Bennett Hypothesis 2.0.
Gillen, Andrew ; Archibald, Robert B. ; Feldman, David H. 等
In their recent Regulation article, Robert Archibald and David
Feldman revisit the "Bennett Hypothesis": the idea, promoted
by former federal secretary of education William J. Bennett, that
increases in federal financial aid lead to higher tuition. ("Does
Federal Aid Drive College Tuition?" Summer 2016.) They argue that
the "federal financial aid system is not a significant driver of
the tuition bill at the nation's nonprofit colleges and
universities," but the for-profit sector does exhibit stronger
evidence of the Bennett Hypothesis.
For almost 30 years, the evidence on the Bennett Hypothesis has
been all over the place. Given this mixed evidence, I've argued
elsewhere that "'Is the Bennett Hypothesis true?' is the
wrong question as it has no consistent answer. The better question is,
'When does the Bennett Hypothesis hold or not hold, and
why?'" So I am pleased that Archibald and Feldman avoid the
common mistake of being Bennett Hypothesis zealots or deniers.
But they do go wrong in their selection of the model to explain the
mixed evidence. They follow an "enrollment management model"
that builds upon the observation that "unlike most firms, nonprofit
colleges and universities often turn away business. They care about who
purchases their services." If these colleges prioritize enrolling
the "best-possible incoming class," it is relatively
straightforward to show that these schools will often forgo the
opportunity presented by an increase in federal aid to raise tuition
because allowing students to keep some of the aid--instead of jacking up
tuition to harvest those government dollars-helps in attracting
high-quality students.
Their model isn't necessarily wrong as a description of what
colleges try to do in enrolling a class. But that isn't the issue
they are investigating. Rather, they are seeking to explain the
empirical evidence on the Bennett Hypothesis, and for that their model
isn't helpful.
Violating an assumption / The first problem with Archibald and
Feldman's argument is that to explain the empirical evidence, their
model needs to violate one of its foundational assumptions.
Their model starts with the assumption that "the revenue needs
[of the college] are set first ... and the tuition-setting and admission
decisions are made together afterward." This is the AT* x E* amount
in their Figures 1-3: the product of multiplying a school's average
tuition revenue by its enrollment. Basically, their model assumes that
there is a predetermined amount of tuition revenue that schools need to
raise from their students. Colleges will then recruit the best students
possible subject to the condition that this class of students must, in
aggregate, pay this predetermined tuition revenue. As Archibald and
Feldman point out, this doesn't mean that each student pays the
exact same amount (AT*). Rather, students whom the college wants to
attract (e.g., those with high academic or athletic potential) will
often be offered discounts/scholarships in the hopes of enticing them to
enroll. Other, less desirable students will be charged more than average
to finance those discounts.
When federal aid is offered, the empirical evidence clearly
indicates that colleges have a range of different "tax" rates,
Archibald and Feldman explain. By "tax," they refer to a
college decreasing the discounts/scholarships it gives a student from
its own funds when the student gets federal aid. This way, schools can
harvest the federal funds without harming their original, intended
enrollments.
The problem for Archibald and Feldman is that they misinterpret
what their model implies about these "tax" rates. They claim
that the "enrollment management model offers no firm prediction
about the tax rate an institution might choose." This is false. The
model explicitly assumes that tuition revenue is fixed. The only tax
rate that leaves tuition revenue unchanged is 0%. Any tax rate greater
than zero will result in an increase in tuition revenue. This oversight
appears to be based on confusion between tuition revenue (what the
college receives) and net price (what the student pays). They
acknowledge that with a hypothetical 100% tax rate (every $ 1 increase
in federal aid leads to a $1 decrease in college aid), "the
institution would get a tuition windfall," but then they change
topics to focus on net tuition: "But notice that in neither case
would the student see a higher list price or net price." The
"tuition windfall" result violates the assumptions of their
model, without which the prediction of no increase in net price has no
basis.
In other words, Archibald and Feldman are trying to explain the
empirical evidence of greater than zero "tax" rates with a
model that is only internally consistent with its own assumptions if the
"tax" rate is zero. They need to find a model that can explain
the evidence without violating its own assumptions.
For-profits/ A number of studies find that the Bennett Hypothesis
does hold for for-profit colleges. Archibald and Feldman explain that
this isn't a strike against their model because for-profits do not
try to enroll the best possible class, and therefore their "model
is not a good description of how for-profit schools operate. These
schools maximize revenue in the short run and profits in the long
run." They then note, with more than a touch of irony, the
"greedy colleges" that would react to increases in the
generosity of federal financial aid by hiking tuition tend to be found
in the for-profit sector, which is the most market-oriented segment of
the higher education industry.
But step back for a moment and recognize how bizarre the evidence
is: the producer is able to capture a large portion of the subsidy. This
would be like if the government offered a $1 subsidy per loaf of bread,
and the result was that bakeries increased the price of bread by roughly
$1. While such a price increase would be possible in the short term if
there are capacity constraints (if each bakery is already producing the
most bread it can), the extra revenue from higher prices would translate
into unusually high profits, which would then attract entrepreneurs to
build new bakeries. The competition from these new bakeries would drive
down the price of bread until profits were no longer unusually high. In
the long run, we would expect for the consumer to pay $1 less for bread,
which combined with the $1 subsidy would leave bakery profits unchanged
(assuming a perfectly elastic long-run supply curve).
Yet the empirical evidence shows that this doesn't happen in
the for-profit college sector. For-profit colleges are able to raise
prices even in the long run. It would be like if the original bakeries
were able to raise prices by $ 1 and keep them there indefinitely. Thus,
even though Archibald and Feldman correctly argue that the enrollment
management model doesn't apply to for-profits because for-profits
do not seek to enroll the best possible class, they still can't
explain why we see convincing evidence of the Bennett Hypothesis among
for-profit colleges. (Elasticity arguments cannot salvage this result
either, as supply in the for-profit sector, which uses scalable online
courses heavily, is likely to be very elastic in long run).
One possible explanation for the for-profit results that would be
consistent with Archibald and Feldman's argument is the
"90/10" rule. This rule dictates that no more than 90% of a
college's revenue can come from federal financial aid programs. But
colleges can't control how much federal aid a student gets (the
government determines this), so a good case can be made that these
colleges have to set their price above the level of federal aid. For
example, if the government is giving each of a college's students
$90 in federal aid, then the college needs to charge tuition of at least
$100 to comply with the 90/10 rule. This implies that an increase in
federal aid would lead to a corresponding increase in tuition,
explaining the evidence showing the Bennett Hypothesis occurs at
for-profit colleges. I actually think there is a lot of truth to this
story, but if so, then Archibald and Feldman's schadenfreude about
for-profits being "greedy" seems more than a little misplaced
as their behavior is driven by compliance with government policies.
A better model? / Archibald and Feldman are on the right track in
seeking a "structural model" that accounts for the goals of
colleges, but perhaps there is a better model that is more consistent
with both the "tax rate" and for-profit evidence. My own
research leads me to the conclusion that Howard R. Bowen's Revenue
Theory of Costs, better known as Bowen's Laws, provides the basis
for a better structural model, in part because it doesn't assume
away the revenue goal like the enrollment management model does. Indeed
Bowen's Laws treat the determination of revenue as a central
question to be answered by the college. According to Bowen:
* The dominant goals of institutions are educational excellence,
prestige, and influence.
* In quest of excellence, prestige, and influence, there is
virtually no limit to the amount of money an institution could spend for
seemingly fruitful educational needs.
* Each institution raises all the money it can.
* Each institution spends all it raises.
* The cumulative effect of the preceding four laws is toward ever
increasing expenditure.
As I detail in "Introducing Bennett Hypothesis 2.0," a
policy paper available from the Center for College Affordability and
Productivity, this theory does a good job of explaining the mixed
evidence. Colleges want more tuition revenue, so when federal aid is
given to their students, they will be tempted to either raise tuition or
cut back on their own discounts/scholarships. But their goal is not
revenue maximization; it is prestige maximization, which means that
sometimes other considerations (e.g., maintaining selectivity) will
preclude the college from choosing to harvest all the federal aid by
raising tuition or cutting their own scholarships/ discounts. The mixed
evidence that we've seen over the past 30 years is therefore
exactly what we'd expect.
In summary, Archibald and Feldman are right in seeking a more
structural model and in highlighting the importance of changes in
college-provided discounts/ scholarships as opposed to only focusing on
listed tuition. (This is a great insight that many scholars, including
myself, have not adequately appreciated in the past.) But their
enrollment management model does not help explain the evidence on the
Bennett Hypothesis. Models building off of Bowen's Laws do a better
job of explaining the evidence, and therefore offer a much more
promising path for future research.
Andrew Gillen
Washington, D.C.
Reply
We thank Andrew Gillen for his thoughtful comments on our recent
paper. We have two reactions that highlight where we concur and where we
don't. First, we agree that structural modeling is crucial in
helping analysts and policymakers alike understand the complex ways that
federal policy affects tuition in the diverse American higher education
system. But we disagree with his contention that our model's
foundational assumptions make it unsuitable for analysis of the Bennett
Hypothesis. Secondly, Gillen argues that the "revenue theory"
is a better alternative to our enrollment management approach. In our
view, the revenue theory suffers from serious methodological flaws. We
will describe a few of them in this short reply.
Gillen claims that our enrollment management model is flawed
because "to explain the empirical evidence, [our] model needs to
violate one of its foundational assumptions." This is not correct.
Our foundational assumption is that "the size of the institution is
set." This is a standard assumption in microeconomics when we
explain short-run behavior of firms. The assumption about size implies a
given physical plant, a certain faculty, and a certain amount of
expenditures to deliver programming. The institution uses historical
information from past applicant classes and information from the current
applicant pool to attract the highest-quality class that meets its goals
for number of students and tuition revenue per student. Discounting is
the key tool. Some schools use it primarily to meet revenue needs while
more elite programs use it to sculpt the highest-quality incoming class.
If there is a change in federal financial aid policy, we assume
that the institution does not immediately change its size. We are still
doing short-run microeconomics. The change in policy means that the
institution's revenue options have changed. Our model points out
the many ways an institution may react to its new opportunities. Indeed,
one possibility is that it will earn more revenue from its students.
When we point out this possibility, we are not violating our
foundational assumptions. The institution's initial assessment of
the revenue it needs from its students was conditioned on its size, its
programming, the quality of the students it hoped to attract, and the
amount of tuition discounting required to hit its initial objectives.
The change in federal financial aid policy affects the amount of
tuition discounting that is required to hit these initial objectives, so
it is perfectly sensible for the institution to adjust the amount of
revenue it extracts from its students. As we suggested, the institution
might use this golden opportunity to increase the quality of its
programming by spending more per student. But it also might choose to
pass the increased subsidy on to poorer students as a lower net price.
It is a fair criticism of our approach that we do not fully model
what each category of college or university will do. In our defense, we
were writing down a descriptive account of an abstract school's
options, not a mathematical model for professional economists. It's
also fair to note that we do not fully describe the process by which the
institution sets the quality of its programing, its long-run size, or
its aspirations for student talent, all of which determine its initial
revenue needs. These are tasks for another day and a more technical
approach.
With regard to for-profit schools, Gillen thinks it bizarre that
they might see increased profits from more generous federal policy. He
believes that competition between schools would eliminate the rents they
could collect. If higher education is highly competitive and the number
of seats available to students expands elastically with demand, then the
Bennett Hypothesis makes no sense for any type of school. We would note
that in the large nonprofit sector there is good evidence that the
number of seats has indeed grown rapidly as demand has surged. But there
is no obvious reason to presume the industry is perfectly competitive.
Many for-profits likely have local market power that could allow them to
push up price in the event that the federal subsidy grows. The empirical
work on the Bennett Hypothesis that uses some structural model of
university behavior (at nonprofits and for-profits alike) usually
presumes that schools can exercise some form of market power.
Local market power may be eroded in a fully online world, and fully
online training is growing fastest in the for-profit sector. But 60% of
students at for-profit institutions currently experience a fully
face-to-face education. And many fully online programs deliberately keep
classes small to ensure some degree of personalization and brand
differentiation. Lastly, the "90-10" rule, requiring that 10%
of school revenues come from sources other than federal funds, is not
likely the driver of the Bennett Effect at for-profits, since most
for-profits are distant enough from the 90% threshold that they would
not be forced to increase tuition just to remain in compliance with the
federal rules.
Gillen's suggestion that Howard Bowen's revenue theory of
cost would provide a better model is not at all appealing to us. In
fact, Gillen's own discussion of the revenue theory illustrates how
it is internally inconsistent. One of Bowen's Laws is "Each
institution raises all the money it can." Yet Gillen says,
"But their goal is not revenue maximization." In other words,
to use this theory, one has to violate one of its laws.
More generally the revenue theory of costs is based on a tautology.
All nonprofit institutions spend as much revenue as they earn. We tested
and critiqued the revenue theory in earlier work ("Explaining
Increases in Higher Education Costs," Journal of Higher Education,
Vol. 79 [May/ June 2008]). In brief, the revenue theory is a higher
education specific theory. It claims that the driving factor shaping the
long-term evolution of higher education costs is higher education
revenue. Yet many other industries display a very similar evolution of
cost over time. If higher education revenues are the force driving
higher education costs, then it must be a coincidence that costs in many
other industries have behaved so similarly. In our view, features the
industries share in common likely drive the similar behavior of cost. In
our last book on college cost, Why Does College Cost So Much?(Oxford
University Press, 2011), we show that the industries whose price growth
looks most similar to higher education tend to be personal services, not
goods, and most personal services have experienced very slow labor
productivity growth.
The tendency for service prices to grow more rapidly than goods
prices is well known. It can be traced back to the work of David Ricardo
in the 19 th century, and in higher education it's called
Baumol's cost "disease." (See William Baumol and Sue Anne
Blackman, "How to Think About Rising College Cost," Planning
for Higher Education, Vol. 23 [Summer 1995]). Any industry that
experiences slower productivity growth than the national average is
likely to experience higher than average price growth because that
industry still must pay national wage rates for its labor, but without
the cost-reducing benefit of high productivity growth.
Second, in many personal services the workforce is highly educated
compared to the national average. This is quite true in higher
education. When the premium on educated workers is growing, all
industries with a highly educated labor force face extra cost pressures.
The wage premium on college-educated labor has grown steadily since the
early 1980s. Lastly, many personal service industries do not just adopt
new technology when it lowers cost. They are driven to adopt new
techniques because their service must evolve to meet new needs, even if
this raises cost. In higher education, much like in medicine, an
evolving standard of care drives the adoption of new and often expensive
technologies. These three broad economic forces that have reshaped the
global economy offer a story for why higher education costs have risen
more rapidly than the overall inflation rate.
Robert B. Archibald
David H. Feldman
College of William & Mary