FDA misses the mark with food labeling rules: there is little evidence that the new labels will improve Americans health.
Scharff, Robert ; Abdukadirov, Sherzod
As the battle to trim American waistlines heats up, the U.S. Food
and Drug Administration has joined in the fray with not one, but two
rules aimed at improving the nation's diet. The rules constitute
the biggest change to the Nutrition Facts label in over two decades.
Despite the comprehensiveness of the effort, the fact that the
rules were built on poor analysis makes it unlikely they will curb
obesity or improve public health. Like the whole grain biscuits and
unappetizing vegetables that are being forced onto the lunch trays of
unhappy schoolchildren, the FDA's efforts should end up in the
trash (or at least a recycling bin).
The FDA proposed the rules based on the authority granted by the
Nutrition Labeling and Education Act of 1990 (NLEA) to regulate how
information is displayed on food products. The first of the proposed
rules, the Food Labeling rule, includes a laundry list of potential
changes that are designed to "assist consumers in maintaining
healthy dietary practices." The changes required are numerous,
involving both formatting and content changes to labels, increases in
recordkeeping, and new analytic requirements.
The second rule, the Serving Size rule, focuses on labeling changes
affecting food packages that hold a small number of servings.
Specifically, the rule requires that foods in packages that contain less
than 200 percent of "reference amounts customarily consumed"
(RACC)--that is, small packages that are nonetheless larger than a
traditional serving size--must nonetheless be labeled as single-serving
containers, while food packages with 200-400 percent of RACC must employ
a dual labeling format that gives nutrition information for both amount
per serving and amount per package. Additionally, the rule defines new
RACC for a number of products and gives a new serving size for breath
mints, among other small changes.
Together, the two rules result in major changes in how nutrition
information is conveyed to the American public, resulting in billions of
dollars in new costs, much of which will ultimately be passed on to
consumers. It is disturbing that the agency made only a halfhearted--and
ultimately failed--attempt to determine whether those costs are
justified by corresponding benefits to the public.
WHY REGULATE?
The FDA gives two reasons to justify the proposed regulations.
First, the FDA argues that it needs to update the Nutrition Facts label
requirements with regard to recommended Daily Values (DV) and serving
sizes. This is a laudable goal given the advancements in nutritional
science over the last two decades. For example, the rule updates the DV
for fiber based on a recent Institute of Medicine (IOM) "Dietary
Reference Intakes" report. The new value is set at the level
associated with the greatest reduction in risk of coronary heart
disease. Similarly, serving sizes are updated to reflect amounts that
people consume today, as opposed to what was consumed in decades past.
Second, the FDA claims that food labels are not currently designed
to promote ideal healthy behaviors. The agency points out that while
many consumers report using the label, they find some of its information
confusing. Consequently, the FDA claims that improving the label's
design could potentially improve consumers' ability to understand
and use the label, which, if successful, would ultimately lead consumers
to make healthier food choices.
On their face, these appear to be sensible changes. A nutritional
label updated to reflect the most recent science would provide consumers
with more accurate information, help consumers make healthier food
choices, and potentially reduce certain disease risks associated with
deficiencies in key nutrients. Nevertheless, the science supporting the
many provisions of these rules is uneven and, in some cases,
nonexistent. Further, there is no effort to assess whether the benefit
from each provision is justified by its cost.
Changing the label design / The Food Labeling rule proposes
numerous changes to the way information is displayed on the label. In
the accompanying regulatory impact analysis (RIA), the FDA relies on the
growing behavioral economics literature to justify some of the proposed
label changes. FDA-cited studies claim that consumers fail to think
through the long-term health implications of their food choices when
they purchase highly caloric foods with poor nutritional value. They
blame consumers' myopic decisionmaking for the growing obesity
problem. The FDA reasons that it is not enough to simply inform
consumers; the label format must also persuade them to make healthier
choices.
[ILLUSTRATION OMITTED]
The FDA hopes that, by increasing the salience of the information
presented on the label, the proposed rule may help consumers to improve
their decisionmaking and increase their use of nutrition facts. For
example, the FDA assumes that making calorie information more prominent
would influence consumers to pay attention to the caloric content of the
food. Similarly, it assumes that disclosing added sugars would alert
consumers if chosen foods are high in energy and poor in nutrition, and
lead consumers to reconsider their choices.
While the FDA cites some general behavioral economics research, it
cites no studies to support its assumption that myopic behavior causes
consumers to overlook information provided by the current nutrition
label. In addition, the agency does not explain how its proposed changes
would counter consumers' myopia. If consumers ignore the
information presented on the current nutrition label because they fail
to account for the long-term effects of their diets, would they not
ignore any additional or reformatted information on the new label?
In fact, an FDA-commissioned study finds that increasing the font
size for calories had no effect on consumers' choices. Contrary to
the FDA's assumption, increasing the prominence of calorie
information did not make it more salient to consumers and did not lead
to healthier choices. Nevertheless, the FDA decided to proceed with its
proposal to increase the prominence of calories on the label.
Beyond that single study, the agency cites no empirical evidence in
support of the remaining label changes. The FDA justifies the changes by
claiming that the improved design would increase label comprehension and
use. While it references a product design manual in support of this
claim, the agency does not test whether its new label actually improves
consumers' comprehension or leads to healthier choices. Similarly,
the FDA cites research that shows consumers' confusion over serving
size information, yet it does not test whether its new serving size
declaration improves consumers' comprehension.
Demonizing added sugar I One of the most prominent changes to the
Nutrition Facts label proposed by the FDA is the requirement for
mandatory declaration of "added sugars." The FDA classifies
added sugars as "sugars and syrups that are added to foods during
processing or preparation." The added sugars line would be inserted
in the label under the line for total sugar content. The agency
justifies the requirement by claiming that added sugars serve as the
main source of calories for youths. The FDA points out that, in contrast
to foods with natural sugars, foods with added sugars are generally not
good sources of vital nutrients. Further, it claims that added sugars
may be displacing other nutrients or leading to overconsumption of
calories.
The FDA provides little evidence that adding a separate line for
added sugars would yield any health benefits. The IOM "Dietary
Reference Intakes" report states that "added sugars are not
chemically different from naturally occurring sugars." As the FDA
points out, "Neither the 2010 [Dietary Guidelines for Americans
(DGA)] nor the IOM macronutrient report concluded that added sugars
consumption from all dietary sources, in itself, increases
obesity." Similarly, the 2010 DGA states that added sugars do not
increase obesity more than any other source of calories. Consequently,
information related to added sugars is not a material fact and there is
little reason for the FDA to require disclosure of different types of
sugars.
To the degree that sugars add to calorie consumption or increase
the risk of dental problems, the current nutrition label already
provides such information on its "Sugars" line. While it is
possible that displaying added sugars may prompt consumers to examine
the nutritional value of the product, the FDA provides no evidence that
this will be the case. In contrast to other proposed nutrition label
modifications, the FDA did not test whether providing information on
added sugars would lead consumers to healthier food choices.
In addition, consumer responses to the disclosure may lead to
unintended consequences. For example, several studies found that foods
with "low-fat" labels may lead to excess consumption and
increased obesity. The perceived healthfulness of the low-fat products
reduced guilt associated with excess consumption. It also increased what
consumers perceive to be an appropriate serving size. Similarly,
consumers opting for products low in added sugars may increase overall
consumption, as they would feel less guilty about eating such products.
Additionally, consumers focusing exclusively on added sugars may
overlook the overall sugar content and fail to constrain total sugar
intake.
It is crucial that the FDA ensures that the label's additional
content leads to better health outcomes before mandating its inclusion
on the nutrition label. Including content that does not help consumers
make healthier choices may crowd out more vital content on the label and
confuse consumers about their choices.
WHERE ARE THE BENEFITS?
In 1994 President Bill Clinton issued Executive Order 12866
requiring regulatory agencies to assess the costs and benefits of major
rules in RIAs. This was a sensible measure designed to ensure that each
major provision of enacted regulations improved social welfare. Of
course, reliable benefits estimates for each rule provision are
necessary if these types of analyses are to have any value. In the case
of the labeling rules, the benefits estimates are completely without
merit. Thus, it is impossible to assess the value of the rule, both as a
whole and in its parts.
The FDA's method used to estimate benefits is both
theoretically and empirically flawed. Specifically, the analysis is
based on results from a single unpublished paper that estimated the
benefits of the introduction of regulations from the NLEA. The results
of this study are not sufficiently clear, are not correctly interpreted
in the RIA, and are incorrectly extrapolated to assess benefits from the
proposed rules. Most importantly, the analysis fails to convey an
understanding that, while the NLEA was characterized largely by the
introduction of new information, the rules proposed here largely
reformat and rescale information.
Use of a flawed study / The cornerstone of the benefit calculations
for both rules is a working paper by Jason Abaluck titled, "What
Would We Eat If We Knew More? The Implications of a Large-Scale Change
in Nutrition Labeling." The paper sought to estimate the benefits
to consumers from the adoption of regulations written to comply with the
NLEA. The paper assesses the effects of label use on consumption
patterns both before and after labeling rules went into effect, finding
that consumption of high-calorie foods declined relative to
lower-calorie foods following the introduction of labeling. It derives
estimates of the economic value of those changes in nutrient
consumption.
There are a number of limitations to this study that were not
discussed in the RIA. First, the study, which is the source of the FDA
benefits estimates, is unpublished and has not been subjected to peer
review. This is especially significant because the author used a novel
approach to estimate consumers' valuations. Data limitations often
require the use of a study that has not been through the normal
peer-review process. But when an unpublished study is of such importance
to an RIA, the agency should urge the author to publish the study or
seek outside reviewers to assess the legitimacy of the paper.
Second, the Abaluck study introduces a bias into the results by
limiting the sample to women aged 19-50 who are the primary meal
preparers in their households. Yet, a recent study by Nicholas Jay
Ollberding, Randi Wolf, and Isobel Contento shows that women are
significantly more likely to view nutrition facts panels than men (72.8
percent vs. 49.5 percent). Thus, any effect of labels on calorie
consumption is artificially inflated by the choice of sample. Although
it might plausibly be argued that men are less likely to be primary meal
preparers, it is also undoubtedly true that some men are primary meal
preparers and others make their own food choices for meals and snacks.
Additionally, the study makes a number of assumptions without
documented support in its effort to derive estimates of economic
benefits from the NLEA. As a result, it is impossible to assess the
validity of the study conclusions. The reliance of the FDA on such a
flawed study does not instill confidence. Still, the problems with the
Abaluck study are minor relative to problems with the FDA's use of
data from the study.
Faulty extrapolation of results in the RIA / The biased and flawed
Abaluck study is the primary source for the estimated benefits used to
justify both proposed labeling rules. To work this minor feat of magic,
the FDA assumes that the proposed rules' impact would be similar to
the original NLEA regulation. The agency then calibrates the Abaluck
study's estimates by accounting for the differences between the
proposed rules and the NLEA. The FDA acknowledges that the new rules
will likely have a smaller effect because they will make fewer changes
to the nutrition label.
This is an irredeemably flawed approach for a number of reasons.
First, the Abaluck study estimates used in the RIA are not complete or
accurate, compounding the problems noted in the previous section. More
importantly, the means used to scale estimates from the Abaluck study
are entirely without scientific merit. Additionally, there are questions
about the measurement of other components of the analysis. Putting
scientific rigor aside, this approach assumes that all the provisions of
both rules can be evaluated using one unitary measure, making the
assessment of individual provisions nearly impossible.
The FDA uses two estimates of the annual monetized benefit per
person from NLEA labeling--$40.60 and $33.40. Updated to reflect current
income, the mean annual per-capita welfare benefit from the NLEA is $58.
However, the FDA omits without comment two other Abaluck model estimates
with lower values--$32.10 and $28.30--potentially inflating the proposed
rules' benefit estimates.
The RIA then scales the Abaluck study estimates to produce the
benefit estimates for the proposed rules. How this is done is
imaginative, but without scientific basis. The FDA starts with the
assumption that the NLEA rule changed 100 percent of the label content
to achieve its health effect valued at $58. The agency then estimates
that the proposed rules would change 33 percent of the physical content
for single-column labels and 25 percent of the content for dual-column
labels. The FDA therefore extrapolates that the proposed rule's
effect would be 33 percent of the NLEA rule's impact for
single-column labels and 25 percent for dual-column labels.
Putting aside the obvious question of why adding a second column
would result in less change, no attempt is made to describe how the
proportion changed is measured. Does it include changes that prohibit
disclosures or just those that mandate new disclosures? More
importantly, the FDA uses a measure based entirely on quantity of
change, not quality. According to this model, one could replace the
nutrition facts label with a label of equal size containing the lyrics
from Led Zeppelin's "Dazed and Confused," resulting in
benefits equivalent to those generated by the NLEA. Perhaps recognizing
the absurdity of this model, the FDA uses the estimates generated from
it as an upper bound, with benefits uniformly distributed between zero
and the estimated values. The lower bound benefits estimate of zero,
however, is the only estimate with any basis in reality.
Marginal benefits of the rule's distinct provisions / It is
easy to let the problems with the model used by the FDA obscure a more
fundamental problem with the RIA. The FDA approach outlined above
assumes that all the provisions of both rules can be evaluated using one
unitary measure. In fact, that makes the evaluation of separate
provisions (required by the Office of Management and Budget) nearly
impossible.
There are dozens of distinct provisions to the rule, but none are
explicitly examined. For example, as noted above, the RIA fails to
explain the benefits of requiring "added sugars" to be
disclosed on labels. The Food Labeling rule notes that there is a
"lack of a physiological distinction between added and naturally
occurring sugars," but the added-sugar information is being
required anyway. Conversely, the RIA fails to explain the benefit of
removing "calories from fat" from the label. Abaluck noted,
"I estimate a small willingness to pay to avoid calories which
appear to be due mostly to a willingness to pay to avoid fat." This
suggests that the removal of this label component may adversely affect
consumer choice. Also, updating serving size may create new anchors for
larger portions, leading to increased calorie consumption. Failure to
assess the rules' provisions in terms of marginal costs and
marginal benefits makes it impossible to determine which of the large
number of individual provisions have benefits that justify their costs.
The costs associated with these rules are substantial, amounting to
$2.3 billion according to the FDA. The methods used to estimate this
figure, however, are not transparent, with many apparently speculative
assumptions used for major cost categories. Furthermore, several cost
categories are simply omitted. Not included in the FDA's estimates
are costs to government for enforcing the rule, costs to industry from
changing package sizes in response to the rule, and recordkeeping costs
to suppliers of ingredients that have added sugars included. There is
also no indication that the FDA considered the larger changes required
of labels for dietary supplements.
ARE THERE ALTERNATIVES TO REGULATION?
In its proposal, the FDA considers four other policy alternatives
to the proposed rule, but the proposals are largely just minor
variations of each other. In reviewing this list of options, it is
apparent that the FDA did not take seriously EO 12866's mandate to
evaluate alternatives.
The first option--issuing no new regulation--is dismissed in two
sentences. This presumes the regulation is necessary, which, as
discussed above, is far from clear. The agency would have to perform
evidence-based analysis, perhaps based on FDA pilot projects, to
demonstrate that issuing no regulation would not be preferable.
The remaining options, which differ primarily in compliance time,
have measured consequences for costs but not for benefits. While
differences in compliance time represent important policy alternatives,
there surely are other policy alternatives that the FDA could have
considered. Moreover, given that this RIA covers two rules and there is
no guarantee that both rules will move forward, at a bare minimum the
FDA must evaluate the two rules separately.
In addition, for a large number of the provisions discussed in the
proposed rules, it appears that the agency is open to change based on
comment. The provisions most likely to be changed or with the highest
costs should be the ones examined formally. The inclusion of those
alternatives would provide decisionmakers with vital information about
the relative importance of classes of provisions.
Beyond the narrow range of alternatives, the rule fails to maximize
the net benefits for the five regulatory options discussed in the
analysis. At a 3 percent discount rate, the four-year compliance option
would provide $29.6 billion in net benefits, while the FDA's
preferred two-year compliance option would provide $29.1 billion in net
benefits. Yet the FDA does not explain its choice of a shorter
compliance time.
The FDA's analysis shows that a longer compliance time reduces
the rule's costs. Because manufacturers periodically update
nutrition labels for their products, the new labeling requirements could
be incorporated within these scheduled updates. Including the
rule's requirements as part of coordinated updates considerably
reduces manufacturers' compliance costs. An uncoordinated label
change would cost manufacturers $6,188 per product as opposed to only
$367 for a coordinated label change.
The longer manufacturers have to comply with the rule, the greater
the share of products they can include in coordinated updates.
Consequently, the two-year compliance option would cost $2.3 billion
while providing $31.4 billion in benefits. In contrast, the four-year
compliance option would cost $0.6 billion while still providing $30.2
billion in benefits. Thus, a two-year delay in the compliance date could
result in an almost four-fold cost reduction, while only marginally
reducing benefits.
The FDA should opt for a longer compliance time. Its benefit
estimates are highly flawed, based on questionable assumptions and a
single unpublished study. The agency provides little empirical support
that proposed changes would be effective. Consequently, the rule's
actual benefits are likely to be smaller. In contrast, the agency
provides considerably better (though by no means ideal) analysis of the
proposed rules' costs. The four-fold reduction in costs resulting
from a longer compliance time will reduce compliance costs to food
manufacturers. Because manufacturers will likely pass on the additional
costs to consumers, lower compliance costs will ultimately mean lower
prices for consumers.
CONCLUSION
The proposed rules aim to improve the accuracy and usability of the
nutrition label, but there is reason to be skeptical of that intended
outcome. Provision of more and better information to consumers is a
preferred strategy to improve consumer choice in the marketplace.
Specifically, a more accurate nutrition label will allow consumers to
make healthier food choices and will encourage adequate intake of vital
nutrients. Nevertheless, while the FDA makes a laudable effort to update
the nutrition label information according to the best available
scientific evidence, it provides little evidence that many of its
proposed label changes would have any beneficial health effects (as
opposed to the concrete costs associated with the rules). This lack of
scientific evidence makes benefits measurement impossible. Undaunted by
this impediment, the agency constructs benefits estimates based on a
single unpublished study and uses several flawed assumptions, all of
which put the validity of the estimates in doubt. Finally, the agency
fails to choose the regulatory option that would maximize net benefits
and considerably reduce the regulatory burdens on small businesses.
Before proceeding with the proposed rules, the FDA should ensure
that each of the provisions being required has tangible and measurable
benefits. If no such benefits can be identified, the provisions in
question should be put on hold pending further study. For those that do
have tangible benefits, the FDA should revise the RIA to provide
empirical support for the health effects of each proposed label change.
Further, the agency should reexamine its benefit estimates using
peer-reviewed studies. In estimating benefits, the FDA should rely on
the empirical studies clearly demonstrating the health effects of
proposed label changes. It should not simply assume that the proposed
rule would produce the same type of benefits as the NLEA rule. It should
also opt for longer compliance times to reduce the regulation's
effect on small businesses and reduce the costs passed on to consumers
in the form of higher prices. Finally, it should make plans to monitor
the rule's progress and effect on public health.
The FDA has a chance to improve the public health by increasing
consumers' comprehension and use of the nutrition label.
Unfortunately, the flawed analysis in the proposed rules makes it
unlikely the FDA has chanced upon an optimal labeling rule. Without
better analysis, the proposed rules will likely only add pages to the
Code of Federal Regulations but fail to shed pounds from the waistlines
of American consumers.
ROBERT SCHARFF is an associate professor in the Department of
Consumer Sciences at the Ohio State University. SHERZOD ABDUKADIROV is a
research fellow in the Regulatory Studies Program at the Mercatus Center
at George Mason University