The intersection of fiscal and regulatory policy.
Batkins, Sam
The Hidden Cost of Federal Tax Policy
By Jason Fichtner and Jacob Feldman
262 pp.; Mercatus Center at George Mason University, 2015
[ILLUSTRATION OMITTED]
Paying taxes is a sufficient annoyance for most people. The time,
effort, countless forms, and accounting expenditures resulting from the
federal tax code are just a few of the many factors why scholars have
sought fundamental reform of the system. It isn't just the $2.5
trillion or so in taxes taken from corporations and individuals every
year, it's the $215 billion to $987 billion in various hidden costs
that makes federal tax policy anti-growth, anti-marriage, and--perhaps
most pervasively--pro-special interest.
In The Hidden Cost of Federal Tax Policy, Jason Fichtner and Jacob
Feldman survey the chief culprits behind flawed tax policy and offer key
principles for successful reform. Although not entirely focused on the
world of regulation, the ancillary components of current policy help to
generate the 200 forms and 2.6 billion work hours associated with the
individual income tax and the 235 forms and 2.8 billion work hours for
the business income tax. Fundamental tax reform could save the nation
billions of hours of paperwork and tens of billions of dollars in
monetary savings. Broken tax policy is more than just a conversation
about what is taken from a paycheck; it concerns what is taken from an
economy.
Estimating hidden costs / Unsurprisingly, there are varying
estimates for the benefits from reforming different components of
federal tax policy. The authors highlight how one component, accounting
costs, is driven largely by the more than 4,000 changes to the code from
2001 and 2010, including 579 in 2010. This accounting slate is
responsible for between $67 billion and $378 billion in annual burdens.
For what it's worth, the Internal Revenue Service estimates the
individual income tax costs $33.6 billion for Americans to navigate
annually. Astonishingly, there is no estimate for the monetary burdens
imposed by the business income tax, even though it generates more
paperwork and more forms.
The second hidden cost lies in the infamous "Tax Gap."
This is the difference between the revenue the IRS is permitted to
collect by law and what it actually collects. The authors note the Tax
Gap is roughly $450 billion--that is, clever (or deceptive) accounting
results in nearly a half-trillion-dollar underpayment. Why should the
average taxpayer care about the IRS's Tax Gap? For one, it creates
a social cost of inequitable tax burdens among some taxpayers; those
with more creative accountants and lobbyists tend to help create the
gap.
Finally, there are the economic costs of a broken tax system.
Again, estimates here vary wildly, between $148 billion and $609
billion. As former Supreme Court Chief Justice John Marshall noted some
200 years ago, "The power to tax is the power to destroy."
Taxes simply increase the cost of doing business, from buying materials
to paying for labor. The wide range for these economic costs derives
from the studies over the years trying to find an appropriate figure. On
the low-end, Soren Blomquist and Laurent Simula estimated in a 2010
paper the deadweight loss of tax compliance at $148 billion, after
accounting for income, payroll, and state income taxes. At the other
end, Martin Feldstein estimated $609 billion in deadweight losses with
the payroll tax and $388 billion without.
Breaking the code / The authors spend nearly as much time in the
book surveying the reasons the tax code is mindlessly broken as they do
offering solutions for rational reform. To no one's surprise,
lobbying plays a heavy role in creating tax credits, exemptions, and
deductions that Americans end up subsidizing. As the saying goes,
"If there is food at the picnic, ants will follow." Given the
size and scope of government, there is always plenty of food.
Fichtner and Feldman note that research reveals intense lobbying is
often effective. They write, "Businesses that increased lobbying
expenditures by 1 percent reduced their effective tax rates by 0.5 to
1.6 percentage points the following year." Diffuse costs,
concentrated benefits--if only we could all be so well-connected.
This lobbying extravaganza is often led by the plethora of lawyers
in Washington, D.C. The authors somewhat gleefully remind the reader
that there is a strong negative international correlation between the
number of law students and economic growth. Conversely, nations with a
high concentration of engineering students tend to have robust economic
growth. Regardless, we can all agree that focusing the nation's
attention on producing tax carve-outs, rather than actual production,
will do no favors for economic growth.
Who doesn't take tax breaks / Part of the problem with a
government of our size is that it intrudes into virtually every area of
life: subsidizing the purchase of a home ($69 billion) and health care
($185 billion), to name just two. Through the years, everyone has become
dependent on, or taken advantage of, favorable tax treatment created by
the code.
The mortgage interest deduction (MID) is singled-out for special
treatment, and rightfully so. If you live near a coast or in a major
city, it is likely one of your largest tax breaks; if you don't,
you're subsidizing large home purchases elsewhere. As the authors
note, less than one in 10 Americans earning less than $50,000 can claim
the MID. High-income earners net a tax benefit that is nine times larger
than tax filers earning between $50,000 and $100,000. Middle-income
Americans can thank the real estate industry for this inequity.
And yet, this deduction does little to advance its intended
function of promoting home ownership, which is a dubious goal of
government in its own right. Instead, the MID encourages more debt and
borrowing. Despite the deduction, the United States is nowhere near the
top for home ownership rates. That title belongs to Singapore at 87
percent, yet Singapore has no MID. The United States clocks in at 65
percent, slightly lower than the United Kingdom, which also doesn't
have a MID.
Reform / There are a million different proposals for reforming the
federal tax code, but Fichtner and Feldman spend just a few words on
broad reform principles: simplicity, equity, efficiency, and permanency.
In the utopian world where federal tax policy does undergo wholesale
reform, expect ancillary regulatory benefits as well. Consider that a 50
percent reduction in the IRS's paperwork burden would generate
roughly 4.5 billion hours in savings. Even assuming a conservative $20
per hour rate for IRS compliance, that would equal $90 billion in annual
savings.
Don't hold your breath for that, unfortunately. Yet, anyone
interested in learning the history of the current tax code and surveying
its failures would do well to review the work of Fichtner and Feldman.
READINGS
* "Marginal Deadweight Loss when the Income Tax Is
Nonlinear," by Soren Blomquist and Laurent Simula. Uppsala
University (Sweden), 2012.
* "Tax Avoidance and the Deadweight Loss of the Income
Tax," by Martin Feldstein. Review of Economics and Statistics, Vol.
81, No. 4 (1999).
SAM BATKINS is director of regulatory policy at the American Action
Forum.