The problem of water.
Libecap, Gary D.
Living with Water Scarcity
By David Zetland
124 pp.; Aguanomics Press, 2014
[ILLUSTRATION OMITTED]
As I write this, California is in the midst of a severe drought
that the National Climate Assessment Review claims is a consequence of
climate change (never mind that tree-ring data show that California long
has experienced severe drought). Water has always been important in the
West, but now it is one of the top political issues.
Challenges include how Co get urban users to conserve (e.g.,
replace landscaping with drought-tolerant varieties, install low-flush
toilets), augment urban supplies (e.g., desalinization, recycling),
shift some water use away from agriculture (where up to 80 percent is
now consumed), and protect natural habitats (e.g., instream flows,
endangered species, recreational use).
Those challenges can be addressed far more straightforwardly than
is evident in most of the policy discussions. Solutions lie in
strengthening existing private water rights, improving water
measurement, and defining groundwater rights and the hydrological links
between surface and groundwater use. Other possible steps include
providing trading platforms, streamlining the regulatory process for
water rights trading, and continuing adjustments in beneficial-use
requirements for maintaining water rights to include environmental
flows.
With clearly defined private rights, markets reallocate water to
meet new demands, communicate opportunity costs, signal scarcity, and
provide incentives for irrigators, urban dwellers, industrial users, and
environmentalists to moderate demand and invest in conservation.
Remedies can be quite simple because a water rights system is already in
place. We need only clarify those rights where they are ambiguous, as I
discuss below.
Unfortunately, this opportunity is not the one called for by
advocates for greater state intervention, regulation, and management.
For many, the public nature of water makes meeting resource challenges
through markets inappropriate, and hence the corresponding demand for
government action. Viewing water as a public resource rather than a
private one limits entrepreneurial solutions to the problem of water.
Pronouncing water a public resource places so many interests at the
policy table that few creative solutions emerge--there are too many
conflicting objectives and no clear way of arbitraging across them.
Gridlock and waste are the results. This is Michael Heller's
tragedy of the anticommons, whereby multiple gatekeepers block socially
productive results.
Water in the West/ Where does the public nature of water come from?
One source is that water is necessary for life, and in semi-arid and
arid regions communities congregate around water sources and only there
can natural habitats flourish. Hence, water supposedly is too critical
to be entrusted to markets. State ownership, distribution, and
management are the alternatives. These are the conditions faced in most
of the world and they provide many of the examples of corruption, waste,
and neglect that David Zetland cites in his new book, Living with Water
Scarcity.
A strong claim for the public nature of water was made in Joseph
Sax's influential 1970 Michigan Law Review article that called for
water to be a public-trust resource, an issue I examine below. Another
source is the recognition that multiple parties share the same water.
For example, under the "prior appropriation" doctrine that
grants water rights on the basis of time of claim in the U.S. West,
initial water diverters may consume 50 percent or less of it, with the
remainder percolating back to the source for subsequent use by others.
Changes in consumption reduce return flows, possibly affecting third
parties. This is the basis for regulation of water trades, and some
states like New Mexico accomplish this more smoothly than do others like
California where the process is more cumbersome.
The private nature of water arises because water is a productive
input into virtually every human activity, from food production, to
copper
mining, to Google Internet searches, to recreational fisheries and
river rafting. Water can be measured and bounded, though that can be
difficult because water is a fluid. Nevertheless, water can be
partitioned among competing uses so as to avoid open access and the
tragedy of the commons. Water can be traded. Where private water rights
exist, water is conserved and effectively used far better than where
private water rights do not exist, such as in many developing countries
where water is a communal or state-owned resource. Accordingly, the
problem of water is due to the lack of definition of water rights and
missing markets, rather than a fundamental, unique characteristic of the
resource.
Prior-appropriation water rights developed in the U.S. West through
first possession in the same manner as private rights to mineral and
agricultural lands. Claimants searched for stream locations where flows
would last through much of the year, filed for ownership of sufficient
water to meet their needs, and constructed diversion dams and ditches to
transport water.
The water had to be put to beneficial use so that excess remained
for others. Under this arrangement, mining and agriculture--the two
early sources of the region's economic development--grew. Mutual
ditch companies or irrigation districts were formed to coordinate
infrastructure investment. Later, the Federal Bureau of Reclamation
(BOR) provided dams, canals, and agricultural subsidies--a result of
interest-group politics. After 1926 the BOR could only contract with
irrigation districts for water delivery.
Urban areas also got into the act. Los Angeles built the Los
Angeles Aqueduct and later the Colorado Aqueduct to transport water to
the city, as did San Francisco from Hetch Hetchy. To obtain water, Los
Angeles bought water rights from farmers in the Owens Valley, an
exchange that has been misrepresented by critics of water markets. (See
"The Myth of Owens Valley," Vol. 28, No. 2.) California's
State Water Project largely is designed to bring water from the north to
the highly urbanized south. Water potentially can be bought and sold
along the system's vast infrastructure.
Rising urban use today, along with increased demands for
stream-flow maintenance, calls for movement of water from historical
agricultural uses to cities and the environment. Drought intensifies the
need for reallocation. This does not have to be a problem, however. More
water can be purchased. Unfortunately, what could be a straightforward
process has been made more difficult by the refusal of many advocates to
rely on existing water rights and by the failure of politicians and
agency officials to smooth the regulatory process. As a result, formal
water trades in California, for example, have been flat since roughly
2005 despite the drought, and throughout the West water marketing is far
more limited than one would expect.
Why is that? It is because too many parties want additional water
without paying for it, an objective legitimatized by the public trust
doctrine. Accordingly, water does not flow routinely from one use to
another through markets as demands and supplies shift. The failure to
rely on markets means that opportunity costs are not fully reflected in
new calls for environmental flows, in construction of desalinization
plants and other supply-augmentation capital, and in farm planting and
urban development decisions. Moreover, incentives for conservation or
investment in water quality are diminished. Not all water would leave
agriculture, but water of lower marginal value would move to other
applications.
Missed opportunities/ In his book, Zetland had an opportunity to
clarify the policy debate because he generally understands water and he
writes well and engagingly. But it is an opportunity that was missed.
Living with Water Scarcity is a short book of water parables--so many
are presented that they do not explain Zetland's points well, and
some that stress community ownership are both confused and unhelpful.
In the best part of the book, "Water for You and Me,"
Zetland examines private water uses, particularly urban water and the
problems encountered when monopoly urban water supply organizations fail
to price water effectively. He points to the absurdity of the Southern
Nevada Water Authority in Las Vegas underpricing water while at the same
time paying households to use less. He might have placed more emphasis
on the power of pricing as evidenced in Phoenix and Tucson, where
residents in Phoenix face flat prices and use over 50 percent more water
per capita than do people in Tucson who face steep block-pricing
schedules. One city looks like an oasis, whereas the other looks like
the desert city it is.
Chapters 1-4 provide valuable arguments about why urban water
management seems so out of sync with new supply and demand conditions
and offer suggestions as to what might be done to improve things.
Chapter 5, "Food and Water," and Chapters 6-10 in the second
part of the book, "Water for Us," are far less carefully
argued or thought out. Here Zetland allows the public nature of water to
confound potential private solutions. Despite earlier criticisms of
bureaucrats and politicians for inefficient water pricing,
infrastructure investments, and distortive water subsidies, he is far
too quick to call for community management of water in line with the
public trust. The community is never defined, and why politics fails in
one case but not another is not explained.
In Chapter 5, Zetland describes his strongest policy
recommendation: farmers should be required to buy and sell water through
an auction process so that they bear the full opportunity costs of the
water they use. Minimum environmental flows are to be deducted following
the recommendations of scientists, and the remaining water should be
auctioned. On first glance, that all seems great, but then many
objections come to mind. First, how will scientists weigh the value of
competing uses or opportunity costs? A lack of cost-benefit analysis
already occurs under the Endangered Species Act and few would find
expansion of this practice a useful approach for water. Second, farmers
are not the source of the problem. They are aware of opportunity costs,
and most would be pleased to sell or lease water that could earn them
more than they generate from agricultural production. Indeed, farmers in
the Palo Verde Irrigation District in California have done just that by
selling options to San Diego to draw on some of their water during
drought-induced shortages.
The ability to trade water makes opportunity costs and scarcity
values apparent to existing rights holders. Where agricultural trades
have been blocked or made very costly arises when water rights are not
clearly defined and community approval is mandated. This has occurred in
the Imperial Irrigation District's effort to sell water to San
Diego and the recent abortive effort of the Oakdale Irrigation District
to lease water to the Westlands Irrigation District (California's
largest). A similar setting exists in the Turlock Irrigation District
where farmers pay $30 per acre-foot of water (325,000 gallons), but they
could sell it for $2,000 per acre-foot or more to Westlands if they were
allowed to do so. In all three cases, community members are granted a
veto over proposed water transfers.
In these cases, water rights are so diffused and uncertain that no
party (except farmers) bears the opportunity costs of failed exchanges.
The solution is to define water rights more precisely. Those who seek to
keep water in the community could buy it in competition with outsiders.
Additionally, because distributional issues loom large in rural areas, a
limited mitigation fund could be set up from some of the transfer
revenues to compensate parties economically harmed. The Palo Verde trade
to San Diego included such a fund, even though farmers had clear rights
to sell. The practice of restricting trades is a broad one. Some 22
counties in California have enacted ordinances to block groundwater
transfers out of the county.
Zetland calls for "getting rights right" via auction, but
as shown above this is not the solution to the problem. Auctioning would
confiscate existing prior appropriation rights, not strengthen them. No
high-priority rights holder would find this remedy attractive, and the
prospect would only shorten time horizons and dim assessment of
opportunity costs. If auctions are mandated, water would be moved from
existing owners into the political process. The brief book discussion
does not make clear whether such auctions would be recurring, or how or
if water secured through auction could be traded subsequently and for
how long.
As generally outlined in the second part of the book, water would
become a public or communal resource. The conditions under which
communal management of any natural resource is successful and when it is
not are not outlined. As Nobel economics laureate Elinor Ostrom's
work has revealed, common management works best under settings where
participants are few in number and fairly homogenous in resource
objectives. That does not describe water. We have other empirical
evidence. Consider the more than 370 million acres of so-called public
lands in the continental United States that are under the supervision of
the U.S. Forest Service and the Bureau of Land Management. Although
environmental advocacy groups and others who seek political access and
control over those lands benefit from this arrangement, most studies
indicate that the public lands are less well managed and allocated
across uses than are private lands. This government management
experiment has been running for a long time, so why should we believe
that greater political oversight of water would have a different
outcome?
Zetland is concerned about protecting stream flows, but this is
possible with markets. Private water rights are routinely traded for
augmenting stream flows by Oregon's Freshwater Trust. Rights are
respected, instream flows count as beneficial use to maintain the right,
and environmentalists pay for the water desired for streams. Hence,
state environmental mandates are not necessary to protect aquatic and
riparian habitats. Moreover, more public control and management of water
under the public trust doctrine is counter to trends with other natural
resources where government regulation has been found wanting. In
fisheries, individual transferable quotas and rights-based arrangements
provide important advantages relative to command-and-control regulation.
(See "Learning How to Fish," Vol. 37, No. 1.) Similarly, in
air quality, a nationwide market in sulfur emission permits rapidly met
clean air objectives at lower cost than did Clean Air Act regulations.
Tradable development rights and conservation habitat credits have
lowered the costs of achieving land use controls relative to government
mandates. Why should water be different?
Sax's commons / As a legal principle, the public trust
doctrine historically applied narrowly to the right of the public to
access navigable waterways without being impeded by private riparian
owners. Through the 19th century there was limited extension of the
doctrine to public ownership of some tidelands and subsurface lakebeds.
The much broader idea that the public had superior rights to
non-navigable waters, wildlife, and other natural resources was outlined
in Sax's 1970 paper, contemporaneous with the rise of the modern
environmental movement.
Sax argued that the public trust doctrine could be employed as a
powerful tool for judicial intervention for environmental regulation.
The judiciary could direct public policy for protecting diffuse public
uses from narrow private ones. The article energized legal scholars and
advocacy groups to expand the doctrine and weaken private property
rights. Under the public trust, the rights of the public are vested in
the state as trustee, and the state administers, protects, manages, and
conserves the resource. Any existing uses have only usufruct rights that
can be withdrawn whenever the state deems that they are inconsistent
with the public trust. The public trust doctrine, therefore, provides
for a major extension of the police powers of the state. The
counterfactual outcome of state administration is never made clear by
advocates. Other than private property rights and markets, what
political model do they have in mind that would make politicians and
bureaucrats more responsive to shifts in resource demand and more
concerned with efficient management and conservation? Advocacy groups
and agency officials are critical of private property rights because if
rights are well defined, those parties have little ability to direct the
resource in a manner they desire unless they pay for it. This, however,
is not a compelling argument for how to address the problem of water.
The most celebrated incorporation of the public trust doctrine came
in 1983 when the California Supreme Court in National Audubon Society v.
Superior Court ruled that the "core of the public trust doctrine is
the state's authority as sovereign to exercise a continuous
supervision and control over" the waters of the state to protect
ecological and recreational values. The ruling expanded the role of the
state in reallocation of water as public values changed; asserted that
existing rights were nonvested and therefore could be reallocated
without compensation; and affirmed broad, open standing to citizens to
raise a claim of harm under the public trust against private water
users.
The focus of Audubon was conflict over Los Angeles's water
rights to the Mono Basin. The city acquired those rights in the 1940s
and began major diversion of water in 1970. Owens Valley and the Mono
Basin supplied 80 percent or more of Los Angeles's water that was
so pure it required no treatment and its flow through the Los Angeles
Aqueduct generated hydropower. Over time, however, Los Angeles's
water diversions had substantial adverse effects on Mono Lake and its
surrounding environment. That brought growing opposition. Advocacy
groups such as the National Audubon Society, Friends of the Earth, the
Sierra Club, and the Mono Lake Committee brought suit in 1979 to curtail
Los Angeles's export of water under the public trust doctrine. The
suit challenged the city's water rights. Ultimately, the California
Supreme Court ruled in favor of the plaintiffs. The 1983 ruling,
however, did not resolve the conflict; rather it opened the door for
numerous parties to get involved and mandated the State Water Resources
Control Board to intervene. The dispute took nearly 20 years to resolve,
with multiple court cases and involvement by various constituent groups
and government agencies. In the end, Los Angeles lost its ability to
divert Mono Basin water. All the while during 20 years of conflict, Mono
Lake's environment continued to worsen, streams remained dry, and
riparian and aquatic habitats were unrestored.
The purchase of Los Angeles's water rights was the obvious
policy alternative, but that remedy was not chosen. The case underscores
how the public trust doctrine undercuts property rights; how costly it
is to resolve disputes under it; and points out the absence of any clear
metric, other than interest-group lobbying, for signaling changes in
trust-resource values. Markets perform far more smoothly and less
contentiously in communicating new values and in reallocating resources.
A major reason settlement was not reached in the Mono case was the
many parties granted standing by the doctrine. It made Mono Basin water
a common pool. When one plaintiff reached agreement with Los Angeles
curtailing water diversions, other plaintiffs called for new, more
extreme restrictions. There was a progressive rise in demands on the
city. Another reason why litigation took so long was the nonvested
nature of property rights under the doctrine. The city not only faced
losses in water rights and associated high water replacement costs, but
had to bear the costs of stranded, nondeployable capital in water export
and hydroelectric generation. Los Angeles faced an all-or-nothing battle
while advocates used the Mono case to elicit donor contributions. Those
competing positions prolonged the process and blocked the more optimal,
timely reallocation of Mono water that market transactions might have
brought.
Although there was a lull in public trust efforts after 1983, those
and other community management demands are rising today as drought
places pressure on existing water supplies. If those demands play an
important role in addressing the problem of water, as Zetland outlines
in the second part of his book, then property rights and markets will be
weakened further and solutions made far more costly and ineffective.
That is not the best way for living with water scarcity.
GARY D. LIBECAP is a professor of corporate environmental
management at the University of California, Santa Barbara.