lines: Interpreting Welfare
Rights. Washington, DC: Brookings Institution.
Meltzer, Alan H., and Scott F. Richard. 1981. "A Rational
Theory of the Size of Government." Journal of Political Economy 89
(5): 914-27.
Moe, Terry M. 1990. "The Politics of Structural Choice: Toward
a Theory of Public Bureaucracy." In Organization Theory: From
Chester Barnard to the Present and Beyond, ed. Oliver E. Williamson. New
York: Oxford University Press, 116-53.
--. 2005. "Power and Political Institutions."
Perspectives on Politics 3 (2): 215-33.
Moe, Terry M., and William Howell. 1999. "The Presidential
Power of Unilateral Action." Journal of Law, Economics and
Organizations 15 (1): 132-79.
Neustadt, Richard M. 1960. Presidential Power. New York: MacMillan.
Newlin, Eliza. 2002. "Right on the Money?" National
Journal, October 26.
Nordhaus, William D. 1975. "The Political Business
Cycle." Review of Economic Studies 42 (2): 169-90.
Patashnik, Eric M. (2008). Reforms at Risk: What Happens after
Major Policy Changes Are Enacted. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University
Press.
Piketty, Thomas, and Emmanuel Saez. 2003. "Income Inequality
in the United States." Quarterly Journal of Economics 118 (1): 1-39
(updated data available at http://elsa.berkeley.edu/~saez/
TabFig2008.xls [accessed December 16, 2011]).
--. 2007. "How Progressive Is the U.S. Federal Tax System: A
Historical and International Perspective." Journal of Economic
Perspectives 21 (1): 3-24.
Pierson, Paul. 2000. "Increasing Returns, Path Dependence, and
the Study of Politics." American Political Science Review 94 (2):
251-67.
Schwartz, Schwartz. 1989. "Why Parties?" Unpublished
manuscript, UCLA.
Sears, David O., and Jack Citrin. 1982. Tax Revolt: Something for
Nothing in California. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.
Shepsle, Kenneth A. 1992. "Congress Is a 'They,' Not
an 'It' Legislative Intent as Oxymoron." International
Review of Law and Economics 12 (2): 239-56.
Skowronek, Stephen. 1993. The Politics Presidents Make: Leadership
from John Adams to George Bush. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.
Stonecash, Jeffrey M., and Andrew E. Milstein. 2001. "Parties
and Taxes: The Emergence of Distributive Divisions, 1950-2000."
Paper presented at the Meeting of the Midwest Political Science
Association, Chicago.
Sundquist, James L. 1968. Politics and Policy: The Eisenhower,
Kennedy, and Johnson Years. Washington, D.: Brookings Institution.
Suskind, Ron. 2004. The Price of Loyalty: George @. Bush, the White
House, and the Education of Paul O'Neill. New York: Simon and
Schuster.
Teles, Steven. 2008. The Rise of the Conservative Legal Movement.
Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.
Theriault, Sean. 2008. Party Polarization in Congress. New York:
Cambridge University Press.
Van Houweling, Robert. 2003. "Legislators' Personal
Policy Preferences and Partisan Legislative Organization. Unpublished
manuscript, Harvard University, Cambridge, MA.
Vogel, David. 1989. Fluctuating Fortunes: The Political Power of
Business in America. New York: Basic Books.
Weatherford, M. Stephen. 2009. "Comparing President's
Economic Policy Leadership." Perspectives on Politics 7 (3):
537-60.
JACOB S. HACKER
Yale University
PAUL PIERSON
University of California, Berkeley
(1.) These basic statistics on inequality, drawn from the work of
Piketty and Saez (2003), are discussed in depth in Hacker and Pierson
(2010).
(2.) Indeed, a central message of Barrels' book that informs
our own perspective is that, given extremely limited knowledge and
unequal participation, voters (especially less affluent ones) have
serious difficulty holding politicians accountable for many of the
complex policy decisions that affect voters' economic standing.
(3.) For evidence of the attention to this claim, see, for example,
Leonhardt (2008); Isaac (2009); Campbell (2011).
(4.) This statistic is for pretax market income. The share
accounted for by the richest 1% would be even larger for posttax and
postbenefit income--as the CBO (2011) shows that taxes and transfers
were actually less redistributive in 2007 than they were in 1979.
(5.) One can see this by continuing with the analogy of putting
your foot on the gas or the brakes. It is much safer to accelerate the
car if your predecessor has had his foot on the brakes. If, instead, he
had his foot on the accelerator, your efforts to keep pushing down on
the gas are likely to lead to disaster.
(6.) This concept is related to, but distinct from, the concept of
a "long coalition" which Bawn et al. (2011) derive from
Schwartz (1989). For Bawn et al., "long coalitions'--the core
of political parties--entail an enduring log-roll among distinct
organized interests. Here we emphasize enduring groups focused on a
particular policy agenda. These groups may, in turn, be a component of a
broader "long coalition" or party.
(7.) We argue elsewhere that this is a central reason polarization
has been asymmetric between the parties--that is to say, it is mostly a
phenomenon of the Republicans moving to the right. Despite a rapidly
expanding literature on polarization, this asymmetry has been noted but
little discussed (cf. Carmines 2011), probably because it is so
difficult to reconcile with the median voter frameworks that predominate
in discussions of American politics.
(8.) An alternative account would argue that tax outcomes reflect
responsiveness to public opinion regarding taxation. Indeed, an account
that stresses the role of groups and "intense demanders" rests
in part on a claim that voters possess a "blind spot" that
makes their efforts to discipline politicians less than fully effective
(Bawn et al. 2011; Arnold 1990). Due to space constraints, we do not
develop this claim with respect to taxation here, but we have elsewhere
(Hacker and Pierson 2005, 2007, 2010). For additional evidence of the
permissiveness of public opinion see Barrels (2008).
(9.) A second group, the Club for Growth, has played an important
complementary role in bringing discipline and focus to Republican policy
makers. Amply funded, with much of its support coming from Wall Street,
the Club for Growth has focused on funding pro-tax cut Republicans,
including ones taking on moderate GOP incumbents. On the Club for
Growth, see Hacker and Pierson (2007).
(10.) Again, it was the violation of such a promise that
precipitated George H. W. Bush's debacle in 1990. After meeting
with Norquist, his son (along with every other Republican contender)
signed a pledge in writing early in the 2000 presidential campaign.
(11.) All of these issues are explored in much more depth in Hacker
and Pierson (2005).
(12.) These "paygo" rules were technically in effect in
2002, but Republican leaders had weakened them in prior years, and given
the overall budget surplus at the time, they posed little constraint on
the 2001 package. (They lapsed at the end of 2002 and were not
reinstated until Democrats recaptured Congress in 2006, so they were
irrelevant to the 2003 cuts.) The same was not true of the use of the
reconciliation process. Under the so-called Byrd Rule that governs
reconciliation, all spending and revenue changes beyond the period of
time covered by the budget--in this case 10 years--must be fully funded;
otherwise, they are vulnerable to a Senate filibuster. Some prominent
Republicans have argued that the Byrd Rule made the sunsets in the law
inevitable. Yet Republicans could have specified offsetting receipts to
fund the tax cut; the Byrd rule was only an issue because of the
commitment to tax cuts without any offsets at any point in the ten-year
window. Moreover, the Byrd Rule does not explain why the sunsets took
effect in 2010, a year before the close of the 10-year budget window.
That provision can only be explained with reference to Republicans'
efforts--revealed in a variety of design choices in addition to the
sunsets--to disguise the true size and distribution of the tax cuts.
Finally, the Byrd Rule cannot explain the other peculiar features of the
cuts, such as their back loading of top-end cuts.
Jacob S. Hacker is the Stanley B. Resor Professor of Political
Science at Yale University and the Director of Yale' s Institution
for Social and Policy Studies. He is the author or coauthor of five
books, most recently, Winner-Take-All Politics with Paul Pierson.
Paul Pierson is John D. Gross Professor of Political Science at the
University of California at Berkeley. His work focuses on political
economy and public policy, both in the United States and in other
affluent democracies.
TABLE 1
Summary of Major Deficit-Reduction Packages Enacted Since 1982
Change in deficit
over 5 yrs, as a
Package Period percent of GDP
Tax Equity and Fiscal Responsibility 1983-1987 -1.3%
Act of 1982 (TEFRA)
Deficit Reduction Act of 1984 1985-1989 -0.5%
1987 budget summit 1988-1992 -0.7%
Omnibus Budget Reconciliation Act 1991-1995 -1.4%
(OBRA) of 1990/budget summit
OBRA 1993 1994-1998 -1.2%
Balanced Budget Act of 1997 and 1998-2002 -0.2%
Taxpayer Relief Act of 1997
Budget Control Act of 2011 2012-2016 -0.3%
Revenue changes,
as a percent of
Package total package
Tax Equity and Fiscal Responsibility 75%
Act of 1982 (TEFRA)
Deficit Reduction Act of 1984 82%
1987 budget summit 39%
Omnibus Budget Reconciliation Act 33%
(OBRA) of 1990/budget summit
OBRA 1993 56%
Balanced Budget Act of 1997 and -68%
Taxpayer Relief Act of 1997
Budget Control Act of 2011 0%
Number of GOP
votes on final Party of
Package passage the President
Tax Equity and Fiscal Responsibility 103 (H) 43 (S) Republican
Act of 1982 (TEFRA)
Deficit Reduction Act of 1984 76 (H) 45 (S) Republican
1987 budget summit 44 (H) 18 (S) Republican
Omnibus Budget Reconciliation Act 10 (H) 23 (S) Republican
(OBRA) of 1990/budget summit
OBRA 1993 0 (H) 0 (S) Democrat
Balanced Budget Act of 1997 and 218 (H) 51 (S) Democrat
Taxpayer Relief Act of 1997
Budget Control Act of 2011 174 (H) 28 (S) Democrat
Source: Vote tallies are from recorded votes, available at
http://www.thomas.loc.gov and http://www.govtrack.us. The 1987 budget
summit was embodied primarily in two laws: the continuing
resolution of appropriations (Public Law 100.202) and the Omnibus
Budget Reconciliation Act of 1987; the vote information is for
the latter. For the 1993 budget deal, the vote is for the Balanced
Budget Act. Details on the budget deals are from Center on Budget
and Policy Priorities based on data from Congressional Budget
Office (CBO) and U.S. Department of Treasury. Changes in revenues,
outlays, and deficits are expressed as a percent of GDP to enable
better comparability across time. Those changes indicate the size
of the package; the "composition" indicates its mix. For TEFRA,
year-by-year numbers are unavailable; however, CBO's September
1982 report suggests that non-interest outlay savings in two
measures (TEFRA and a separate reconciliation bill) were about
one-third as big as TEFRA's revenue increases. That 1982
breakdown is used to represent the composition of the
package as a whole. Several major packages are omitted
because of a lack of data. For further details, see
http://www.cbpp.org/cms/index.cfm?fa=view&id=3617.