The meaninglessness of the SEC pay disclosure rule.
Brannon, Ike ; Batkins, Sam
A lawyer in Illinois recently billed a client for working 180 hours
in a week. The client paid the bill, even though a week is only 168
hours long. The client wasn't being foolish--he knew how many hours
are in a week. Instead, he saw value in paying the lawyer for what he
asked. After all, the lawyer had just produced a major, hard-fought
victory.
The case involved a construction firm that was facing bankruptcy.
The company approached its largest unsecured creditor, which was the
main bank in the community, and asked for another loan. The firm secured
the loan by pledging its trucks, inventory, and equipment. Shortly
thereafter, it went bankrupt and the bank took over the assets to cover
not only its secured debt, but also its earlier, unsecured loans.
That's not supposed to happen; unsecured creditors go to the back
of the line when it comes to divvying up assets.
The trustee in bankruptcy asked a few top law firms to take on the
case against the bank, but they demurred; suing the biggest financial
institution in the area was not for the faint of heart, and none saw
much of a chance for a great payday. But one lawyer leapt to take the
case. He secured the job by suggesting to the trustee that if it could
be demonstrated that the bank made the final loan solely to get its
hands on assets to cover the unsecured loan, the bank would have to
disgorge every dime it took from the construction firm and pay penalties
to boot.
He won the case and the trustee recouped millions of dollars from
the bank, an order of magnitude more than he ever conceived he would
recover for the other debtors. After the ruling, the bankruptcy judge
convened a short hearing to wrap up loose ends and approve the
trustee's expenses. When the judge noted the lawyer's bill
included a week when he billed 180 hours, the trustee made it clear he
would not object to that or any other item in the bill. The judge
approved it. The trustee said the fee went beyond saying "thank
you" for a job well done: he wanted to pay his lawyer a decent fee
to let the rest of the bar know that he would take care of anyone
willing to take on a big bank or who did more than just go through the
motions and rack up hours.
[FIGURE 1 OMITTED]
It is an apt analogy for executive pay: boards (and shareholders)
have every reason to reward chief executives and other officers who take
over moribund companies and dramatically improve their value. To jump on
a sinking ship can be a career-ender for an executive. Boards should
want to reward CEOs who take on such challenges and succeed not only as
a way to show their appreciation, but also to provide a tangible signal
that the next guy who pulls off this trick for them will also be amply
rewarded.
CEO compensation disclosure rule / The problem in executive
compensation is that there are plenty of CEOs who receive outsized
rewards for merely minding the store. And, of course, there are examples
where CEO pay resembles crony capitalism and sizeable bonuses are
completely unnecessary to retain the current CEO or attract a talented
successor. Much of that pay represents an expense that produces nothing
for the stockholder.
Despite the advent of new analytical measures of performance and a
pause in CEO compensation growth (CEO pay growth has slowed dramatically
in the last decade, as shown in Figure 1), Congress apparently thought
that the private sector needed more help on this issue. The Dodd-Frank
Financial Reform Act of 2010 tasked the Securities and Exchange
Commission to implement a rule requiring corporations to regularly
publish the ratio of their CEOs' compensation (including benefits
and bonuses) to the median compensation of their work forces.
While it may seem churlish to object to merely asking firms for one
more datum, this piece of information is all but useless in shedding
light on the issue. Whether a CEO makes 20,200, or 2,000 times as much
as the median compensation of the firm's employees provides no
particular insight as to whether a CEO is fairly compensated.
For example, a company that operates retail outlets will have a
host of workers earning the minimum wage. How does comparing its CEO pay
ratio to a company that outsources all low-skilled jobs to service
companies provide useful shareholder information? A similar issue arises
when comparing a financial services company with thousands of branches
across the country to another financial services company with no retail
outlets. By this metric, the active retailer will seem grossly overpaid
compared to the New York City investment bank CEO, regardless of salary
or performance.
Perhaps we should exclude retail employees in this instance, or
else impute a reasonable number of them for the investment bank to make
this metric compelling. Or, more logically, the SEC should just do away
with such a flawed measure altogether, as common sense would dictate.
The pay-ratio statistic is also susceptible to manipulation and
creates incentives Congress could never have intended. For instance, a
few years ago food-maker Sarah Lee's CEO, Brenda Barnes, spun off
all of its bakeries, choosing to contract out all production and focus
its attention on marketing and research. In one fell swoop, the
CEO-median worker compensation ratio plummeted. Did it go down too much?
What are the relevant companies to compare its pay ratio now? How would
the ratio inform investors in any worthwhile way? Besides, if the CEO
pay ratio would prove to be a meaningful metric to investors, CEOs would
have more of an incentive to contract out any activities primarily done
with low-wage workers. Is this necessarily a good thing?
Large costs, small benefits / Another problem firms may face when
trying to calculate the CEO pay ratio is that it necessitates compiling
data in a way that most companies are not accustomed to doing. As a
result, it will require companies to expend some effort (and resources)
to calculate it. Major corporations do not typically centralize payroll
operations; if a company owns several divisions that are working fine,
it often leaves them alone with such arcane issues such as meeting
payroll. They may no longer have this luxury.
Computing compensation--as opposed to just wages--makes this even
more difficult. It requires examining health insurance costs, pension
costs, and every other fringe benefit provided, and then ascribing a
portion of the cost to each employee. There's no "quick and
dirty" way to do it--the value of health insurance depends greatly
on an employee's age and family situation, and of course pension
benefits vary with income and tenure for most defined benefit plans.
Companies that have operations overseas where the government
provides a large degree of health care need to think about how to
attribute that to their compensation costs. Generally, income taxes are
higher in places with more generous public health benefits. That
suggests that a company needs to consider those tax costs when trying to
calculate the compensation of its median employee. The provision
specifically includes all overseas workers, so there's no skirting
the issue. Some multinationals operate in dozens of countries, and
compiling data on all forms of employee compensation, dealing with
third-party administrators, and then converting those figures into a
pointless ratio for regulators makes for an expensive annoyance.
Real costs and virtually zero benefits to the company add up to a
rule that flunks any bona fide cost-benefit analysis, but that is of
little concern to Congress and the SEC. However, it may turn out to be a
bigger concern to the courts. By law, SEC regulations must promote
capital formation, increase efficiency, or facilitate investor
protection. It's almost impossible to argue with a straight face
that any of those goals are advanced by this rule.
The SEC's Proposal and Request for Comments sheepishly admits
that it likely contains no notable benefits. It states, "Neither
the statute nor the related legislative history directly states the
objectives or intended benefits of the provision or a specific market
failure." It also frankly admits the possible absence of any
tangible benefits.
The projected compliance costs are large: one group of trade
associations estimates it would cost roughly $7.6 million per company to
compile a satisfactory pay ratio, or nearly $30 billion in total for the
3,830 companies estimated to be covered by the provision. Even if one
assumes average compliance costs of $250,000 per firm, there are still
annual costs to the economy approaching $1 billion.
[ILLUSTRATION OMITTED]
Not surprisingly, the SEC's cost estimates are much lower, as
the agency only quantified the paperwork costs of outside professionals
to derive the pay ratio. The SEC estimates that the rule would impose
545,792 annual hours of paperwork (which works out to 190 hours per
company) and $72.7 million in costs. Those figures differ from the trade
associations' by a couple orders of magnitude. Given the paucity of
analysis supporting the SEC's estimates, our hunch is that the
actual number hews closer to the industry estimate.
Low-balling compliance costs isn't unusual for the SEC.
Consider the agency's "conflict minerals" rule, which was
also promulgated in accordance with Dodd-Frank. Under the rule, firms
are required to report whether their products were manufactured using
minerals extracted in the Democratic Republic of Congo or nearby areas,
where valuable minerals are mined and sold to fund military conflict.
The SEC originally estimated that the rule would impose 153,000 burden
hours and $71 million in costs on firms, but after an avalanche of
complaints the agency raised the estimates to 2,225,273 burden hours and
$4.7 billion in total costs. That's a 650 percent increase. But
even if the SEC's initial estimate for the compensation ratio rule
proves to be the final figure, it would still be the ninth most
expensive Dodd-Frank rule to "fix" an issue that in no way
contributed to the financial crisis.
Baseball's dilemma / Paying salaries above what the market
would dictate is a problem that afflicts more than the executive suite.
Major League Baseball clubs have been dealing with this problem for
decades, though it became especially acute during the early free market
era before the advent of advanced performance metrics.
For instance, in the 1990s the Chicago Cubs had an outstanding
right side of the infield in future Hall of Fame second baseman Ryne
Sandberg and three-time all-star first baseman Mark Grace. In 1993,
Sandberg became the highest-paid player in baseball, signing a contract
worth $6 million a year. The next year, the team gave Grace a similar
contract after his agent argued that since Grace's offensive
numbers were similar to Sandberg's, he deserved a similar salary.
But it was an erroneous comparison. Second base is a defensively
vital position, and throughout baseball history there have been only a
few players who could both play the position well and hit for power.
Sandburg was one of them, as attested by his nine Gold Gloves (awarded
to the league's best defensive player at each position), seven
Silver Sluggers (league's best offensive player at each position),
10 All-Star Game appearances, and his 1984 National League Most Valuable
Player award. According to the advanced baseball statistics website
FanGraphs, between 1984 and 1994, Sandberg's play gave his team
almost twice as many wins as his closest National League counterpart.
Grace, on the other hand, was a singles hitter playing a position
normally manned by a power hitter (though Grace was a good fielder,
winning three Gold Gloves). In his prime, he was only a
slightly-above-average hitter for a first baseman, yet his pay put him
above most of his first base peers.
Today, most teams would not dream of paying a singles-hitting first
baseman any where near the salary of a power-hitting, slick-fielding
second baseman (witness Robinson Cano's mammoth new contract with
the Seattle Mariners). Teams have access to much more sophisticated
statistics that capture a player's true contribution to his team,
such as Wins Above Replacement (WAR) or Weighted On-Base Average (mOBA),
than they did two decades ago. Using those measures, it is hard to
justify playing Grace regularly at first base, let alone paying him a
superstar's salary. Few teams would do so today.
But despite our ability to precisely quantify a player's
performance, there are still many players who earn much more than their
contributions on the field can justify. Consider the most recent
contracts for the New York Yankees' Alex Rodriguez (10 years,
$252.87 million) and Alfonso Soriano (eight years, $136 million) and the
Los Angeles Angels' Alex Pujols (10 years, $240 million).
What's the point of grumbling about those? It's that
paying CEOs what they truly deserve is an even more difficult than
paying ballplayers. Many of the metrics used (such as comparing one CEO
to his peers in the same industry or of companies the same size) are
facile and easy to manipulate, not unlike the data baseball agents
torture in their quest to get big paydays for their clients. The
economist Richard Thaler once observed in the New Republic that there is
no business in the world where employers can measure the performance of
their workers as precisely as baseball. We're hard-pressed to name
an industry that is more competitive than the major leagues. If those
guys regularly end up awarding contracts that overpay players, perhaps
we should acknowledge that fairly compensating talented individuals is
difficult.
Metrics for CEO performance/There is a need for baseball-like
advanced statistics to provide a better understanding of the true value
of a CEO. Fortunately, this analysis is already happening, as various
economists and companies that work on executive compensation issues have
devised metrics that aim to capture CEO performance as well as ways to
connect compensation to performance.
For baseball players, there is no single metric that can fully
capture value. The aforementioned WAR is the one most commonly used by
today's analysts, along with a variety of new metrics that attempt
to capture defensive performance. Likewise, analysts who try to capture
a CEO's contribution focus on earnings growth, revenue growth, and
returns, all of which have a strong correlation with Total Shareholder
Return (TSR). A recent study by Farient Advisors suggests that earnings
growth (whether earnings per share, net income, or operating income) had
the highest correlation to shareholder value across industries.
However, those metrics don't work quite the same for every
industry. For instance, energy, banking, and pharmaceuticals showed a
particularly low correlation between earnings growth and TSR, which can
be attributed in part to the difficulties in predicting future value in
early-stage life sciences companies, as well as the inherent uncertainty
faced by industries subject to considerable regulatory oversight.
It's a difficult task, of course: while we may have better measures
of company performance these days, the extent to which we can attribute
a company's long-term profits to the CEO's performance is
still (and will always be, at least for most industries) difficult or
impossible to discern.
Using rules to "send a message"/The point of forcing
firms to calculate and publish the CEO-median worker compensation ratio
is, of course, to generate outrage in the hope that it will provoke a
lower ratio. But it's unclear how this helps workers, and that is
the relevant issue.
Why have unions been the most fervent advocates for this regulation
since Congress first contemplated its inclusion in Dodd-Frank? Do unions
expect that companies will lower this ratio by boosting median wages? If
so, it is difficult to conceive why that would happen. It will always be
cheaper for a firm to lower the ratio--if it ever did find it expedient
to do so--by reducing the CEO's compensation. And if it lowers CEO
compensation, there is no reason to think that the savings would be used
to increase the pay of rank-and-file employees, whose wages are largely
dictated by the local labor market. Besides, it's more likely the
firm would lower this ratio through subterfuge of some sort--perhaps by
jettisoning low-paid workers or deferring a CEO's compensation
until he leaves. The most likely outcome of the rule is no change in
firm behavior whatsoever, except that they will be forced to expend
effort and resources to calculate a statistic that will be of no use to
them, their boards, their shareholders, or investors.
SEC rules are not meant to serve as an ideological bulletin board
for whatever political party happens to be in power. But that's
precisely what the authors of the CEO pay ratio rule had in mind: it is
intended to convey a message that CEOs are paid too much.
There's some evidence that the courts have a jaundiced eye for
such political shenanigans. In January, lawyers arguing over the
validity of the conflict minerals rule before the Court of Appeals for
the District of Columbia suggested that the regulation is primarily
intended to be a "shaming statute" or "scarlet
letter" freighted with ideological intent, and that it serves no
public purpose. The court seemed inclined to agree with that
perspective.
Mandating the regular publication of a crude gauge of relative CEO
compensation is a costly exercise that fixes precisely nothing.
IKE BRANNON is a senior fellow at the George W. Bush Institute and
president of Capital Policy Analytics, an economic consulting firm based
in Washington, D.C. SAM BATKINS is director of regulatory policy at the
American Action Forum.