The contemporary presidency: the personnel process in the modern presidency.
Lewis, David E.
During a presidential election year, public attention naturally
turns toward candidates and campaigns. Newscasters and media experts
dissect polls and campaign strategy. The best prepared candidates,
however, are thinking beyond voting day toward postelection planning.
The immensity of transition planning requires that responsible
presidential campaigns begin planning months and even more than a year
in advance. Governor George W. Bush began planning for a transition to
the presidency in April 1999, well before he had even secured a vote to
become his party's nominee, much less president of the United
States. Presidential candidates do the planning out of sight from the
campaign and the press. If word leaks out about postelection planning,
this can create uncertainty and division among the candidate's
campaign staff and appear presumptuous to voters. Yet candidates who
refuse to plan cannot make up for it in the short period between
Election Day and inauguration.
The task of transitioning to become president is enormous (Burke
2000, 2004; Patterson and Pfiffner 2001; Pfiffner 1996). On the
personnel side, the president must fill 3,000 to 4,000 positions in the
federal executive establishment (Lewis 2008; Patterson 2008; Patterson
and Pfiffner 2001; Pfiffner 1996). One-quarter of these posts require
Senate confirmation, which adds a layer of complexity to their
selection. (1) Presidents do so under time constraints and tremendous
scrutiny from supporters, Congress, and the press.
The stakes in these decisions are high. Missteps in early
appointments distract from the president's priorities and can leave
the president significantly understaffed in key policy areas. For
example, President Obama's nomination of former Senate Majority
Leader Tom Daschle to head the Department of Health and Human Services
foundered on revelations about Daschle's tax problems, hindering
the president's work on health care reform. The president was also
slow to fill vacancies in the Treasury Department, where Secretary
Timothy Geithner was the only confirmed nominee during the crucial early
period after the nomination. (2) Missteps in these early appointments
contribute to the Washington community's first impressions of the
president. The willingness of Washington insiders to bend to the
president's wishes depends upon insiders' assessment of
whether going along with the president will cost them more than it gains
them. A president who bungles appointments early in his presidency sends
the signal that supporting the president is risky. Early missteps are
also a distraction since media stories focus on these issues rather than
the president's policy priorities. If presidents lose control of
the news cycle, it is hard for the president to refocus the
nation's attention on their policy agenda.
Ultimately, given the substantial authority delegated to government
executives in areas such as the environment, health, and foreign policy,
these appointments can have a significant influence on policy outputs
(Moe 1982, 1985; Randall 1979; Stewart and Cromartie 1982; Wood 1990;
Wood and Anderson 1993; Wood and Waterman 1991, 1994). Picking the right
persons for key appointed jobs can lead to huge policy changes that have
dramatic consequences for voters and key stakeholders. It is hard to
imagine any assessment of President Obama's first term divorced
from the actions, advice, and infighting of his economic team (Suskind
2011). Similarly, President George W. Bush's ultimate legacy is
determined in part by the actions of appointees such as Donald Rumsfeld,
Paul Wolfowitz, and Douglas Feith at the Department of Defense, and
Michael Brown at the Federal Emergency Management Agency (Cooper and
Block 2007; Woodward 2002).
Presidents tackle their personnel responsibilities differently.
They prioritize different positions and display different levels of
personal involvement. Yet, all presidents face broadly similar concerns
and incentives, to manage the federal executive establishment and use
the pool of available jobs to achieve policy and political goals. They
accomplish the latter often through the shrewd use of appointments as a
form of political currency (Heclo 1977; Lewis 2008; Mackenzie 1981;
Newland 1987; Pfiffner 1996; Tolchin and Tolchin 1971, 2010).
In this article, I review the current state of presidential
personnel politics, borrowing heavily from earlier published work. I
review how modern presidents face similar choices but also how the
environment confronting presidents has been changing. I describe the
causes of an increase in the number and penetration of appointees and
how presidents have asserted more control of personnel selection, aided
by an augmented White House personnel operation. The article describes a
relatively stable number of appointees since 1980 and suggests that one
reason for the stability is concerns for management performance. I
conclude by making suggestions for reforming the personnel system
equally applicable to either party's candidate for the presidency
in 2012.
Presidents and Personnel
When President Obama was campaigning for the presidency in 2008, he
regularly criticized the incumbent president for his expansive use of
executive power. Once in office, however, President Obama's views
on executive power changed. (3) Notable among his actions were his
continued use of signing statements and his use of executive orders.
During the year preceding the presidential election, President Obama
made significant policy changes in education, student loans, mortgage
repayment, and prescription drugs as part of his "we can't
wait campaign" to work around an unsympathetic Congress. (4) In
personnel, the president appointed big donors to key ambassadorial
posts, a practiced he criticized in 2007. The president also asserted
new power to name recess appointees during a period when Congress did
not believe it was in recess. (5)
President Obama's transformation is not surprising to
presidency scholars. Presidents have a dramatically different vantage
point and incentives than they did as legislators or candidates.
Presidents are held accountable by voters for the functioning of the
entire government and, confronted with these high expectations,
presidents naturally grasp for the power that will enable them to meet
these expectations. In the executive branch, presidents are held
responsible for the policy choices and performance of between 2 and 3
million civilian employees working in 15 cabinet departments and 55 to
60 independent agencies. Presidents respond to this awesome
responsibility by using their power over the number and types of
appointees to control agency activities.
Of course, presidents try and meet public expectations through
other means as well. For example, they propose legislation, make public
appeals, and direct foreign policy. However, the successful pursuit of
these activities also involves presidential personnel. Appointments are
an important political resource that presidents use in working with
interest groups, the political party, and key members of Congress (Heclo
1977; Mackenzie 1981; Tolchin and Tolchin 1971, 2010; Weko 1995).
Presidents try to satisfy key groups through naming prominent members to
administration posts. They use patronage to reward party members for
work on the campaign and to unite party factions. Members of Congress
ask the president to name their favorites to administration jobs, and
presidents use the giving and withholding of jobs to ease the passage of
their favored legislation. More generally, presidents know that publicly
rewarding administration supporters with jobs encourages further work
for the party or president.
While all modern presidents, by virtue of their institutional
position, share similar incentives with regard to personnel, their
decision-making environment has changed over time, partly as a result of
the actions of previous presidents (Moe 1985). Past presidential choices
influence the resources and rules confronting successive presidents, and
presidents learn from the mistakes and successes of their predecessors.
(6) Of particular note in the last half century, presidents have sought
an increase in the number and penetration of appointees in the federal
executive establishment, and they have played a larger role in the
selection of appointees, aided by an increasingly sophisticated White
House personnel operation.
Increases in Appointees
Since the publication of the Plum Book in 1960, the number of
appointed positions has almost doubled both in total numbers and as a
percentage of federal civilian employees (Figure 1). Presidents, with
the cooperation of Congress, have increased the number of appointees.
Some of the increase is the natural result of an increase in the number
of federal programs and agencies (Light 1995). When Congress creates new
programs or agencies, they create new Senate-confirmed positions to
manage these endeavors.
A significant source of the increase in appointees, however, is the
desire of presidents to secure more control of the policy-making process
within federal agencies. As the federal government has grown in size,
scope, and complexity, Congress has delegated increasing amounts of
policy-making authority to federal agencies. Presidents naturally have
sought more control over the policy-making apparatus. One particular
focus of presidents has been the agencies that control the levers of
presidential governance (Lewis and Moe 2009). They have increased the
number and penetration of appointees most significantly in agencies
responsible for budgets, personnel, and regulatory review. Between 1960
and 2008, the number of appointees in the Bureau of the Budget/Office of
Management and Budget (budgets, regulatory review) increased from 11 to
37 appointees, while the number of appointees in the Civil Service
Commission/ Office of Personnel Management increased from 3 to 30. The
effect of this can be seen most clearly in Figure 2, which graphs the
dramatic changes in the Civil Service Commission between 1978 and 1984
when it was reorganized into the Office of Personnel Management as part
of the Civil Service Reform Act of 1978. The increase in appointees
extended down much deeper into the personnel agency's hierarchy,
leading to significant turnover in the career ranks and facilitating a
dramatic change in the civil service system itself.
[FIGURE 1 OMITTED]
More generally, the largest increases in appointees in the last 50
years have come during periods of unified party control and after party
changes in the White House (Figure 3). In 1978, for example, at the
Democratic President Jimmy Carter's request, the Democratic
Congress created the Senior Executive Service, a flexible corps of
high-level managers, 10% of whom could be appointees. This contributed
to an increase of close to 1,000 appointees in the federal service
compared to 1976. (7) Generally, Congress is more sanguine about an
increase in appointments during periods when a president from the
majority's party is in the White House. Formally, Congress must
create all new positions requiring Senate confirmation. Presidents have
more discretion over the number of appointees in the Senior Executive
Service and the number of lower-level Schedule C appointees, but their
discretion is limited by Congress. When Congress and the president share
the same views about policy, Congress tends to support efforts to
increase the number of appointees in order to bring policy in line with
what the president and majority prefer. An increase in appointees also
can provide members of Congress exciting new patronage opportunities or
increased control over policymaking themselves (Rottinghaus and Bergan
2011).
[FIGURE 2 OMITTED]
[FIGURE 3 OMITTED]
Every time a Republican replaces a Democrat or a Democrat replaces
a Republican in the White House, the new president seeks to assert
control of the continuing government and redirect agency activities
often through the addition of new appointed positions. Republicans and
Democrats often target different agencies. President target agencies
that carry out policies they do not like or whose employees have
different political views. So, for example, President Ronald Reagan
targeted environmental and social welfare agencies while President Bill
Clinton targeted the Department of Commerce (Durant 1992; Durant and
Resh 2009; Lewis 2008).
Once new positions are created, they often persist. Each new
administration uses the previous administration's map of appointees
as a starting point for their own staffing. New presidents are reluctant
to give up appointed positions because they hold out the promise of
helping them secure control of agency policy making but also provide a
means of satisfying the immense demand for jobs in the new
administration. New administrations also do not have the time or
capacity to review existing positions to determine where appointees are
helpful and improve both responsiveness and management and where their
elimination would cost nothing more than the loss of patronage
possibilities. The result is an irregular but noticeable increase in the
total number of appointees.
Of course, a certain amount of the increase stems from the
president's desire to find jobs for the thousands of supporters,
volunteers, campaign workers, and others for jobs in the administration.
For example, one of the key motivations for President Dwight
Eisenhower's creation of a new class of appointees, Schedule C
appointees, was the Republican Party's desire for jobs (Van Riper
1958). While Eisenhower was concerned about securing control over a
bureaucracy that had been largely built and staffed by New Deal
Democrats for 20 years, it was also the case that Republicans were
hungry for federal jobs after having been out of power for 20 years.
Currently, there are approximately 1,500 Schedule C appointments. A
significant portion of these positions are filled as a form of political
exchange rather than fitness for office. Presidents reward campaign
personnel, surrogates, and donors with jobs because it is an inducement
for future work for the president in the next campaign. More generally,
when presidents publicly reward those that have sided with the
president, this encourages other political actors to side with the
president in other contexts.
Changing Presidential Role in Selecting Appointees
Up until the passage of the Pendleton Act (1883), the United States
had an all-appointee personnel system. The fact that federal employees
were at-will employees does not imply that presidents selected them. On
the contrary, presidents were beholden to parties for their nomination
and their election. Parties parceled out control over appointments to
different factions within the party after the election, with factions
often given explicit control over a specific subset of nominations
either by agency or region. The distribution of federal jobs was
carefully orchestrated by parties and governed by understandings between
the president, party, and members of Congress. Up through the Eisenhower
administration, it was common for the national party to set up offices
close to the White House to manage the flow of requests for jobs in the
new administration.
Aided by a growing White House staff and increasingly independent
campaign organizations, presidents at mid-century began to assume
greater control over personnel selection at the expense of the national
parties, department heads, and members of Congress. Presidents developed
the capacity to play a larger role in the selection of personnel.
President Harry Truman was the first president to have a staff member
specifically assigned to handle presidential personnel. The Kennedy
administration employed a three-person personnel staff to help fill
1,500 to 2,000 positions. This staff grew to 25 persons by the Nixon
administration and presidents since Reagan can employ over 100 persons
during a presidential transition. Since the Nixon administration,
presidents have regularly included professional recruiters in their
personnel offices, and the process for selecting appointees has become
regularized and increasingly institutionalized. Nomination and selection
is increasingly governed by defined processes, a clear division of
labor, and sophisticated computer systems to handle the resumes from job
applicants.
Each president begins by prioritizing certain positions to fill
early. These positions usually include key White House positions, top
executive branch positions (e.g., cabinet), positions critical for the
fulfillment of the president's agenda, and positions dealing with
hot button issues. John Kennedy's personnel aide Larry O'Brien
described that administration's thinking in the following way,
"If we can get control of the top 600 or 400 or 300 jobs, if we can
only get this, get these people properly placed, then we will have some
degree of control" (Lewis 2008, 27). One Carter personnel aide
talked about the efficacy of filling the "choke" points in
government first (Lewis 2011). Pendleton James, director of the
Presidential Personnel Office (PPO) during the Reagan administration
describes how the Reagan administration focused first on the "key
87" positions, which importantly included those essential for
Reagan's economic policy (Lewis 2008, 28).
Presidential reach is also extending. While modern presidents were
always involved in the selection of top agency officials, the selection
of lower-level appointees was often left to department heads or other
party or political officials. During his first term, President Richard
Nixon let cabinet secretaries select their subordinates and famously
sought to regain control over the selection of lower-level appointees in
his second term (Nathan 1975). President Carter followed a similar
pattern during his only term in office (Pfiffner 1996). He initially
promised cabinet secretaries control over the selection of lower-level
appointees only to try and retake control half way through his term when
he realized that many of the appointees selected were damaging his
efforts to get policy change both in the agencies and Congress.
Presidents since Reagan have sought with varying degrees of success to
assert control over all appointees in the executive establishment.
According to one personnel official in the Clinton administration, each
agency head was told "These positions are Bill Clinton's, and
he appoints them--the Senate-confirmed positions, the non-career SES
positions, and the Schedule C positions--he selects them" (Lewis
2008, 24).
Increased responsibility for filling positions and matching job
requesters to jobs has led PPO offices to regularize their processes.
Presidents confront two general tasks, filling key positions for policy
making and responding to requests for jobs in the administration. In
some cases, the right person for a job has applied for the job in a
formal or informal way. In other cases, the appropriate persons have to
be sought out by the PPO. One of the most difficult tasks is dealing
with persons seeking an administration position who have a political
claim for a job because of work for the campaign or a connection to a
key political official. Recent administrations have tended to divide up
these two distinct tasks--filling positions vs. finding jobs for
applicants--into separate offices within PPO. The latter have names like
the Office of Priority Placement. These two processes can work in
parallel, only occasionally intersecting, since the process of filling a
key policy-making position is quite different from finding a job for
someone from the campaign. The former is focused on the position and the
latter is focused on the person. The PPO puts processes in place to make
sure the candidate has had the appropriate background checks and been
vetted politically. During this process recent presidents have used a
system of White House liaisons in the departments and agencies to
communicate with the PPO about vacancies, recommend persons to fill
vacant positions, and relay departmental objections to White House
recommendations for vacant positions. These offices are also a way of
keeping agency appointees connected to the views and priorities of the
White House. In practice, top agency officials and the White House
usually work cooperatively to fill lower-level appointee positions. The
White House has recommendations, and the agency has recommendations,
with each exercising a veto. In cases of disagreement, higher-level
White House officials are introduced to resolve the disagreement.
The increasing capacity of the PPO and the sophistication of its
operation has allowed presidents a greater chance of accomplishing their
policy and political goals through personnel. Presidents take a number
of different factors into account in personnel selection including
loyalty, competence, patronage (i.e., distributing jobs to persons
recommended by the party, campaign, donor, Congress), diversity
(geographic, demographic), and senatorial preferences. Given the
importance of personnel selections for the control over agency policy
making, presidents have paid a significant amount of attention to the
loyalty and competence of their nominees (Edwards 2001; Moe 1985; Weko
1995). As one director of PPO explained, "this is not a beauty
contest. The goal is to pick the person who has the greatest chance of
accomplishing what the principal wants done ... After the strongest
candidate (s) has been identified, assess the political wisdom of the
selection, and adjust accordingly" (Lewis 2008, 27). The increased
capacity of the PPO allows presidents to be better able to select
persons who are loyal, competent, and to assess the political wisdom of
the candidates.
Of course, the pool of loyal and competent persons who are also
politically connected in useful ways is limited. Presidents must
regularly choose candidates that are not ideal on one dimension or
another. Presidents have been most inclined to place those with both
loyalty and competence in the agencies central to their policy-making
agenda or agencies that are unlikely to carry out the president's
wishes without direct and effective supervision. Presidents are more
likely to choose persons selected for campaign work or political
connections in agencies less central to their agenda and agencies that
naturally share the president's policy priorities.
Appointees and Control of the Federal Executive Establishment
One of the interesting features of the counts of the number of
political appointees in Figure 1 is that the number actually peaks in
1980. This raises the interesting question of why this number has not
increased since 1980. The number of appointees has been relatively
stable since 1980 with small increases or decreases depending upon the
whether there has been a party change in the White House or unified
government. There are a number of explanations for this pattern. First,
Congress has constrained presidential efforts to increase the number of
appointees. During this time period, there have only been a few years of
unified party control. This makes it difficult for presidents to
increase the overall number of appointees. For example, in 1987
Democratic members of Congress accused the Reagan administration of
"packing" the top ranks of government with appointees (Lewis
2008, 42). Similarly, during the Clinton administration, Republicans
accused the president and his commerce secretary of politicizing the
department by increasing the number of appointees. (8) Even in the
absence of explicit congressional criticism, presidents worry about how
their efforts to increase appointees will be perceived by Congress and
the public. The chances that Congress objects to presidential actions to
increase the number of appointees only increases as Congress becomes
more polarized.
As a practical matter, filling all of the positions and keeping
them filled is also a burdensome and politically fraught process. It is
a significant management challenge for any president. For example, after
18 months, President Obama had filled only 79% of the key
Senate-confirmed positions in his administration (Lewis 2011). Some of
the initial vacancies remained in positions that were tainted by scandal
or were politically contentious, but others were simply low-priority
positions for the president such as under- and assistant secretaries for
administration and management, inspectors general (including two in the
Treasury Department), and chief financial officers in the larger
agencies. Like other presidents, President Obama was also slow to fill
positions in smaller independent boards and commissions.
It is difficult to determine whether the overall delay was due to
the Senate's obstructionism or the president's slowness. Both
likely play a role. The president confronted obstruction in the Senate
from his own party and the minority party. Senators from each party used
holds on presidential nominees to force action by the president on
issues unrelated to the nominees themselves. For example, Senator Mary
Landrieu (D-LA) objected to the nomination of Jacob Lew to be director
Office of Management and Budget. She placed a hold on his nomination to
protest the administration's moratorium on oil extraction in the
Gulf. (9) Similarly, Robert Menendez (D-NJ) placed holds on Obama's
nominees to lead two science agencies because of policy disagreement
about Cuba. (10) On the Republican side, Senator Richard Shelby (R-AL)
placed a hold on scores of nominees as a means of drawing attention to
his concerns about contract and funding for his home state. (11)
The minority party also steadfastly refused to confirm some
objectionable nominees, leading the president to controversially use and
extend the recess appointment power. Of course, the president put in
place the most restrictive ethics requirements of any new president, and
his White House spent significant time vetting potential nominees. (12)
The vetting by the White House and Congress was lengthy, repetitive, and
invasive, and deterred many candidates from serving (Burke 2009;
Sullivan 2009). Of course, the president's aggressive vetting and
deliberate pace may be indirectly related to Senate obstructionism. If
the president anticipates trouble, he has a strong incentive to select
nominees carefully to avoid Senate objections and public embarrassment.
A final reason presidents have been hesitant to increase the number
of appointees further is concerns for performance. While presidents
prefer more appointees than Congress or a fully informed American public
would prefer, presidents are also constrained by concerns for
competence. Even during the height of the spoils period when each new
president generated dramatic turnover in the federal service, new
presidents kept some long-serving clerks in the large departments simply
because these departments could not run without the collective expertise
and institutional knowledge of these persons. Large departments often
would have a carryover clerk and a party clerk (White 1954). Similarly,
modern presidents will make adjustments to the number of appointees but
are constrained by the effect their choices will have on the competence
of the agencies they politicize (Lewis 2008; Maranto 1998, 2001; Moe
1985).
Presidents have witnessed, through painful experience, and scholars
have demonstrated systematically how the increase in the number and
penetration of appointees has had deleterious consequences for federal
agency performance. This can be seen in dramatic cases such as the
Federal Emergency Management Agency's response to Hurricane Katrina
and Iraq Reconstruction. In the aftermath of these crises, the president
reduced the number of appointees and the types of persons selected to
fill the remaining appointed positions. For example, in the aftermath of
Hurricane Katrina, President Bush named R. David Paulison to head the
agency. Paulison was a career firefighter with previous experience
within the agency directing emergency preparedness. President Obama
chose another career emergency manager, W. Craig Fugate to run the
agency. Systematic scholarly studies of the relationship between
appointees and management performance also describe the impact of
appointees on federal management performance (see, e.g., Gallo and Lewis
2012; Lewis 2008).
Management Performance
Management teams in all federal agencies are comprised of a mix of
appointees and career executives. Most scholars agree that an
appropriate mix of these two populations is best for performance, since
each brings different benefits to agency management (see, e.g., Bok
2003; Dunn 1997; Golden 2000; Heclo 1977; Krause, Lewis, and Douglas
2006; Suleiman 2003). Appointees play a vital role, since they provide
electoral accountability. The possibility of presidential removal makes
appointees more responsive than their careerist counterparts. Careerists
are protected from removal by procedural rights and appeals as well as
connections to key patrons and stakeholders. Appointees' close
connections to administration officials and partisans in Congress
provide them a unique perspective on agency tasks and relationships that
can facilitate the provision of budgets and necessary political support
for agency programs. Appointees are more likely to see the world through
the eyes of elected stakeholders like the president and can bring
energy, responsiveness, and risk taking into agency decision making in a
way that can improve performance (see, e.g., Bok 2003; Maranto 1998,
2001, 2005; Moe 1985). Since appointees are by nature short timers, they
are more likely to focus on a limited number of definable goals and feel
pressure to demonstrate progress on these goals.
Whatever advantage appointees may have in human capital, they often
lack the subject area background or public management qualifications of
their careerist counterparts. (13) Careerists are more likely to have
program and policy expertise derived from agency work experience and
long tenures managing or helping manage federal programs (see, e.g.,
Cohen 1998; Heclo 1975, 1977; Kaufman 1965; National Commission on the
Public Service 1989, 2003; Suleiman 2003). Careerists are more likely to
have public management experience in the federal government and agency
they work in. They understand the difference between public and private
management and are used to managing large public organizations with
thousands of employees and large budgets. They have a better
understanding of the rhythms of public sector work, informal networks,
and the arcane realities of public agency management. Their long
familiarity with the agency and its budgets and process helps them
manage programs better and interface more effectively with outside
stakeholders and inside partners.
Even if appointees have the background and qualifications to manage
federal programs well, their presence down at the program management
level can be harmful to government performance. There are hidden costs
to politicization. The first hidden cost is increased management
turnover and persistent vacancies in federal management (Dull and
Roberts 2009; Heclo 1977; O'Connell 2009). Once key management
positions are filled by appointees, they stay that way in future
administrations. This means management positions filled by appointees
experience systematically higher rates of turnover on average than
management positions filled by careerists. While the average chief
executive officer in the private sector stays five to seven years, the
average tenure of an appointee varies by level but is usually about 2.5
years.
Regular turnover in management positions at this level has
corrosive effects on management performance (Boylan 2004; Heclo 1977).
Two years is about long enough to start new initiatives and begin to see
them implemented but not long enough to see them fully carried out. This
makes it hard for appointees to credibly commit to reform. The regular
turnover of appointees often follows this pattern of new priorities, new
initiatives, and short tenures--so much so that careerists begin to
naturally resist appointee management. One Department of Defense
civilian with government experience described it this way: "We
start, we stop, we reverse, but we seldom move ahead for any period of
time. One loses interest after a few years." (14) Long-serving
careerists believe that their efforts implementing appointee initiatives
may well be wasted. This makes them naturally cautious.
The second related cost is that, even if appointees have the
appropriate qualifications to manage federal programs, they are
systematically more attentive to political and short-term considerations
to the detriment of long-term program and agency management. The
penetration of appointees deeper into agency hierarchies presses
political concerns down into agency decisions in a way that may be
problematic. For example, recent work by John Hudak (2012) demonstrates
that the distribution of federal discretionary grants is importantly
influenced by electoral geography and timing. Swing states receive a
greater number of grants and a greater amount of total grant dollars
than other states, and this is particularly the case during the run up
to a presidential election.
Appointees are and perceived to be short timers and naturally focus
accomplishing a limited set of finite goals. This is beneficial for
forcing agency activity but can be problematic for agency management
since this myopic focus systematically reduces the incentive of agency
managers to engage in long-term planning. Political appointees will
often be out of office when the benefits of long-term planning are
realized. Unfortunately, many problems require long-term planning and
vision rather than the accomplishment of visible short-term goals.
Persistent vacancies in agency management positions, such as under and
assistant secretaries for management, is an example of this problem,
since presidents see these positions as ones that can be filled last or
leave vacant the longest. Appointees with short time horizons also have
fewer incentives to deal with large but distant problems.
The final hidden cost is the effect increasing numbers of appointed
positions have on efforts to recruit and retain the best talent in the
civil service (Bertelli and Lewis n.d.; Gailmard and Patty 2007; Lewis
2008). If increasing numbers of the top agency jobs are filled regularly
by appointees, this means that there are fewer jobs with the highest pay
and greatest levels of responsibility available to career professionals.
This influences the ability of the agency to retain top career
professionals or induce the best and brightest workers into agency work.
Agency employees can project forward in their careers. When talented
employees see that they will never be able to rise to the most important
and consequential positions, the chances they want to stay in the agency
diminish. Federal pay is not sufficient, and it cannot be made up for by
meaningful influence over agency decisions when agencies are top heavy
with political appointees. The increasing penetration of appointees
makes it difficult to motivate civil servants to work hard and
creatively to accomplish the agency's mission. When agency
professionals exert effort to develop plans and work creatively to solve
problems only to have their plans repeatedly turned down or their work
discarded, this reduces their incentive to do this work in the first
place. Similarly, if this work leads to no more access, power, or pay,
there are fewer incentives to do this work, and it is absolutely
important for agency performance.
Collectively, programs administered by appointees or located in
federal agencies where management teams comprised of high percentages of
appointees have performed worse in large-N evaluations of agency
performance. For example, appointee-run programs got systematically
lower Program Assessment Rating Tool (management grades) scores during
the Bush administration, particularly when programs are run by
appointees from the campaign (Gallo and Lewis 2012; Gilmour and Lewis
2006). Federal employees working in agencies with high percentages of
appointees in the management team were less likely to report the
presence of leadership, good management practices, and work satisfaction
in their agencies (Lewis 2008). Federal agencies with high percentages
of appointees were also the slowest to respond to citizen requests for
information and the most likely to claim exemptions from those requests
(Lewis and Wood n.d.).
This is not to suggest that appointee management is necessarily
worse. On the contrary, there are extraordinarily competent and
conscientious appointees. The chances, however, that a program or agency
gets several of these in a row are much lower, and the simple fact of
their regular turnover and different priorities can damage management
performance. The best evidence suggests that an appropriate mix of
appointees and careerists is best for management. Some agencies already
have an appropriate mix. Other agencies have far too many appointees for
optimal management performance. The unique history of the U.S. personnel
system, presidential and legislative desires to give out patronage, and
repeated efforts by Republican and Democratic presidents to get control
of administrative agencies implementing key policies has created a
situation where the United States has dramatically more appointees than
most other developed democracies.
Conclusion
With any luck, both presidential campaigns will have engaged in
serious postelection planning prior to the publication of this article.
The task, of course, will be easier for President Obama if he is
reelected. He already has staffed his administration and has a personnel
operation in place and running smoothly. Governor Mitt Romney will have
to bring his personnel operation up to speed quickly and begin to staff
his administration if he is elected. Both candidates are likely to
confront a sharply divided Congress that will make securing major
legislative accomplishments difficult without supermajorities.
One area where the new president may be able to get some traction
is in good governance legislation, including common sense appointment
reforms. Smart legislation is already circulating in Congress that
includes reasonable provisions such as reducing the number of appointed
positions requiring Senate confirmation, streamlining the forms nominees
must fill out for the president and the Senate, and making background
checks less extensive for previously confirmed nominees. Presidents will
also be given a lot of good appointment advice such as to take a close
look at career professionals for open appointed positions, work hard to
guide new nominees through the confirmation process, and orient them to
their new jobs once they get confirmed.
The new president should also consider taking action to reduce the
number of political appointees. Many former presidential personnel
officials state openly that the president does not need 3,000 to 4,000
positions to manage the executive branch. Of course, efforts to cut
appointed positions must be done judiciously and with our eyes open to
the ways cutting appointees could limit the president's power to
distribute jobs for political gain. Presidents are naturally concerned
that a reduction in appointees could influence their ability to
negotiate, bargain, hold the party together, and induce future work for
the campaign and party. Yet most experienced personnel officials will
tell you that for every one job given out, you create 10 unhappy
applicants. Most of the jobs given out in patronage fashion are
lower-prestige and lower-pay jobs that do not provide the president much
political benefit in any case.
There are three specific ways the new presidents and Congress
should look to cut. First, presidents should look to reduce the number
of Senate-confirmed positions in a limited way in the cabinet and more
aggressively in the smaller departments and agencies. (15) More
specifically, the president can target specific types of
Senate-confirmed positions to cut: management positions and part-time,
commission, and advisory posts. An obvious place to begin is with under-
and assistant secretaries for management, chief financial officers, and
inspectors general, which are some of the most persistently vacant
Senate confirmed positions. Such positions are ideally suited for long
timers, persons oriented to care about long-term planning and the
agency's health. Presidents could fill these posts with career
members of the Senior Executive Service whose long experience in the
federal government would be valuable but over whom the president still
retains substantial control. Cuts in part-time, commission, and advisory
posts (which often require Senate confirmation) would not directly help
performance in the larger agencies, but cutting such positions would
make the immensity of the personnel task easier for the PPO and reduce
the burden on the Senate to let both parties focus on the nominees for
the key policymaking positions.
Second, efforts to cut appointees of all types should look to the
program or bureau level. The best empirical evidence suggests that the
deleterious effects of appointee management exist at the program level,
and appointee-run programs do worse than their careerist counterparts
managing comparable programs. Placing career executives in program
management roles will induce career executives to stay and build careers
in the federal service without sacrificing political accountability,
since presidential appointees managing agencies and bureaus will
continue to oversee the careerists managing federal programs.
Third, policy makers should consider cuts in Schedule C positions
after the election. Presidents since Ford have functioned with as many
as 1,700 and as few as 1,000 Schedule C appointees in similarly sized
executive branches. Schedule C positions are for persons serving in
policy and supporting positions but usually in a staff role. Persons
appointed in these positions have little formal authority and can accrue
substantial informal authority. Some of the difficulties in the past
administration with appointees stemmed from personnel in Schedule C
positions. Comparable positions to those filled by appointees in
Schedule C positions are filled by careerists in different agencies with
little apparent influence on responsiveness.
The new presidents could pursue legislation to secure these
reductions. There are several possible ways of accomplishing this such
as changing the appointment authority of certain positions or setting
caps for each agency. For example, Congress has frequently included a
limitation rider in the Department of Transportation appropriations,
which said, "none of these appropriations shall be used to pay for
more than 108 appointees." In the legislation creating the
Department of Homeland Security, Congress authorized a set number of
assistant secretaries, requiring Senate confirmation only for a portion
them. Congress also did not specify that many positions in the agency
would require Senate confirmation. The president has some discretion in
determining which positions require Senate confirmation. Both methods
allow the administration to prioritize where to place appointees while
still cutting their numbers. Short of new legislation, the president
could also pursue this strategy unilaterally by refusing to create
Schedule C positions, deciding not to name noncareer appointees to the
Senior Executive Service, and nominating career professionals to
Senate-confirmed positions.
Ultimately, presidents are reluctant to give up appointed positions
since having that flexibility allows presidents to both influence policy
and satisfy patronage demands. Short of another crisis like Katrina or
scandal like the politicization of the Department of Justice during the
Bush years, the chances for a concerted effort to reduce appointees
rests on electing a president willing to make difficult cuts.
AUTHOR'S NOTE: I thank Jim Pfiffner for helpful comments.
References
Bertelli, Anthony M., and David E. Lewis. n.d. "Policy
Influence, Outside Options, and Exit in the Federal Service."
Typescript, Vanderbilt University.
Bok, Derek. 2003. "Government Personnel Policy in Comparative
Perspective." In For the People: Can We Fix Public Service?, eds.
John D. Donahue and Joseph S. Nye Jr. Washington, DC: Brookings
Institution, 255-72.
Boylan, Richard T. 2004. "Salaries, Turnover, and Performance
in the Federal Criminal Justice System." Journal of Law and
Economics 47 (1): 75-92.
Burgess, Simon, and Marisa Ratto. 2003. "The Role of
Incentives in the Public Sector: Issues and Evidence." Oxford
Review of Economic Policy 19 (2): 285-300.
Burke, John E 2000. Presidential Transitions: From Politics to
Practice. Boulder, CO: Lynne Rienner.
--. 2004. Becoming President: The Bush Transition, 2000-2003.
Boulder, CO: Lynne Rienner.
--. 2009. "The Obama Transition: An Early Assessment."
Presidential Studies Quarterly 39 (3): 574-604.
Cohen, David M. 1998. "Amateur Government. "Journal of
Public Administration Research and Theory 8 (4): 450-97.
Cooper, Christopher, and Robert Block. 2007. Disaster: Hurricane
Katrina and the Failure of Homeland Security. New York: Times Books.
Crewson, Philip E. 1995. "A Comparative Analysis of Public and
Private Sector Entrant Quality." American Journal of Political
Science 39 (3): 628-39.
Dull, Matt, and Patrick S. Roberts. 2009. "Continuity,
Competence, and the Succession of Senate-Confirmed Agency Appointees,
1989-2009." Presidential Studies Quarterly 39 (3): 432-53.
Dunn, Delmer D. 1997. Polities and Administration at the Top:
Lessons from Down Under. Pittsburgh, PA: University of Pittsburgh Press.
Durant, Robert E 1992. The Administrative Presidency Revisited:
Public Lands, the BLM, and the Reagan Revolution. Albany, NY: State
University of New York Press.
Durant, Robert E, and William G. Resh. 2009."
'Presidentializing' the Bureaucracy." In The Oxford
Handbook of the American Presidency, eds. George C. Edwards, III, and
William G. Howell. Oxford, UK: Oxford University Press, 577-600.
Edwards, George C., III. 2001. "Why Not the Best? The
Loyalty-Competence Trade-Off in Presidential Appointments."
Brookings Review 19 (2): 12-16.
Gailmard, Scan E, and John W. Patty. 2007. "Slackers and
Zealots: Civil Service, Policy Discretion, and Bureaucratic
Expertise." American Journal of Political Science 51 (4): 873-89.
Gallo, Nick, and David E. Lewis. 2012. "The Consequences of
Presidential Patronage for Federal Agency Performance." Journal of
Public Administration Research and Theory 22 (2): 219-43.
Gilmour, John B., and David E. Lewis. 2006. "Political
Appointees and the Competence of Federal Program Management."
American Politics Research 34 (1): 22-50.
Golden, Marissa Martino. 2000. What Motivates Bureaucrats? Politics
and Administration During the Reagan Years. New York: Columbia
University Press.
Heclo, Hugh. 1975. "OMB and the Presidency--The Problem
of'Neutral Competence.' " The Public Interest 38
(Winter): 80-98.
--. 1977. A Government of Strangers: Executive Politics in
Washington. Washington, DC: Brookings Institution.
Hudak, John. 2012. "The Politics of Federal Grants:
Presidential Influence over the Distribution of Federal Funds."
Ph.D. diss., Vanderbilt University.
Johnson, Clay. 2008. "Recommendations for an Effective 2008
Transition." Public Administration Review 68 (4): 624-26.
--. 2009. "The 2008-2009 Presidential Transition: Preparing
Federal Agencies." Presidential Studies Quarterly 39 (4): 819-22.
Kaufman, Herbert. 1965. "The Growth of the Federal Personnel
System." In The Federal Government Service, ed. Wallace S. Sayre.
Englewood Cliffs, NJ: Prentice-Hall, 7-69.
Krause, George A., David E. Lewis, and James W. Douglas. 2006.
"Political Appointments, Civil Service Systems, and Bureaucratic
Competence: Organizational Balancing and Gubernatorial Revenue Forecasts
in the American States." American Journal of Political Science 50
(3): 770-87.
Lewis, David E. 2008. The Politics of Presidential Appointments:
Political Control and Bureaucratic Performance. Princeton, NJ: Princeton
University Press.
--. 2009. "Modern Presidents and the Transformation of the
Federal Personnel System." The Forum 7 (4): article 6.
http://www.degruyter.com/view/j/for.2010.7.420120105083456/
for.2010.7.4/for.2010.7.4.1338/for.2010.7.4. ] 338.xml?format=INT
(accessed April 25, 2012).
--. 2011. "Presidential Appointments in the Obama
Administration: An Early Evaluation." In The Obama Presidency:
Change and Continuity, eds. Andrew Dowdle, Dirk van Raemdonck, and
Robert Maranto. New York: Routledge.
Lewis, David E., and Terry M. Moe. 2009. "Struggling Over
Bureaucracy: The Levers of Control." In The Presidency and the
Political System, 9th ed., ed. Michael Nelson. Washington, DC: CQ Press.
Lewis, David E., and Abby K. Wood. n.d. "The Paradox of Agency
Responsiveness: A Federal FOIA
Experiment." Typescript, Vanderbilt. University
https://my.vanderbilt.edu/davidlewis/files/2011/
12/lewis-and-wood-paper-v.9.pdf (accessed April 2, 2012).
Light, Paul. 1995. Thickening Government: Federal Hierarchy and the
Diffusion of Accountability. Washington, DC: Brookings Institution.
Mackenzie, G. Calvin. 1981. The Politics of Presidential
Appointments. New York: Free Press.
Maranto, Robert. 1998. "Thinking the Unthinkable in Public
Administration: A Case for Spoils in the Federal Bureaucracy."
Administration and Society 29 (6): 623-42.
--. 2001. "Why the President Should Ignore Calls to Reduce the
Number of Political Appointees." The Heritage Foundation
Backgrounder 1413. http://www.heritage.org/research/reports/2001/
02/bgl413es-why-the-president-should-ignore-calls-to-reduce (accessed
April 25, 2012).
--. 2005. Beyond a Government of Strangers. Lanham, MD: Lexington
Books. Moe, Terry M. 1982. "Regulatory Performance and Presidential
Administration." American Journal of Political Science 26 (2):
197-224.
--. 1985. "The Politicized Presidency." In The New
Direction in American Politics, eds. John E. Chubb and Paul E. Peterson.
Washington, DC: Brookings Institution Press, 235-71.
Nathan, Richard P. 1975. The Plot that Failed: Nixon and the
Administrative Presidency. New York: Wiley.
National Commission on the Public Service. 1989. Leadership for
America: Rebuilding the Public Service. Lexington, MA: Lexington Books.
--. 2003. Urgent Business for America: Revitalizing the Federal
Government for the 21st Century. Washington, DC: Brookings Institution
Press.
Newland, Chester A. 1987. "Public Executives: Imperium,
Sacerdotium, Collegium? Bicentennial Leadership Challenges." Public
Administration Review 47 (1): 45-56.
O'Connell, Anne Joseph. 2009. "Vacant Offices: Delays in
Staffing Top Agency Positions." Southern California Law Review 82
(5): 913-99.
Patterson, Bradley H., Jr. 2008. To Serve the President: Continuity
and Innovation in the White House Staff. Washington, DC: Brookings
Institution.
Patterson, Bradley H., Jr., and James P. Pfiffner. 2001. "The
White House Office of Presidential Personnel." Presidential Studies
Quarterly 31 (3): 415-38.
Perry, J., and Wise, L. 1990. "The Motivational Bases of
Public Service." Public Administration Review 50 (3): 367-73.
Pfiffner, James E 1996. The Strategic Presidency: Hitting the
Ground Running. Lawrence: University Press of Kansas.
Randall, Ronald. 1979. "Presidential Powers versus
Bureaucratic Intransigence: The Influence of the Nixon Administration on
Welfare Policy." American Political Science Review 73 (3): 795-810.
Rottinghaus, Brandon, and Daniel E. Bergan. 2011. "The
Politics of Requesting Appointments: Congressional Requests in the
Appointment and Nomination Process." Political Research Quarterly
64 (1): 31-44.
Stewart, Joseph, Jr., and Jane S. Cromartie. 1982. "Partisan
Presidential Change and Regulatory Policy: The Case of the FTC and
Deceptive Practices Enforcement, 1938-1974." Presidential Studies
Quarterly 12 (4): 568-73.
Suleiman, Ezra. 2003. Dismantling Democratic States. Princeton, N
J: Princeton University Press. Sullivan, Terry. 2009. "Pursuing the
Details of Inquiry." White House Transition Project Paper, 2009-01.
http://whitehousetransitionproject.org/resources/briefing/WHTP-
200901b%20Details%20of%20Inquiry.pdf (accessed November 2, 2010).
Suskind, Ron. 2011. Confidence Men: Wall Street, Washington, and
the Education of a President. New York: Harper.
Tolchin, Martin, and Susan J. Tolchin. 1971. To the Victor:
Political Patronage from the Clubhouse to the White House. New York:
Random House.
--. 2010. Pinstripe Patronage: Political Favoritism from the
Clubhouse to the White House and Beyond. Boulder, CO: Paradigm
Publishers.
U.S. Congress. House. Committee on Post Office and Civil Service.
1960. Policy and Supporting Positions. Washington, DC: Government
Printing Office.
Van Riper, Paul E 1958. History of the United States Civil Service.
Evanston, IL: Row, Peterson.
Weko, Thomas J. 1995. The Politicizing Presidency: The White House
Personnel Office, 1948-1994. Lawrence: University Press of Kansas.
White, Leonard D. 1954. The Jacksonians: A Study in Administrative
History, 1829-1861. New York: Macmillan.
Wood, B. Dan. 1990. "Does Politics Make a Difference at the
EEOC?" American Journal of Political Science 34 (2): 503-30.
Wood, B. Dan, and James E. Anderson. 1993. "The Politics of
U.S. Antitrust Regulation." American Journal of Political Science
37 (1): 1-39.
Wood, B. Dan, and Richard W. Waterman. 1991. "The Dynamics of
Political Control of the Bureaucracy." American Political Science
Review 85 (3): 801-28.
--. 1994. Bureaucratic Dynamics: The Role of Bureaucracy in a
Democracy, Transforming American Politics. Boulder, CO: Westview Press.
Woodward, Bob. 2002. Bush at War. New York: Simon & Schuster.
DAVID E. LEWIS
Vanderbilt University
(1.) There are three main types of appointees in the executive
branch, Senate-confirmed appointees (1,141), appointees in the Senior
Executive Service (665), and Schedule C appointees (1,559).
Senate-confirmed positions are those at the top of the federal executive
hierarchy such as cabinet secretaries, commissioners, and other top
executives. Below these appointees is the Senior Executive Service,
which is a layer of managers comprised of a maximum of 10% appointees.
Schedule C appointees are persons serving in a confidential or
policy-determining position bur at a lower level. These are often staff
positions. In addition to these positions, presidents must also fill
judgeships, select White House personnel, and recruit thousands of
persons for advisory commissions across the executive branch (Patterson
2008).
(2.) David Cho, "Staffing Shortage Hinders Treasury's
Progress," Washington Post, March 10, 2009.
http://www.washingtonpost.com/wp-
dyn/content/article/2009/03/09/AR200902807.html (accessed October 26,
2010).
(3.) Laura Meckler, "Obama Shifts View of Executive
Power." WallStreetffournal, March 20, 2012, A1.
http://online.wsj.com/article/
SB10001424052702303812904577292273663694712.html (accessed April 2,
2012).
(4.) Jackie Calmes, "Jobs Plan Stalled, Obama to Try New
Economic Drive," New York Times, October 23, 2011.
http://www.nytimes.com/2011/10/24/us/politics/jobs-plan-stalled-obama-to-try- new-economic-drive.html?_r=1&ref=business (accessed April 2,
2012); Tom Cohen, "Obama Uses Executive Orders as a Political
Tool," CNN, November 1, 2011.
http://articles.cnn.com/2011-ll-01/politics/politics_obamaexecutive-orders 1 executive-orders-press-secretary-jay-carney-inaction?_s=PM:POLITICS
(accessed April 2, 2012).
(5.) Jeanne Cummings, "Barack Obama Rewards Big Donors With
Plum Jobs Overseas." Politico, November 11, 2009.
http://www.politico.com/news/stories/1109/29699.html (accessed April 2,
2012); Cooper, Helene, and Jennifer Steinhauer, "Bucking Senate,
Obama Appoints Consumer Chief." New York Times, January 4, 2012.
http://www.nytimes.com/2012/01/05/us/politics/richard-cordray-named-
consumer-chief-in-recess-appointment.html?pagewanted all (accessed April
2, 2012).
(6.) Whereas, the continuing professional parts of the
institutional presidency, such as the Bureau of the Budget, previously
contributed transition advice, presidents now largely rely on advice
from partisans from previous administrations and, to a lesser extent,
academics working through organizations such as the American Society of
Public Administration and the White House Transition Project. In
addition, recent presidents have worked hard to ease the transition of
their successors (Burke 2009; Johnson 2008, 2009).
(7.) The creation of the Senior Executive Service is one part of
the story, contributing about 350 new appointees at this middle level,
in addition to the approximately 450 that carried over from the previous
Noncareer Executive Assignment system. Underappreciated during this
period is the increase of about 650 Schedule C appointees.
(8.) Stephen Barr, "Daley Pledge on Patronage Applauded."
Washington Post, January 24, 1997, A21.
(http://www.washingtonpost.com/wp-srv/politics/govt/admin/stories/
daley01297.htm, last accessed April 2, 2012).
(9.) Brady, Jessica, "Landrieu Maintains Hold on Lew Despite
End of Drilling Ban," Roll Call, October 12, 2010
http://www.rollcall.comlnews150659-1.html (accessed October 24, 2010).
(10.) Juliet Eilperin, "Nominations on Hold for Two Top
Science Posts," Washington Post, March 3, 2009.
http://www.washingtonpost.com/wp-dyn/content/article/2009/03/02
/AR2009030202425.html (accessed October 26, 2010).
(11.) Shailagh Murray, "Sen. Shelby Releases Hold on
Nominees," Washington Post, February 9, 2010.
http://www.washingtonpost.com/wp-dyn/content/article/2010/02/
AR2010020804199.html (accessed October 24, 2010).
(12.) The president put in new tough rules on lobbyists. He
prohibited lobbyists from working in agencies they had lobbied in over
the previous two years. New appointees had to agree not to lobby an
agency they had worked in for the duration of Obama's tenure (Burke
2009, 590).
(13.) There is an ongoing debate about whether the best and
brightest enter the private sector or public sector (see, e.g., Burgess
and Ratto 2003; Crewson 1995; Perry and Wise 1990)
(14.) Timothy B. Clark and Marjorie Wachtel, "The Quiet Crisis
Goes Public," Government Executive, June 1988, 28.
(15.) Since 1960, the number of Senate-confirmed positions has
increased a modest 65 positions in the continuing departments.
David E. Lewis is the William R. Kenan, fir Professor of Political
Science at Vanderbih University and co-director of the Center for the
Study of Democratic Institutions. He is the author 0f Presidents and the
Politics of Agency Design and The Politics of Presidential Appointments.