Would expanded family leave hurt workers?
Batkins, Sam ; Brannon, Ike
A good many politicians have elevated the need to reduce income
inequality as the paramount purpose of economic policy in the immediate
future. There are many ways to pursue such a goal, of course, but the
easiest and most popular--at least of late--is to simply reduce the
income of the wealthy. Such a maneuver usually doesn't improve
anyone's well-being beyond government employees and contractors,
but it is a way for the government to demonstrate its dedication to The
Cause.
Another method that supposedly would reduce inequality--and one
that is becoming au courant--is to provide paid family medical leave to
new parents, adult offspring of infirm parents, or couples dealing with
other medical or family crises. It is a "socially responsible"
benefit and because it is already done in Europe, the thinking goes, it
ought to be done here.
The problem is that creating a new, expensive entitlement, at least
in this instance, is not necessarily a useful or productive way for
government to demonstrate its obeisance to the family. Mandating paid
family leave will result in sharply higher employment costs, and the
market will ultimately respond by either reducing employment, wages, or
some combination thereof, whether government finances the benefit or it
comes via a government man date. If not done correctly, it could also
create perverse incentives that might harm those most likely to use such
benefits.
D.C.'s experiment / Much like the states and localities that
have dramatically boosted their minimum wage to huzzahs from the
progressive crowd, Washington, D.C. has blazed its own path in its quest
to implement family leave. To its credit, the city council realized that
mandating that all businesses provide six months of paid leave to new
parents would provide a hardy incentive for businesses to avoid hiring
women of childbearing age, progressive or not. They came up with a
funding method that would avoid that hazard: impose a 1% profits tax on
all businesses in the city, regardless of the number of their employees
who availed themselves of the benefit, and use the revenue to subsidize
on-leave employees' income. This way the cost would be socialized
across all profitable businesses, with the government writing the check.
The problem that quickly surfaced was that a mere 1% tax
didn't go nearly far enough in funding the desired six months of
benefits. To provide workers with that much leave at something
approaching their pre-leave wages, the tax would have to be north of 3%.
At that rate, the city's normally somnolent Chamber of Commerce was
roused to action and prodded its members to stand together in opposition
to the tax, which was sufficient to force the District government to
retreat to "Plan B." They reduced the scope of the benefit,
kept the tax at 1%, and distracted the angry advocates of the benefit
with talk of a $15 minimum wage being next on the agenda.
Those are some of the costs, but surely the benefits of paid leave
justify the burdens, right? A family medical leave law would pass a
cost-benefit analysis? Probably not.
Costs / Many governments across the globe have determined that the
benefits of paid family leave are worth the significant regulatory and
fiscal costs they impose, but that begs the question: What would more
generous family leave practices cost the United States? Data from the
Organization for Economic Co-operation and Development detail how much
industrialized nations spend on family leave policies. Those data allow
us to roughly estimate the cost of the United States adopting mandatory
paid leave.
For this empirical comparison, we looked at the per-country
spending as a proportion of GDP in three different categories: paternity
leave, sick leave, and family medical leave. The United States spends
roughly 0.7% of gross domestic product (GDP) on family support, a broad
category that includes paternity and maternity leave. That percentage is
far smaller than what other developed countries spend on this category.
Sweden spends fully 3.6% of its GDP on family leave, more than five
times the U.S. ratio. Denmark's spending exceeds 4%, while the
Scandinavian average is 3.3%. To put that in perspective, defense
spending is less than 1.3% of GDP for the Scandinavian countries, 40% of
what it allocates to family leave. The OECD average expenditure for
family support is 2.2%.
While the United States may be a laggard when it comes to family
leave, it spends a bit more on sick leave policies, a category that
includes disability pensions, paid sick leave, and other
incapacity-related benefits. Such spending comprises roughly 1.4% of
GDP, which amounts to $260 billion a year. That is still well below the
OECD average of 1.9% of GDP, and miles away from the vaunted
Scandinavian social support. Norway devotes nearly 3.3% of its GDP to
sick leave and Sweden spends even more.
The OECD does not report any data on maternity leave for the United
States, in part because such benefits--if captured--show up in the sick
leave data. According to the data, the OECD average expenditure for paid
parental leave is 0.38% of GDP; Sweden spends roughly three-quarters of
a point of its GDP on parental leave, compared to 0.62% for Norway and,
surprisingly, just 0.29% for France.
If the United States were to devote the same proportion of GDP to
sick leave as the rest of the OECD, it would require an additional $90
billion. To match the largesse of Norway and Sweden, the figure would
need to be closer to $350 billion. For the United States to reach
European levels of family leave support as a proportion of the economy,
it would cost more than $520 billion annually. To match OECD spending
for maternity and parental leave alone would be at least $70 billion
annually--twice that to match Swedish-level generosity.
These figures comport with other studies on the costs of expanding
family leave rules, which estimate minimum spending amounts ranging from
$159 billion to $306 billion. For example, the "FAMILY Act,"
sponsored by Rep. Rosa DeLauro (D-Conn.) and Sen. Kirsten Gillibrand
(D-N.Y.) and designed to provide 12 weeks of paid family leave, would
finance the benefit through a 0.4% payroll tax hike. However, this tax
increase would only finance about $30 billion in new annual spending,
not nearly enough to cover the designed benefits. For many Americans,
paid family leave sounds like a wonderful perk until they realize
they're the ones who would pay for their own benefit.
Benefits / Since providing families with paid leave would cost so
much money, we should expect similarly outsized benefits. However, there
is little evidence that it would do so.
Proponents of paid family leave point to studies showing that it
can lead to improved maternal health and declines in depression
symptoms. That would not only improve well-being but also reduce health
care costs associated with these issues, most of which are currently
borne by taxpayers. Proponents also argue that paid leave should
contribute to higher labor force participation rates, and in turn higher
output, perhaps to the extent that it could almost pay for itself by
generating higher tax revenue.
Quantifying how paid leave might affect health outcomes is
exceedingly difficult, so we will devote our attention to labor force
participation rates, especially considering that many of the benefactors
of paid leave would be higher-income households.
California and New Jersey both enacted some form of paid leave
legislation in the last decade; however, neither state experienced a
sizeable increase in female labor force participation rates. In fact, in
both instances, female participation rates declined, matching an overall
trend in the economy. That does little to bolster the argument that
family leave significantly increases the labor force.
[ILLUSTRATION OMITTED]
Looking nationally, the U.S. female labor force participation rate
stands at 57%, slightly below the pre-Great Recession peak of 60%, but
still well above the OECD average of 51.5%. Scandinavia's average
is about 10 percentage points higher.
The rapid increase of women working in the U.S. economy in the
second half of the 20th century was an unmitigated good for the economy
and society, but it's unreasonable to expect it to ever increase at
that rate again. First, women's skills and training have changed
drastically since the mid-1900s: today, women are on average more
educated than men and have a better employment history. Part of the
economic boom created by the entrance of women into the labor market
owed to the fact that not only was there an increasing proportion of
women entering the labor market, but the average skill level of working
women increased concomitantly.
What's more, the overt and systemic discrimination against
women even entering the workforce that prevailed in mid-20th-century
America has largely disappeared. Women who enter the labor market today
are more likely to obtain jobs that make the best use of their skill
set.
Finally, the simple fact that the female labor force participation
rate today is already at a high level means that it's difficult to
see the rate increasing anywhere near its trend in the last century. The
decades-long secular decline in the men's labor force participation
rate, which is currently just below 70%, or 13 percentage points above
women, suggests a rough upper-bound for women's rates. What's
more, we live in a world where the female rates have essentially
stagnated for the last two decades.
The Affordable Care Act (ACA), the latest social welfare expansion
in the United States, was supposed to boost the U.S. economy by ending
"job lock" and allowing workers to go where they would be most
productive. To some degree it achieved this, although the manifestation
of this freedom--a rise in what has come to be pejoratively called the
"gig economy," referring to the increasing number of
short-term projects, consultancies, and other limited
"gigs"--has given its authors heartburn. The ACA also
effectively incentivized millions of Americans to leave the labor force
because the legislation provides them--for better or worse--the means to
obtain affordable health insurance without holding a job.
Claiming that another social welfare expansion--one that would
reduce wages and employment as well as create a deadweight loss--can
somehow drive increases in GDP is nonsensical. There are numerous
policies that would drive GDP growth and increase participation rates,
but they don't rely solely on further welfare spending--most of
which would go to the welloff--changing the dynamics of the U.S. labor
market.
Other people's money / Enacting generous parental support
policies would doubtless have benefits for families. But these benefits
would primarily accrue to higher-income families and could potentially
cost upwards of 3% of GDP. If one parental leave policy could boost
labor force participation rates to rarified Scandinavian territory and
add more than 12 million people (the result of a 10% increase in female
labor force participation) to the workforce, these benefits might
justify the costs. Unfortunately, there is little evidence that this
would be the result of paid family leave, and it is hard to contemplate
any economy-wide benefit that would remotely approach the costs inherent
in such a policy change.
Making sound economic policy involves the government making
priorities and recognizing the opportunity costs of certain actions, but
it's been awhile since Congress or the White House acknowledged the
true underlying costs of its actions. For instance, the final floor
speech in support of the ACA touted it as the greatest deficit reduction
piece of legislation to ever pass through Congress, despite the fact
that it will ultimately necessitate Congress spending hundreds of
billions of dollars a year. The supposed cost savings were ephemeral at
best and non-existent in reality. Similarly, in 2016 Congress passed tax
legislation that made a plethora of temporary "tax extenders"
permanent with nary a discussion of whether permanence made more sense
than simply lowering tax rates for individuals or small businesses.
A statistic that has received almost as much attention as the
expanding wage gap--at least among labor economists--has been the
shrinking ratio of wages to GDP. After remaining remarkably stable for
practically the entire 20th century, this ratio began trending downward
and--unlike in other such instances--it shows no signs of regressing
toward the mean. For capital to take an increasing share of total income
strikes many as a disturbing trend, and there have been numerous
proposals to try to "rebalance" the two.
The problem is that it isn't simply the case that capital is
receiving a greater share of national income. Rather, a steadily growing
share of the portion allocated to labor goes toward paying for benefits.
This has occurred both because the cost of providing
benefits--especially health insurance--has gone up as well as the fact
that government has prodded firms to provide more in the way of non-wage
benefits.
While it may seem that asking employers to provide workers with
paid time off to take care of an infirm parent or a sick child is the
compassionate thing to do, there is no free lunch. The cost of this will
largely be borne by the workers, no matter what mechanism is used to
finance the benefit. There is no particular reason to think that such a
benefit would be progressive--middle and upper-middle class workers will
be more likely to have employment covered by such a provision than
low-income Americans. If we base the payment for the worker who takes
leave on his or her salary, then it will almost assuredly be a
regressive benefit.
Mandating more paid leave changes the composition of our
compensation further away from wages and salary and more toward
benefits, with the bulk of those benefits going to the middle class and
above. We are hard-pressed to embrace this as a compassionate solution
to what ails the American economy.
SAM BATKINS is director of regulatory policy at the American Action
Forum.
IKE BRANNON is a visiting fellow at the Cato Institute and
president of Capital Policy Analytics.