The last one hundred days.
Howell, William G. ; Mayer, Kenneth R.
A lame duck President might look at his authority to govern in the
transition period as if it were a large balloon with a slow leak.... The
balloon is ineluctably shrinking with each passing week.... By the end
of the year, he will have lost the attention of the permanent government
and can accomplish very little.
--James Pfiffner (1996, 5)
As his "long goodbye" in 2000-2001, Clinton was "a
whirling dervish of a President who appointed judges, signed treaties,
gave campaign-style speeches, issued scads of executive orders,
rescinded ethics regulations he had penned in his first term, raised
political money, gave dozens of interviews, granted 234 pardons and
clemencies, fired an enemy from her government job, negotiated his own
plea-bargain agreement, cast aspersions on his successor, installed a
crony as head of the Democratic Party, and gave an entire series of
farewell addresses in which he essentially said he wasn't leaving
at all."
--Carl Cannon (2001, 274)
A curious thing happens during the last one hundred days of a
presidential administration: political uncertainty shifts to political
certitude. The president knows exactly who will succeed him--his policy
positions, his legislative priorities, and the level of partisan support
he will enjoy within the new Congress. And if the sitting president (or
his party) lost the election, he has every reason to hurry through
last-minute public policies, doing whatever possible to tie his
successor's hands.
Can he succeed? If James Pfiffner's quote above is any
indication, prospects are dim. Defeated at the polls in November and
guaranteed political retirement in January, an outgoing president has
little ground upon which to advocate for his (someday her) policy
agenda. During his final months in office, his public prestige and
professional reputation--the ingredients of persuasion, and the
purported foundations of presidential power--run empty. Members of
Congress have little cause to do a defeated president's bidding;
and without them, presidents cannot hope to accomplish anything of
consequence. As such, outgoing presidents have little choice but to
recognize their plight, gather their belongings, and close the door on
their administration.
In our estimation, this misconstrues things. By ignoring important
policy options outside of the legislative process, scholars have
exaggerated the frailty of outgoing presidents and underestimated the
influence they continue to wield. Presidential power does not reduce to
bargaining, negotiating, and convincing members of Congress to do things
that the president cannot accomplish on his own. Presidents can (and
regularly do) act alone, setting public policy without having to rally
Congress's attention, nor even its support (Cooper 2002; Howell
2003; Mayer 2001). With executive orders, proclamations, executive
agreements, national security directives, and memoranda, presidents have
ample resources to effectuate policy changes that stand little chance of
overcoming the collective action problems and multiple veto points that
plague the legislative process. And having "lost the attention of
the permanent government," outgoing presidents have every reason to
strike out on their own, set new policy, and leave it to the incoming
administration to try and steer an alternative course.
Examples of last-minute presidential actions abound. It was
President John Adams's "Midnight" appointments, which
Jefferson refused to honor, that prompted the landmark Marbury v.
Madison Supreme Court decision. Grover Cleveland created a
twenty-one-million-acre forest reserve to prevent logging, an act that
led to an unsuccessful impeachment attempt and the passage of
legislation annulling the action. Then, in response to the congressional
uprising, "Cleveland issued a pocket veto and left office"
(Combs 2001, 331). Jimmy Carter negotiated for the release of Americans
held hostage in Tehran, implementing an agreement on his last day in
office with ten separate executive orders, many of which sharply
restricted the rights of private parties to sue the Iranian government
for expropriation of their property. It was, according to Harold Hongju
Koh, "One of the most dramatic exercises of presidential power in
foreign affairs in peacetime United States history" (Koh 1990,
122). In late December 1992, George Bush pardoned six Reagan
administration officials who were involved in the Iran-Contra scandal, a
step that ended Independent Counsel Lawrence Walsh's criminal
investigation. "[In] a single stroke, Mr. Bush swept away one
conviction, three guilty pleas, and two pending cases, virtually
decapitating what was left of Mr. Walsh's effort, which began in
1986" (Johnston 1992). (1) And as Carl Cannon's quote at the
beginning of this paper indicates, during his final days in office
Clinton "issued scads of executive orders" on issues ranging
from protecting the Hawaiian Islands Coral Reef Ecosystem Reserve to
prohibiting the importation of rough cut diamonds from Sierra Leone to
curbing tobacco use both domestically and abroad.
In this article, we document the flurry of activity that regularly
occurs during the ultimate weeks of a defeated president's
administration, and the lasting impact this can have on his
successor's ability to govern. We proceed as follows. First, we
review the literature on presidential transitions and recount the
conventional understanding of presidential power. We then introduce the
president's powers of unilateral action and specify why presidents
have such strong incentives to exercise them during the waning hours of
their administrations. Analyzing trends in regulatory activity, we
identify spikes that coincide with presidential transitions. Finally,
through a series of case studies, we illustrate how last-minute
directives issued by presidents can tie the hands of their successors,
occasionally forcing them to choose between accepting objectionable
policies as law or paying a steep political price for trying to change
them.
Transitioning In and Out of Government
There is, at present, a sizable literature on presidential
transitions (Brauer 1986; Burke 2000; Henry 1960; Jones 1998; Kumar and
Sullivan 2003; Pfiffner 1996). Without exception, this work places
incoming presidents (aides and advisers brought in tow) front and
center. The literature really is about the challenges of moving from a
campaign to a governing stance, of transforming former governors,
senators, and vice presidents into presidents, of preparing November
victors for the awesome responsibilities and powers that await them in
January. It spells out the issues of staffing, management, agenda
setting, and policy formulation that inevitably confront
presidents-elect. It catalogs the personal and professional
tensions--between policy and political advisers, between campaign
workers and governing staffers, between Washington insiders and loyal
aides from the president-elect's home state--that regularly infect
transitions. Much of this literature, further, has a strong prescriptive
element. It offers up advice to newly elected presidents--delineate
clearly lines of authority; delegate wisely; heed the importance of
management; promote loyalty, though not at the expense of free and open
dialogue--in the hopes that they will avoid the mistakes of past
transitions. This literature, in short, details how former presidential
candidates steady their sights on the presidency itself, lay the
groundwork for governance, and, if they are lucky, generate the momentum
needed for change.
To the extent that they receive attention in the transitions
literature, outgoing presidents stand as little more than informational
resources for incoming administrations. In his presidential memos, for
instance, Richard Neustadt recommends that newly elected presidents
actively (though with due skepticism) seek the advice of sitting
secretaries and undersecretaries, advisers, and staffers. Lamenting how
little these officials are used, and how quickly they are forgotten,
Neustadt notes that "transitions offer opportunities to extract a
whole governmental generation's lore at once. But those who need it
most and could best use it, the incomers, rarely think of such
things" (Jones 2002, 167).
Instead, outgoing presidents rapidly fall out of favor and fade
away. In his authoritative book on presidential transitions, James
Pfiffner argues that,
When control of the presidency changes parties, the lame-duck
administration has eleven weeks to tidy up its affairs and
prepare the way for the new administration. Immediately after
the election power begins to shift noticeably. Senior career
executives begin to distance themselves from their bosses.... The
bureaucratic machine begins to slip into neutral gear because its
present leaders cannot guarantee any commitments beyond January
20. (1996, 5-6)
Pfiffner's perspective is widely shared. Writes Carl Brauer,
during presidential transitions "formal authority continues to
reside in the occupant of the White House, [but] his political power is
small compared to that of his successor. The focus of attention is on
the person about to become President, not on the person about to vacate the office" (1986, xiv). Laurin Henry characterizes outgoing
presidents as "caretakers" who enjoy three final months to
close up shop and ease into retirement (1960, 3). The sitting
president's policy agenda, his independent interests and
initiatives, along with the powers he wielded during the prior three and
three-quarter years, quickly dissipate in the waning months of his
administration, as attention rightfully shifts to the newly elected
president and the spectacle of a new government being formed.
A fair amount of quantitative work on second-term presidents
substantiates the impression that presidential influence begins to
decline the moment that reelection prospects foreclose. For instance,
second-term presidents have an especially difficult time using
ceremonial activities (major speeches, foreign and domestic travel) to
harness public support, underscoring "what appears to be a
lessening of effort" on their part (Brace and Hinckley 1993, 395).
This effort, apparently, extends into the legislative arena. Charles
Jones, for instance, studied the legislative histories of twenty-one
landmark laws initiated by presidents between 1947 and 1990 (1994).
Second-term presidents launched only three of these laws; presidents
with longer electoral horizons initiated the remaining eighteen.
Presidential struggles, however, are not confined to second terms.
Indeed, all presidents face a common dilemma. As Paul Light observes,
opportunities to advance an agenda peak early, typically during an
administration's first hundred days--precisely when presidents are
least organized and least knowledgeable about the workings of the
federal government. While expertise may grow over time, presidential
influence wanes. Midterm losses in Congress, the crowding of legislative
calendars, and depleted "energy and creative stamina" all
conspire against the president, locking him in a "cycle of
decreasing influence" (Light 1994, 41).
Over the course of presidential administrations, most trajectories
point downward. Public approval ratings steadily (though not
monotonically) decline (Mueller 1973; Stimson 1976); the
president's ability to guide legislation through the House and
Senate drops, often precipitously (Bond and Fleisher 1990; Rudalevige
2002); and the probability that presidents successfully steer their
Supreme Court nominees through the confirmation process declines rather
markedly, especially in the final months of his administration (Krutz,
Fleisher, and Bond 1998; Ruckman 1993; Segal 1987). And as it is with
approval ratings, agenda setting, and the confirmation of Supreme Court
nominees, so it is with legislative productivity rates more generally.
By David Mayhew's count, 3.5 fewer landmark laws on average are
enacted during the second two years of a presidential term than during
the first (Mayhew 1991). By the end of a presidential term, the
government appears to shift into low gear, putting off major action,
stalling nominations, and generally biding time, as key actors await the
arrival of a new administration.
For the most part, these trends bottom out during the final three
months of a presidential term. Defeated at the polls and granted but a
few months to disband his administration, an outgoing president has none
of the resources he needs to ensure compliance within the executive
branch or rally support on Capitol Hill. Indeed, it is difficult to
imagine a time when the president's bargaining position is more
bereft than the period after he, or his party, has lost a national
election. The moment the public boots him from office, the
president's promises turn hollow, his threats idle, his political
capital effete. As there is little presidents can do for those who
occupy other parts of the federal government, there is little reason for
them to expend much effort, or time, advancing his agenda. The
president's capacity to negotiate, broker deals, and ultimately
persuade is, at last, depleted.
His power, however, is not.
All Is Not Lost
Portraits of outgoing presidents going quietly into the night
overlook an important feature of American politics, and of executive
power--namely, the president's ability to unilaterally set public
policy (Cohen and Krause 1997; Cooper 1986, 1997, 2002; Howell 2003;
Howell and Lewis 2002; Krause and Cohen 1997; Mayer 1999, 2001; Mayer
and Price 2002; Moe and Howell 1999a, 1999b; Shull 1997). Using
executive orders, proclamations, executive agreements, national security
directives, memoranda, and other directives, presidents have at their
disposal a wide variety of means to effectuate lasting and substantive
policy changes, both foreign and domestic. Because they do not depend
upon the active support or cooperation of Congress, these tools of
direct action present ample opportunities for presidential influence,
influence that has very little to do with bargaining or persuasion
(Howell 2005). "With the stroke of the pen," these actions
assume the weight of law. And so they remain until and unless someone
else overturns them.
A basic principle governs the production of unilateral directives:
presidential policy making rises as Congress's capacity to
legislate declines (Howell 2003). If Congress cannot get its act
together--either because of partisan divisions within its membership or
the timing of the electoral calendar--presidents have strong incentives
to exercise their unilateral powers. For indeed, when gridlock prevails
within Congress, presidents can (and regularly do) strike out on their
own and set policies that would not survive the legislative process. As
Justice Jackson recognized in his famous concurring opinion of
Youngstown Sheet & Tube Co. v. Sawyer, "Congressional inertia,
indifference, or quiescence may sometimes, at least as a practical
matter, enable, if not invite, measures on independent presidential
responsibility" (343 U.S. 579 (1952), p. 637). The reverse of this
governing principle, however, also holds: when Congress stands poised to
enact sweeping policy changes, unilateral activity should decline,
regardless of whether Congress supports the president. If Congress
stands ready to enact his agenda, the president has every reason to
engage the legislative process, if only because laws are more durable
than unilateral directives. Likewise, if Congress opposes his agenda,
the president cannot readily exercise his unilateral powers without
subsequently being overturned.
Incentives to exercise these unilateral powers, as such, should
intensify in the final stages of a presidential administration. It is
then that Congress is least likely to do the president's bidding
because, all agree, his powers to bargain, negotiate, and persuade have
diminished. It is also then that the legislative process grinds to a
virtual standstill, assuring that little effort will be expended on
advancing his agenda--nor, by extension, on reversing policy directives
that the president issues on his own. Precisely because legislative
success rates taper off at the end of a term, unilateral activity should
spike upward.
Not all transitions, however, invite unilateral activity. When the
office passes from Republican to Republican, or Democrat to Democrat,
the sitting president has little cause to hurry through a slew of
last-minute directives. A reelected incumbent need not issue a slate of
unilateral directives during the final months of his first term; nor
does an outgoing president who is to be replaced by a co-partisan.
Emerging victorious in November, these presidents are assured of four
more years in service of their legislative agendas. Rather, it is when
the incumbent's party loses that presidents should exercise these
powers with exceptional zeal, making final impressions on public policy
in the short time before the opposition party assumes control.
Patterns of Unilateral Activity
Our empirical expectations are straightforward: presidential
transitions should witness jumps in unilateral activity when power
switches from one party to the other; but transitions from first to
second terms, and transitions from co-partisans, should not impact the
frequency with which presidents issue unilateral policy directives.
Some preliminary evidence already supports our expectations.
Kenneth Mayer has demonstrated that presidents issue nearly twice as
many executive orders (exempting purely administrative orders) during
the final month of those terms when they are leaving office to a
successor of the opposite party (Mayer 2001). Mayer finds no effects
during transitions between first- and second-term presidents, or in the
final month that divides two presidents from the same party. (2) In
every one of Mayer's regressions, the observed impact of
presidential transitions on unilateral activity is substantially larger
than those observed for all other explanatory variables. (3) The
results, further, hold irrespective of whether one examines the 1939-99
or the 1949-99 time period. These findings, according to Mayer, give
credence to the contention "that executive orders have a strong
policy component, as otherwise presidents would have little reason to
issue such last-minute orders" (2001, 97).
Mayer's analysis does not differentiate trivial from
significant executive orders. Because many executive orders concern
rather mundane matters--renaming administrative agencies, exempting
individuals from mandatory retirement, amending civil service rules,
establishing working groups and commissions--it is important to
distinguish those that substantively change public policy from those
that purely affect the administration and management of the executive
branch. Fortunately, both Howell (2003; and see the introductory paper
to this volume) and Mayer and Price (2002) have constructed time series
of those executive orders that had a significant impact on public
policy. Identifying citations of executive orders by federal judges,
members of Congress, and the media, Howell created two significant
executive order time series during the post-War era. From a random
sample of 1,000 executive orders, Mayer and Price isolated significant
orders based upon both the political and media coverage they received,
as well as their policy and legal importance based upon content
analyses.
The two datasets generate very different results with respect to
presidential transitions. In Howell's data, presidents do not
appear to issue any more orders during the final three months of their
administrations than during earlier periods of their terms. Significant
differences, however, are observed in Mayer and Price's data. Based
on the random sample of orders issued between 1945 and 1999, presidents
issued, on average, 1.08 significant orders during each of the last
three months of their terms. During transitions from first to second
terms, and from incumbents to newly elected presidents from the same
party, 1.32 significant orders are issued. But when presidents, or their
parties, lose the office to the opposition, they issue an average of
2.34 significant orders during each of the final three months of
office--almost twice the average level of activity recorded during the
modern era.
The differences observed in the two data sets may reveal an
important facet of unilateral policy making that occurs at the end of a
presidential term. To generate their lists, Howell consulted political
citations and media coverage while Mayer and Price read the content of
the orders and relied upon historians and policy experts to evaluate
their substantive importance. If presidents are issuing important
last-minute directives that attract little public attention--as all
anticipate the arrival of an incoming administration--then it stands to
reason that Howell's data set would not generate effects, while
Mayer and Price's does.
Bursts of unilateral activity at the end of a presidential
administration, however, should not be restricted to executive orders.
Indeed, regulatory activity more generally ought to shoot up during the
last three months of an outgoing president's term. In a report put
out by the Mercatus Center at George Mason University, Jay Cochran uses
the number of pages in the Federal Register as a proxy for production
levels of rules and regulations (Cochran 2001). In addition to executive
orders, these pages include proclamations, administrative directives,
and documentation relating to the regulatory process (from notices of
proposed rulemaking to final rules). Rudimentary statistical tests show
jumps in presidential activity during transitions, especially after an
incumbent president or his party loses in November. Cochran concludes
that "there is in fact a systematic tendency across time and across
parties to increase regulatory volumes during the waning days of an
administration" (2001, 15).
In this section, we extend the Federal Register time series and
subject it to more rigorous tests. Figure 1 presents the data. The solid
line depicts a nonlinear smoother that, by omitting noise components
from the time series, reveals underlying trends in the data. While the
number of pages of the Federal Register rises slowly from 1945 to 1970,
it takes off in the early 1970s, then dips slightly in the 1980s, only
to rise again in the 1990s.
Observations that occur during transition periods from one party to
another are denoted by an "X"; all others are dots. Note that
a solid majority number of X's in Figure 1, and every single X
since Carter, are located well above the smoother, lending some
preliminary support for our contention that unilateral activity
increases during the waning months of an outgoing president's
administration. Simple descriptive statistics tell much the same story.
In a typical month, 3,215 pages of presidential directives, rules, and
memoranda fill the Federal Register. During those transitions that do
not yield a change of party, 3,499 pages are issued on average. When a
challenger from the opposite party as the incumbent's wins in
November, however, outgoing presidents issue directives that fill fully
4,747 pages in each of the final three months of their administrations.
These differences are significant at p < .01.
Much the same is observed in multivariate regressions.
Autocorrelation functions reveal that the time series contains a unit
root, and hence is not stationary; uncorrected, all t and F tests are
spurious. Fortunately, by taking first differences the series becomes
stationary, allowing us to perform standard time-series regressions.
Autocorrelation and partial autocorrelation functions suggest that the
differenced series has a first-order moving average component, but no
autoregressive component. (4) We therefore estimate the following IMA (0, 1, 1) model: (5)
[Y.sub.t] = [[beta].sub.0] + [[beta].sub.1][M.sub.t] +
[[beta].sub.2]([M.sub.t.sup.*][S.sub.t]) + [e.sub.t] +
[[theta].sub.1][e.sub.t-1]
where Y represents the number of pages of presidential documents in
the Federal Register, M identifies the last three months of completed
presidential administrations, and (M * S) is an interaction variable
between M and S, an indicator for a change in the party of the
president. All variables are first differenced, and robust standard
errors are calculated. Our theory principally concerns the value of
[[beta].sub.2], which we expect to be positive and statistically
significant. Table 1 presents descriptive statistics for all variables.
Column 1 of Table 2 presents the results. As expected, presidential
transitions generally do not witness surges in regulatory activity. When
the office switches parties, however, significant and positive impacts
are observed. Having lost in November, presidents usher through the
regulatory process roughly 25 percent more rules and directives during
the final three months of their terms. To check the robustness of the
results, column 2 then adds to the model fixed effects for the month,
year of term, and presidential administration to account for seasonal,
intra-administration, and presidency variations, respectively. Little
changes. The main effects, while positive, remain statistically
indistinguishable from zero, while the interaction term is substantively
large and statistically significant. (6)
There are, of course, considerably more factors that contribute to
unilateral activity than simply issues of timing. Howell, for instance,
presents a simple game theoretic model that predicts more unilateral
directives during periods of unified government and when gridlock
prevails in Congress (Howell 2003). (7) In addition, a number of
scholars have found that war and the state of the economy contribute to
unilateral activity (Howell 2003; Krause and Cohen 2000; Mayer 1999,
2001; Mayer and Price 2002). As such, we re-estimate the above models
adding controls for divided government, the average size of the majority
parties in the House and Senate, war, the size of the federal budget,
and recession. Column 3 presents the results.
The main effect of presidential transitions now is statistically
significant, suggesting that presidents generally issue more rules and
regulations during the final three months of their administration.
Again, though, effects are significantly larger when the office of the
presidency changes parties. Consistent with other scholars' claims,
regulatory activity decreases during periods of divided government and
large budgets. The impacts for congressional majorities and recession,
though of the expected sign, are not statistically significant. Finally,
the observed impact of war conflicts with conventional wisdom. While
previous scholars find that presidents issue more executive orders when
the nation is at war, regulatory activity more generally appears to
decline. (8)
Making Orders Stick
How long do last-minute presidential actions endure? Surely, what
an outgoing president accomplishes unilaterally in the twilight of his
administration, the incoming president can undo unilaterally during his
honeymoon. Presidents regularly issue executive orders, proclamations,
and rules that overturn unilateral actions taken by their predecessors.
And should they prefer not to overturn an order, newly elected
presidents can simply block its implementation. Just as Reagan imposed a
sixty-day moratorium on the implementation of rules that Carter
instituted during the last three months of his administration, so did
Bush (43), immediately upon taking office, put a halt to orders that
Clinton issued in the waning days of his administration.
It would be a mistake, however, to conclude that the bursts of
unilateral activity that occur in the final months of an outgoing
president's administration ultimately, indeed almost immediately,
amount to little more than last gasps of a discredited regime.
Occasionally, presidents cannot alter orders set by their predecessors
without paying a considerable political price, undermining the
nation's credibility, or confronting serious legal obstacles.
Consider the following.
The Arsenic Regulations
Outgoing presidents can impose a wide range of obligations on
incoming presidents. Some of these commitments may come directly from
the president, in the form of executive orders, proclamations,
administrative directives, appointments, or other unilateral actions.
Others may originate in executive branch agencies through the rulemaking
process. And there are special advantages associated with pursuing this
latter route. "{Once} a final regulation has been published in the
Federal Register, the only unilateral way an administration can revise
it is through new rulemaking under the Administrative Procedure Act.
Agencies cannot change existing regulations arbitrarily; instead, they
must first develop a factual record that supports the change in
policy" (Dudley 2001). If a lame-duck administration can hustle a
final rule out the door before January 20th, the new administration must
begin an entirely new cycle of rulemaking. Not only does this require
time, but changing the status quo may well mean taking on interest
groups who are reticent to give up ground that they have just won.
To see this, consider the December 2000 water quality regulations
issued by the Environmental Protection Agency (EPA). On January 22,
2000, the EPA published a ninety-one-page final rule on the maximum
levels of arsenic permitted in public drinking water. (9) The new rule
lowered the maximum allowable level of arsenic from 50 parts per billion
(ppb), a threshold that had been in effect since 1975, to 10ppb, with
the new standard to go into effect in March 2001. Shortly after taking
office, the Bush administration delayed the effective date of all
pending regulations by sixty days, a move that applied to the arsenic
rule. (10) On March 20, amid hints that the Bush administration planned
on scrapping the Clinton-era rule altogether, EPA Administrator
Christine Todd Whitman announced an additional sixty-day delay. (11)
And then, all hell broke loose. Cass Sunstein described the
reaction:
A national survey conducted between April 21 and April 26, 2001,
found that fifty-six percent of Americans rejected the Bush
decision, whereas only thirty-four percent approved of it--and
that majorities of Americans opposed the decision in every region
of the nation. At various points, the public outcry combined
concern, certainty, and cynicism. "Arsenic Everywhere, and Bush
Is Not Helping," according to one newspaper. "You may have voted
for him, but you didn't vote for this in your water," wrote the
Wall Street Journal. In an editorial, the New York Times demanded
that "Americans should expect their drinking water to be at least
as safe as that of Japan, Jordan, Namibia, and Laos," all of which
impose a 10 parts per billion (ppb) standard. A respected journalist
asked, "How callous can you get, Mr. Compassionate Conservative?"
(2002, 2261)
Soon thereafter, the Democratic National Committee assessed the
first 100 days of the Bush administration with an ad, in which a young
toddler asks, "Can I please have some more arsenic in my water,
mommy?" (12) In unusually blunt language, an attorney for the
Natural Resources Defense Council criticized the decision as one that
will "force millions of Americans to continue to drink
arsenic-laced water. Many will die from arsenic-related cancers and
other diseases, but George Bush apparently doesn't care. This
outrageous act is just another example of how the polluters have taken
over the government." (13)
The Bush administration argued, initially, that it was not at all
clear that the benefits of the 10 ppb standard would outweigh the costs.
Clinton's January 22, 2001 rule estimated the total annual cost of
the 10ppb rule to be $206 million, with the household cost varying from
under $1 per year in large systems to $327 per year in small systems.
(14) The main benefit would be a reduction in the number of both fatal
and nonfatal bladder and lung cancers, with the EPA estimating that the
10ppb standard would prevent between twenty-one and thirty fatalities
annually. (15) Using a baseline of $6.1 million per life saved and
$607,000 per illness prevented, the EPA found that the benefits of the
proposed regulation could be valued at up to $198 million per year, with
additional nonquantifiable benefits stemming from reduction in illnesses
other than lung and bladder cancer. (16) Even though the highest
quantified benefits of the 10 ppb standard ($198 million) were less than
the highest estimate of the costs ($206 million), the EPA
"concluded that once the non-quantified benefits of the 10ppb
standard were included, the costs would well be justified"
(Sunstein 2002, 2275).
Such estimates, though, were based on what some analysts considered
to be dubious assumptions. Sunstein notes that the calculations of lives
saved and illnesses prevented came from epidemiological studies from
Taiwan, and were based on the assumption that the health risks of
arsenic increased as a linear function of exposure (Sunstein 2002,
2272-73). (17) In addition, the valuation assigned to lives saved was
based largely on 1970s studies of how much employers had to compensate
employees for risky jobs. The estimate of the value of an illness
avoided "does not come from measurements of people's
willingness to pay to reduce a statistical chance of nonfatal cancer,
but instead--and somewhat astonishingly--from shoppers' responses
to hypothetical questions about how much they would pay to reduce a
statistical risk of chronic bronchitis" (Sunstein 2002, 2275). A
Brookings Institution-American Enterprise Institute study attacked the
proposed rule, arguing that the costs would exceed the benefits by up to
$190 million per year (Burnett and Hahn 2001).
Nevertheless, the new rule put the Bush administration in an
impossible situation. However much officials might have wanted to argue
about the ambiguities in the scientific data, the health risks of
arsenic, the costs of lowering the standard, and the uncertain benefits,
they were, quite simply, swamped by the prevalent view that arsenic was
a poison, and that quibbling over costs and benefits and uncertainties
and linear versus sublinear dose-response curves was ridiculous when
children were drinking contaminated water. In October 2001, after
additional reviews supported the lower threshold, the EPA announced that
it would implement the 10ppb standard according to the schedule set out
in the January rule. (18)
Prior to the January 2001 arsenic rule, 50ppb stood as the
reversion policy. But once the final rule was issued, the default
outcome changed to the lower 10ppb standard. This is an obvious but
crucial change, as it completely reframed the regulatory question. The
Bush administration was no longer simply defending the higher standard.
In order to succeed it had to discredit the new standard. Moreover, the
new reversion point fundamentally altered the debate, which was no
longer about whether it made sense to lower the permissible levels of
arsenic; rather, the question became why the Bush administration wanted
to raise current permissible levels. Although the counterfactual is
speculative, it is reasonable to think that absent the new rule the Bush
administration would have had an easier time imposing a compromise it
position were working down from 50ppb rather than up from 10. Faced with
the new analyses which supported the lower standard, EPA Administrator
Whitman "{had} little choice but to adopt a standard at least as
tough as the one she had delayed" (Kaiser 2001, 2189). In June of
2003 the U.S. Circuit Court of Appeals upheld the Clinton standard of
10ppb, dismissing a suit filed by the state of Nebraska. (19) The new
standard is now slated to go into effect in 2006, right on schedule with
the original Clinton order.
Public Lands
Clinton's high end-of-term energy had some consequences that
Bush could not undo, even if he were so inclined. Throughout his terms,
Clinton had aggressively used his delegated power under the 1906
Antiquities Act to establish numerous national monuments. (20) Unlike
many unilateral acts, though, these national monuments, once established
by proclamation, could not be "disestablished" by a subsequent
proclamation. The Antiquities Act, which Clinton used to legally justify
his actions, only permits presidents to extend federal protections to
new sires; nothing in the act allows presidents to weaken, much less
retract, existing protections. The only way Bush could reverse
Clinton's actions was to assemble the necessary majorities and
supermajorities required to enact a law--a difficult feat indeed, given
the multiple veto points and collective action problems that plague the
legislative process. (21)
Knowing this, Clinton issued a batch of proclamations during the
final months of his administration that extended federal protections to
more than 2 million acres of public lands. On November 9, 2001, Clinton
issued proclamations 7373 and 7374 which expanded the protected lands in
Craters of the Moon, Idaho and Vermilion Cliffs, Arizona. Then, just
days before leaving office, Clinton issued proclamations 7392-99 and
7402, which created national monuments in the Virgin Islands,
California, New Mexico, Idaho, Montana, Arizona, and New York totaling
more than 1 million acres. (22) And with executive orders 13178 and
13196 issued in December 2000 and January 2001, Clinton extended federal
protections to fully 84 million acres of Hawaiian undersea coral reefs.
However much Bush might have objected to both the substance of
Clinton's orders and the process by which they were issued, he
lacked statutory authority to undo them unilaterally. Moreover, the Bush
administration noted that any organized effort to overturn them
legislatively would be pointless. In February 2001, Secretary of the
Interior Gall Norton stated that while she "disapprove{d} of the
process by which those monuments were generally created," there
would be no effort to revoke them (Pianin 2001). In June 2001,
Representative Mike Simpson (R-ID) introduced legislation to curb the
president's authority under the Antiquities Act. Under the proposal
(H.R. 2114), a president would have a difficult time creating national
monuments larger than 50,000 acres. In these cases, the law imposes
notification, consultation, and public comment. Crucially, it requires
positive congressional action within two years to approve the
designation. Although the bill was reported by the House Committee on
Resources, no floor action occurred. (23) Simpson reintroduced the bill
in 2003 as H.R. 2386; as of this writing, the bill has yet to emerge
from committee.
International Commitments
Last-minute domestic policy initiatives can, as the arsenic rules
demonstrated, put the new administration in an uncomfortable (if not
altogether untenable) position. There are times, however, when an
outgoing president can create international commitments, which have the
effect of putting the international prestige of the United States on the
line. To be sure, a newly elected president can withdraw from
international agreements negotiated by his predecessor--doing so,
however, may damage relations with the other nations that were party to
the agreement, just as they harm the United States' perceived
credibility in the globe more generally. Consider two such examples, one
involving a president's efforts to dissolve an international
crisis, the other an effort to construct a new international court.
In 1981, outgoing President Carter used executive orders, many
signed on his last day in office, to secure the release of American
hostages held in the Tehran embassy since November 1979. These orders
committed the United States to abide by a series of international
agreements governing the disposition of claims against the Iranian
government. Although it was within the Reagan administration's
power to revoke them, the fact that Carter had used the orders to bind
the nation to international law made the legal situation much more
complicated than it would have otherwise been:
Had President Reagan been confronted with a piece of unwanted
domestic legislation, he would have had to consider only the
domestic political ramifications of the course he took. By
contrast, in adhering to the Algiers Declarations, President
Carter had bound the United States to international obligations
that thereby rendered the United States accountable to the
international community. Further, in contrast to many treaties
which contain obligations but do not contain clear provisions
as to remedies for violations of those obligations, the Algiers
Declarations expressly created an enforcement mechanism: the
Iran-United States Claims Tribunal--with the power to resolve
disputes over the interpretation and performance of any provision
to the Declarations. Thus, the Reagan Administration knew from the
outset that its stringent interpretation of the Declarations could
be passed upon by an international tribunal. (Combs 2001, 307-8)
Combs, who was a legal adviser to the claims tribunal, also notes
that although the Reagan administration was hardly enthusiastic about
the agreement Carter had negotiated, officials ultimately saw no
alternative to implementing it. (24)
On December 31, 2000, Clinton announced that the United States
would become a signatory to the Treaty of Rome, which established the
International Criminal Court (ICC). The United States was one of seven
nations to vote against the final treaty in 1998, largely because of
concerns that the ICC would be able to assert jurisdiction over U.S.
military personnel. "The principal objection raised by the
administration ... was that American nationals, particularly members of
the armed services, could in certain contingencies be subjected to trial
in the new court without the specific consent of the United States"
(Leigh 2001, 126). (25) But on the last day on which nations could sign,
Clinton reversed course. And he did so without any intention of even
submitting the treaty for Senate ratification. (26)
Unlike Carter's Algiers Declaration executive orders,
Clinton's decision did not formally bind the incoming
administration to the ICC. Still, many international legal scholars
argued that as a signatory, the United States did have an obligation
under international law to refrain from actively working to undermine
the treaty. (27) But the Bush administration, along with Congress,
remained strongly opposed to the ICC. It was obvious to all observers
that ratification was out of the question; indeed, Congress enacted
language to a 2002 supplemental Department of Defense Appropriations Act
that prohibited any expenditures "to provide support or other
assistance to the International Criminal Court or to any criminal
investigation or other prosecutorial activity of the International
Criminal Court." (28)
In May 2002, shortly before the new ICC was set to enter into
force, the White House announced its intention to "unsign" the
treaty and renounce all obligations as a signatory, an act that UN
officials claimed was unprecedented (Lewis 2002). Yale Law School professor Harold Hongju Koh called the action a "profound
error," and argued that the United States was missing what he
called "an international Marbury v. Madison moment" that could
redefine the role of international institutions (as quoted in Lewis
2002). Former presidential candidate John Anderson argued that the
repudiation "{traduced} one of the most important principles of
American democracy" (2002, 7). (29) Critics claim that the nation
was playing a particularly sharp-edged form of political hardball,
withholding foreign aid from any country that refuses to immunize U.S.
citizens against ICC action, and threatening to veto any Security
Council resolutions on peacekeeping operations unless U.S. military
personnel are exempted from ICC jurisdiction (Becker 2003; Marquis
2002).
Of course not everyone thinks that withdrawing from the Treaty of
Rome is a bad idea, and the withdrawal did not attract a significant
amount of public attention (Rabkin 2002; Swaine 2003). But the move did
(and continues to) complicate foreign policy, requiring the Bush
administration to expend political capital that it might otherwise have
been able to devote to other purposes.
Conclusion
At its core, this article identifies a straightforward empirical
pattern. Contrary to conventional wisdom on the matter, presidents do
not quietly relinquish their powers the moment that the nation votes
them out of office. Instead, these presidents squeeze these last moments
in office for all they are worth, issuing all sorts of rules and
directives, many of which cannot be changed without exacting a
significant political price to either the incoming president or to the
nation as a whole. While legislative processes may lay dormant at the
end of a presidential term, the production of unilateral directives
kicks into high gear.
More generally, though, our analysis makes use of an emerging
theoretical emphasis on the president's unilateral powers. We argue
that presidents have always had a motive to wield their power up to the
very last minute. Our contribution is a confirmation that presidents
have the means to do so in ways that establish concrete and enduring
policies--policies that the current Congress would likely refuse to
enact, and that the succeeding president is sometimes forced to accept.
Reflecting upon the legitimacy of these "lame-duck"
policies, we can distinguish between two types of last-minute
presidential actions. The first are those that are consistent with the
presidential preferences as expressed throughout his term, or which are
merely an extension or continuation of existing policy. Because policy
processes, even for unilateral actions, take time, a decision issued a
week before the inauguration might reflect work that has been going on
for months--even well before the election. The second category consists
of those decisions that would not have been made had the president (or
at least the president's party) been reelected. Such policies are
either inconsistent with previous actions or are sufficiently
controversial that they would have created unacceptable political
consequences for the president. As we have noted, defeated presidents
are no longer encumbered by the threat of electoral retribution; by
definition, that threat has already been carried out. Outgoing
presidents need no longer concern themselves about the electoral
consequences of what they do during the transition, or about how a
controversial decision will affect the rest of their agendas. A poorly
considered act could, of course, affect a president's legacy, but
that is more of a personal than a public concern. Democratic
accountability, if it is to be exercised at all, can only be enforced
through indirect means, such as through threats that an unpopular
last-minute action might hurt a future presidential nominee.
Obviously, some policies that emerge in the final months of a
president's term have nothing to do with presidents trying to rush
through last-minute orders that they either could not, or would not,
advance during the first three and three-quarter years of their term.
Many, however, do. For instance, Bush's Christmas pardons of key
Iran-Contra figures, and Clinton's notoriously controversial
pardons of Marc Rich and Carlos Vignali, generated such strong criticism
that it is easy to infer that they would not have happened had Bush won
reelection in 1992 or Gore succeeded Clinton in 2000. In addition, the
findings from the regression models suggest that many more reflect
presidential efforts to hurry through last-minute orders before the
closing of their administrations. The models, recall, control for
intra-year, intra-administration, and administration fixed effects.
Moreover, the interaction effects of end-of-term periods and party
switches generate substantively large and statistically significant
effects. Given that transitions from Democratic (Republican) to
Republican (Democratic) administrations yield significantly higher
levels of regulatory outputs than do Democratic (Republican) to
Democratic (Republican) transitions, we can fairly attribute these
bursts of activities to something more than just standard regulatory
processes.
As Susan Dudley notes, "Of course, some of these so-called
midnight regulations may have been developed carefully over many years,
in a rulemaking process that just happened to have culminated during the
final months of the administration. But certainly others were hurried
into effect without the usual checks and balances, and may cater to
special interests rather than the public interest." (30) As an
example, Dudley documents new Department of Energy standards mandating
minimum energy efficiency for air conditioners, heat pumps, and washing
machines that typically require upward of a decade to develop, but that
"hurtled through the regulatory process at lightning speed"
during the last couple of months of Clinton's administration.
Criticisms, of course, are easily cast at last-minute policy
making, both the directives themselves and the powers presidents deploy
to issue them. Nancy Combs, for instance, expresses concern that "a
democratic tension arises whenever a lame-duck office holder uses his
remaining days in office to advance policy objectives that he believes
his successor does not support." These directives lack the sort of
legitimacy that pre-election activity has, because by definition they
are issued after a president (and, in many cases, his party) has been
repudiated at the polls. Moreover, there are no opportunities for
democratic accountability, because, again, voters do not have a
subsequent chance to express their approval or disapproval. (31)
To engage this normative debate, however, is to concede a basic
fact that runs contrary to conventional understandings of presidential
power: precisely when powers of persuasion abandon them, when
presidential command over the legislative process reaches its low point,
presidents regularly strike out on their own, set vitally important
public policies, and leave it up to Congress and an incoming
administration to try and recover an old status quo.
References
Anderson, John. 2002. Unsigning the ICC. Nation, April 29, p. 7.
Arnold, Anthony. 2003. Trial by fire: The International Criminal
Court pushes ahead. Harvard International Review 24(4): 11-12.
Becket, Elizabeth. 2003. U.S. suspends aid to 35 countries over new
international court. New York Times, July 1, p. 12.
Bond, Jon, and Richard Fleisher. 1990. The president in the
legislative arena. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.
Brace, Paul, and Barbara Hinckley. 1993. Activities from Truman
through Reagan: Timing and impact. Journal of Politics 55(2): 382-98.
Brauer, Carl. 1986. Presidential transition: Eisenhower through
Reagan. New York: Oxford University Press.
Burke, John. 2000. Presidential transitions: From politics to
practice. Boulder, CO: Lynne Rienner Publishers.
Burnett, Jason, and Robert Hahn. 2001. EPA's arsenic rule: The
benefits of the standard do not justify the costs. Washington, DC:
AEI-Brookings Joint Center for Regulatory Studies.
Cannon, Carl. 2001. The Long goodbye. National Journal, January 27,
p. 274.
Cochran, Jay. 2001. The Cinderella constraint: Why regulations
increase significantly during post-election quarters. Unpublished
report, George Mason University, Fairfax, VA.
Cohen, Jeffrey, and George Krause. 1997. Opportunity, constraints
and the evolution of the institutional presidency: The issuance of
executive orders, 1939-1996. Unpublished manuscript.
Combs, Nancy Amoury. 2001. Carter, Reagan, and Khomeini:
Presidential transitions and international law. Hastings Law journal
52(January): 303-439.
Cooper, Phillip. 1986. By order of the president: Administration by
executive order and proclamation. Administration & Society 18(2):
233-62.
--. 1997. Power tools for an effective and responsible presidency.
Administration & Society 29(5): 529-56.
--. 2002. By order of the president: The use and abuse of executive
direct action. Lawrence: University Press of Kansas.
Dudley, Susan. 2001. Reversing midnight regulations. Regulation, p.
9.
Henry, Laurin. 1960. Presidential transitions. Washington, DC:
Brookings Institution Press.
Howell, William G. 2003. Power without persuasion: The politics of
direct presidential action. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.
--. 2005. Power without persuasion: Rethinking foundations of
executive influence. In Presidential-politics, edited by G. Edwards.
Belmont, CA: Wadsworth.
Howell, William, and David Lewis. 2002. Agencies by presidential
design. Journal of Politics 64(4): 1095-114.
Johnston, David. 1992. Bush pardons 6 in Iran-Contra Affair,
aborting a Weinberger trial. New York Times, December 24, p. A1.
Jones, Charles. 1994. The presidency in a separated system.
Washington, DC: Brookings Institution Press.
--. 1998. Passages to the presidency: From campaigning to
governing. Washington, DC: Brookings Institution Press.
--, ed. 2002. Preparing to &president: The memos of Richard E.
Neustadt. Washington, DC: Brookings Institution Press.
Kaiser, Jocelyn. 2001. Second look at arsenic finds higher risk.
Science 293(5538): 2189.
Koh, Harold Hongju. 1990. The national security constitution:
Sharing power after the Iran-Contra Affair. New Haven, CT: Yale
University Press.
Krause, George, and David Cohen. 1997. Presidential use of
executive orders, 1953-1994. American Politics Quarterly 25 (October):
458-81.
Krause, George, and Jeffrey Cohen. 2000. Opportunity, constraints,
and the development of the institutional presidency: The case of
executive order issuance, 1939-1996. Journal of Politics 62 (February):
88-114.
Krutz, Glen, Richard Fleisher, and Jon Bond. 1998. From Abe Fortas
to Zoe Baird: Why some presidential nominations fail in the Senate.
American Political Science Review 92(4): 871-81.
Kumar, Martha, and Terry Sullivan, eds. 2003. The White House
world: Transitions, organization, and office operations. College
Station: Texas A&M University Press.
Leigh, Monroe. 2001. The United States and the statute of Rome.
American Journal of International Law 95(1): 124-31.
Lewis, Neil. 2002. U.S. is set to renounce its role in pact for
world tribunal. New York Times, May 5, p. 18.
Light, Paul C. 1994. The president's agenda: Domestic policy
choice from Kennedy to Clinton. Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University Press.
Marquis, Christopher. 2002. U.S. is seeking pledges to shield its
peacekeepers from tribunal. New York Times, August 7, p. 1.
Mayer, Kenneth. 1999. Executive orders and presidential power.
Journal of Politics 61 (2): 445-66.
--. 2001. With the stroke of a pen: Executive orders and
presidential power. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.
Mayer, Kenneth, and Kevin Price. 2002. Unilateral presidential
powers: Significant executive orders, 1949-99. Presidential Studies
Quarterly 32(2): 367-86.
Mayhew, David R. 1991. Divided we govern: Party control, lawmaking,
and investigations, 1946-1990. New Haven, CT: Yale University Press.
Moe, Terry, and William Howell. 1999a. Unilateral action and
presidential power: A theory. Presidential Studies Quarterly 29(4):
850-72.
--. 1999b. The presidential power of unilateral action. Journal of
Law, Economics, and Organization 15(1): 132-79.
Mueller, John. 1973. War, presidents and public opinion. New York:
Wiley.
Pfiffner, James P. 1996. The strategic presidency: Hitting the
ground running. Lawrence: University of Kansas Press.
Pianin, Eric. 2001. White House won't fight monument
designations. Washington Post, February 21, p. A7.
Rabkin, Jeremy. 2002. Don't tread on us: How to handle the
International Criminal Court. Weekly Standard, May 20, pp. 11-13.
Ruckman, P. 1993. The Supreme Court, critical nominations, and the
Senate confirmation process. Journal of Politics 55(3): 793-805.
Rudalevige, Andrew. 2002. Managing the president's program:
Presidential leadership and legislative policy formation. Princeton, NJ:
Princeton University Press.
Scheffer, David. 2002. A treaty Bush shouldn't unsign. New
York Times, April 6, p. 15.
Segal, Jeffrey. 1987. Senate confirmation of Supreme Court
justices: Partisan and institutional politics. Journal of Politics
49(4): 998-1015.
Shull, Steven A. 1997. Presidential-congressional relations: Polity
and time approaches. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press.
Stimson, James. 1976. Public support for American presidents: A
cyclical model. Public Opinion Quarterly 40(1): 1-21.
Sunstein, Cass. 2002. The arithmetic of arsenic. Georgetown Law
Journal 90(7): 2255-309.
Swaine, Edward. 2003. Unsigning. Stanford Law Review 55(5):
2061-89.
/// (Republican) transitions, we can fairly attribute these bursts
of activities to something more than just standard regulatory processes.
As Susan Dudley notes, "Of course, some of these so-called
midnight regulations may have been developed carefully over many years,
in a rulemaking process that just happened to have culminated during the
final months of the administration. But certainly others were hurried
into effect without the usual checks and balances, and may cater to
special interests rather than the public interest." (30) As an
example, Dudley documents new Department of Energy standards mandating
minimum energy efficiency for air conditioners, heat pumps, and washing
machines that typically require upward of a decade to develop, but that
"hurtled through the regulatory process at lightning speed"
during the last couple of months of Clinton's administration.
Criticisms, of course, are easily cast at last-minute policy
making, both the directives themselves and the powers presidents deploy
to issue them. Nancy Combs, for instance, expresses concern that "a
democratic tension arises whenever a lame-duck office holder uses his
remaining days in office to advance policy objectives that he believes
his successor does not support." These directives lack the sort of
legitimacy that pre-election activity has, because by definition they
are issued after a president (and, in many cases, his party) has been
repudiated at the polls. Moreover, there are no opportunities for
democratic accountability, because, again, voters do not have a
subsequent chance to express their approval or disapproval. (31)
To engage this normative debate, however, is to concede a basic
fact that runs contrary to conventional understandings of presidential
power: precisely when powers of persuasion abandon them, when
presidential command over the legislative process reaches its low point,
presidents regularly strike out on their own, set vitally important
public policies, and leave it up to Congress and an incoming
administration to try and recover an old status quo.
References
Anderson, John. 2002. Unsigning the ICC. Nation, April 29, p. 7.
Arnold, Anthony. 2003. Trial by fire: The International Criminal
Court pushes ahead. Harvard International Review 24(4): 11-12.
Becket, Elizabeth. 2003. U.S. suspends aid to 35 countries over new
international court. New York Times, July 1, p. 12.
Bond, Jon, and Richard Fleisher. 1990. The president in the
legislative arena. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.
Brace, Paul, and Barbara Hinckley. 1993. Activities from Truman
through Reagan: Timing and impact. Journal of Politics 55(2): 382-98.
Brauer, Carl. 1986. Presidential transition: Eisenhower through
Reagan. New York: Oxford University Press.
Burke, John. 2000. Presidential transitions: From politics to
practice. Boulder, CO: Lynne Rienner Publishers.
Burnett, Jason, and Robert Hahn. 2001. EPA's arsenic rule: The
benefits of the standard do not justify the costs. Washington, DC:
AEI-Brookings Joint Center for Regulatory Studies.
Cannon, Carl. 2001. The Long goodbye. National Journal, January 27,
p. 274.
Cochran, Jay. 2001. The Cinderella constraint: Why regulations
increase significantly during post-election quarters. Unpublished
report, George Mason University, Fairfax, VA.
Cohen, Jeffrey, and George Krause. 1997. Opportunity, constraints
and the evolution of the institutional presidency: The issuance of
executive orders, 1939-1996. Unpublished manuscript.
Combs, Nancy Amoury. 2001. Carter, Reagan, and Khomeini:
Presidential transitions and international law. Hastings Law journal
52(January): 303-439.
Cooper, Phillip. 1986. By order of the president: Administration by
executive order and proclamation. Administration & Society 18(2):
233-62.
--. 1997. Power tools for an effective and responsible presidency.
Administration & Society 29(5): 529-56.
--. 2002. By order of the president: The use and abuse of executive
direct action. Lawrence: University Press of Kansas.
Dudley, Susan. 2001. Reversing midnight regulations. Regulation, p.
9.
Henry, Laurin. 1960. Presidential transitions. Washington, DC:
Brookings Institution Press.
Howell, William G. 2003. Power without persuasion: The politics of
direct presidential action. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.
--. 2005. Power without persuasion: Rethinking foundations of
executive influence. In Presidential-politics, edited by G. Edwards.
Belmont, CA: Wadsworth.
Howell, William, and David Lewis. 2002. Agencies by presidential
design. Journal of Politics 64(4): 1095-114.
Johnston, David. 1992. Bush pardons 6 in Iran-Contra Affair,
aborting a Weinberger trial. New York Times, December 24, p. A1.
Jones, Charles. 1994. The presidency in a separated system.
Washington, DC: Brookings Institution Press.
--. 1998. Passages to the presidency: From campaigning to
governing. Washington, DC: Brookings Institution Press.
--, ed. 2002. Preparing to &president: The memos of Richard E.
Neustadt. Washington, DC: Brookings Institution Press.
Kaiser, Jocelyn. 2001. Second look at arsenic finds higher risk.
Science 293(5538): 2189.
Koh, Harold Hongju. 1990. The national security constitution:
Sharing power after the Iran-Contra Affair. New Haven, CT: Yale
University Press.
Krause, George, and David Cohen. 1997. Presidential use of
executive orders, 1953-1994. American Politics Quarterly 25 (October):
458-81.
Krause, George, and Jeffrey Cohen. 2000. Opportunity, constraints,
and the development of the institutional presidency: The case of
executive order issuance, 1939-1996. Journal of Politics 62 (February):
88-114.
Krutz, Glen, Richard Fleisher, and Jon Bond. 1998. From Abe Fortas
to Zoe Baird: Why some presidential nominations fail in the Senate.
American Political Science Review 92(4): 871-81.
Kumar, Martha, and Terry Sullivan, eds. 2003. The White House
world: Transitions, organization, and office operations. College
Station: Texas A&M University Press.
Leigh, Monroe. 2001. The United States and the statute of Rome.
American Journal of International Law 95(1): 124-31.
Lewis, Neil. 2002. U.S. is set to renounce its role in pact for
world tribunal. New York Times, May 5, p. 18.
Light, Paul C. 1994. The president's agenda: Domestic policy
choice from Kennedy to Clinton. Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University
Press.
Marquis, Christopher. 2002. U.S. is seeking pledges to shield its
peacekeepers from tribunal. New York Times, August 7, p. 1.
Mayer, Kenneth. 1999. Executive orders and presidential power.
Journal of Politics 61 (2): 445-66.
--. 2001. With the stroke of a pen: Executive orders and
presidential power. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.
Mayer, Kenneth, and Kevin Price. 2002. Unilateral presidential
powers: Significant executive orders, 1949-99. Presidential Studies
Quarterly 32(2): 367-86.
Mayhew, David R. 1991. Divided we govern: Party control, lawmaking,
and investigations, 1946-1990. New Haven, CT: Yale University Press.
Moe, Terry, and William Howell. 1999a. Unilateral action and
presidential power: A theory. Presidential Studies Quarterly 29(4):
850-72.
--. 1999b. The presidential power of unilateral action. Journal of
Law, Economics, and Organization 15(1): 132-79.
Mueller, John. 1973. War, presidents and public opinion. New York:
Wiley.
Pfiffner, James P. 1996. The strategic presidency: Hitting the
ground running. Lawrence: University of Kansas Press.
Pianin, Eric. 2001. White House won't fight monument
designations. Washington Post, February 21, p. A7.
Rabkin, Jeremy. 2002. Don't tread on us: How to handle the
International Criminal Court. Weekly Standard, May 20, pp. 11-13.
Ruckman, P. 1993. The Supreme Court, critical nominations, and the
Senate confirmation process. Journal of Politics 55(3): 793-805.
Rudalevige, Andrew. 2002. Managing the president's program:
Presidential leadership and legislative policy formation. Princeton, NJ:
Princeton University Press.
Scheffer, David. 2002. A treaty Bush shouldn't unsign. New
York Times, April 6, p. 15.
Segal, Jeffrey. 1987. Senate confirmation of Supreme Court
justices: Partisan and institutional politics. Journal of Politics
49(4): 998-1015.
Shull, Steven A. 1997. Presidential-congressional relations: Polity
and time approaches. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press.
Stimson, James. 1976. Public support for American presidents: A
cyclical model. Public Opinion Quarterly 40(1): 1-21.
Sunstein, Cass. 2002. The arithmetic of arsenic. Georgetown Law
Journal 90(7): 2255-309.
Swaine, Edward. 2003. Unsigning. Stanford Law Review 55(5):
2061-89.
WILLIAM G. HOWELL
Harvard University
KENNETH R. MAYER
University of Wisconsin
(1.) Bush granted pardons to Caspar Weinberger, Robert McFarlane,
Elliot Abrams, and three CIA officials.
(2.) Mayer and Price (2002) and Howell (2003) also find that
presidents issue more significant executive orders during the first year
of their administration when they succeed an incumbent of the opposite
party. Many of these orders amend, or overturn, actions taken by the
prior administration (more on this later) or direct policy initiatives
that the previous president refused to undertake.
(3.) These include, but are not limited to, fixed presidential
effects (occasionally interacted with divided government), indicators
for election years and the first years of a term, presidential
popularity, and a series of lagged versions of the dependent variable.
(4.) ACFs show a significant negative spike at the first lag, while
all subsequent lags are small and insignificant; PACFs begin large and
negative, but dampen steadily thereafter.
(5.) The first term refers to the autoregressive component, the
second to the moving average component, and the third to the variance of
the error term. For all regressions estimated, cumulative periodograms
show the residuals to be white noise. Nonetheless, we also estimated
numerous low-order alternatives to the (0, 1, 1) specification, each of
which generates results chat are consistent with those presented below.
(6.) To conserve space, estimates for the fixed effects are not
reported. Within each year, effects are largest during the spring,
summer, and fall months; over the course of each administration, the
production of presidential orders appears relatively constant; and while
Ford and Carter stand at the time series' apex, Bush (43) rests at
its nadir.
(7.) In addition to majority party size and divided government,
Howell (2003) also argues that newly elected presidents who replace
presidents of the opposite party will rely upon their unilateral powers
with greater frequency than will newly elected presidents of the same
party as their predecessor. When adding to the statistical models in
Table 2 an indicator variable for such presidents, or when comparing the
fixed effects for the two types of presidents, negative and
statistically significant results emerge. Unlike the results presented
in Table 2 of Howell's contribution to this volume, however, all of
the other findings included in the model remain unaffected by the
inclusion of this indicator variable.
(8.) For the most part, the results for the fixed effects also hold
constant--the one exception being year-of-term effects, which appear
significant and positive during year three.
(9.) Environmental Protection Agency, "National Primary
Drinking Water Regulations; Arsenic and Clarifications to Compliance and
New Source Contaminants Monitoring; Final Rule," 66 Federal
Register 6976-7066, January 22,2001.
(10.) Executive Office of the President, "Memorandum for the
Heads and Acting Heads of Executive Departments and Agencies," 66
Federal Register 7702, January 24, 2001.
(11.) In April 200l, the EPA delayed the rule again, until February
2002. 66 Federal Register 20580, April 23, 2001.
(12.) Julie Samuels, "DNC Sounds Off on First 100 Days,"
NationalJournal.com, April 30, 2001. Available from
http://nationaljournal.com/membersladspotlight/2001/04/0430dnc1.htm.
(13.) Natural Resources Defense Council press release, March 20,
2001. Available from http://www.nrdc.org/media/pressReleases/010320.asp.
(14.) Environmental Protection Agency, Final Rule, January 22,
2001, 7011.
(15.) EPA Final Rule, January 22, 2001, 7009.
(16.) EPA Final Rule, January 22, 2001, 7017.
(17.) Alternatively, the EPA could have used a
"sublinear" dose-response curve, which assumes that the risk
drops significantly below some threshold of exposure. See Sunstein
(2002, 2273).
(18.) During the summer of 2001, three separate expert reviews
supported the 10ppb standard. The EPA's Science Advisory Board
concluded in August 2001 that the original cost-benefit analysis had
underestimated the benefits of the lower standard. Environmental
Protection Agency, Arsenic Rule Benefits Analysis: An SAB Review. Review
by the Arsenic Rule Benefits Review Panel (ARBRP) of the U.S. EPA
Science Advisory Board, EPA-SAB-EC-01-008, August 2001. A National
Academy of Sciences update to its 1999 report reached the same
conclusion. National Academy of Sciences, Arsenic in Drinking Water:
2001 Update. Report from the Subcommittee to Update the 1999 Arsenic in
Drinking Water Report, Committee on Toxicology and Board on
Environmental Studies and Toxicology (Washington, DC: National Academies
Press, 2001). At the same time, The National Drinking Water Advisory
Council found EPA's cost estimates reasonable. NDWAC, Report of the
Arsenic Cost Working Group to the National Drinking Water Advisory
Council, August 14, 2001. Available from
http://www.epa.gov/safewater/ars/ndwac-arsenic-report.pdf.
(19.) State of Nebraska v. Environmental Protection Agency, 356
U.S. App. D.C. 410.
(20.) Congress enacted the Antiquities Act in 1906 to give the
president the authority to protect historically important archeological
sites from development. Clinton, though, used the act to create huge new
national monuments (most controversially, the Grand Staircase-Escalante
National Monument in Utah, covering 1.7 million acres) that critics
claimed went well beyond appropriate use. See Mayer and Price (2002) for
a description of some of these proclamations. This usage, "largely
obscure before Bill Clinton's invocation of it in the {1996} Grand
Staircase decision, the Antiquities Act achieved a degree of cultural
salience when it played a key role in an episode of the NBC television
series about the White House, The West Wing" (2002, 369).
(21.) See, for example, U.S. Congress, House Committee on the
Judiciary, Subcommittee on Commercial and Administrative Law, Executive
Orders and Presidential Directives. 107th Cong., 1st Sess., Serial no.
10, March 22, 2001; Carol Hardy Vincent and Pamela Baldwin, National
Monuments and the Antiquities Act, Congressional Research Service, RL
30528, April 17, 2000; Carol Hardy Vincent and Pamela Baldwin, Authority
of a President to Modify or Eliminate a National Monument, Congressional
Research Service, RS 20647, August 3, 2000; Todd F. Graziano, "The
Use and Abuse of Executive Orders and Other Presidential
Directives," The Heritage Foundation Legal Memorandum, No. 2,
February 21, 2001.
(22.) Proclamations 7392-99, January 17, 2001, and Proclamation
7402, January 20, 2001.
(23.) U.S. Congress, House Committee on Resources, National
Monument Fairness Act. Report 107-408, 107th Cong., 2d Sess., April 15,
2002.
(24.) Some administration officials urged Reagan to abrogate the
agreement, under the theory that it was negotiated under threat, and
therefore invalid. Other possibilities included "selective
implementation," although the Office of Legal Counsel concluded
that this was not a viable option (Combs 2001, 342-44).
(25.) Monroe Leigh, "The United States and the Statute of
Rome," American Journal of International Law 95, no. 1 (2001),
124-31.
(26.) "I will not, and do not recommend that my successor
submit the treaty to the Senate for advice and consent until our
fundamental concerns are satisfied." President Clinton,
"Statement on the Rome Treaty on the International Criminal
Court," Weekly Compilation of Presidential Documents, December 30,
2000, p. 4.
(27.) For a fuller analysis of this issue, see Swaine (2003).
(28.) PL 107-117, section 8173.
(29.) For other criticisms of the decision, see Arnold (2003) and
Scheffer (2002).
(30.) See Susan E. Dudley, "Midnight Regulations at All-Time
High," Intellectual Ammunition, March 1, 2001. Available from
http://www.heartland.org/Article.cfm?artId=99.
(31.) The political legitimacy of the second type of decision--as
distinct from the formal legal legitimacy--is certainly open to
question. Nevertheless, it is difficult to make blanket statements about
legitimacy unless we are prepared to divorce the concept from other
perhaps equally valid considerations-such as justice or fairness. It is
quite possible that a president could make an unpopular or politically
risky decision that happens to be fair.
William G. Howell is associate professor of government at Harvard
University and the author of Power without Persuasion: The Politics of
Direct Presidential Action (Princeton University Press, 2003). He has
written a variety of papers on presidential power, political
institutions, and education politics and policy. He is currently
finishing a book that examines congressional checks on presidential war
powers.
Kenneth R. Mayer is professor of political science at the
University of Wisconsin Madison. His book, With the Stroke of a Pen:
Executive Orders and Presidential Power (Princeton University Press,
2001), won the 2002 Neustadt Award, given by the APSA's Presidency
Research Group.